Skip to content
Publicly Available Published by De Gruyter July 24, 2020

Detecting Tail Risks to Preclude Regulatory Arbitrage

The Case for a Normatively Charged Approach to Regulating Shadow Banking

  • Matthias Thiemann EMAIL logo and Tobias H. Tröger

Abstract

This paper contributes to the debate on the adequate regulatory treatment of non-bank financial intermediation (NBFI). It proposes an avenue for regulators to keep regulatory arbitrage under control and preserve sufficient space for efficient financial innovation at the same time. We argue for a normative approach to supervision that can overcome the proverbial race between hare and hedgehog in financial regulation and demonstrate how such an approach can be implemented in practice. We first show that regulators should primarily analyse the allocation of tail risk inherent in NBFI. Our paper proposes to apply regulatory burdens equivalent to prudential banking regulation if the respective transactional structures become only viable through indirect or direct access to (ad hoc) public backstops. Second, we use insights from the scholarship on regulatory networks as communities of interpretation to demonstrate how regulators can retrieve the information on transactional innovations and their risk-allocating characteristics that they need to make the pivotal determination. We suggest in particular how supervisors should structure their relationships with semi-public gatekeepers such as lawyers, auditors and consultants to keep abreast of the risk-allocating features of evolving transactional structures. Finally, this paper uses the example of credit funds as non-bank entities economically engaged in credit intermediation to illustrate the merits of the proposed normative framework and to highlight that multipolar regulatory dialogues are needed to shed light on the specific risk-allocating characteristics of recent contractual innovations.

JEL Classification: G21; G28; H77; K22; K23; L22

Table of Contents

  1. Introduction

  2. Tail Risk Allocation at Public Backstops as Critical Determinant of the Regulatory Treatment of Non-Bank Finance

    1. Why Regulate Shadow Banking?

    2. What Should be Regulated in Shadow Banking?

      1. Paying the Price for Safety Net Access

      2. Access to Ad Hoc Public Backstops for Unregulated Entities?

    3. How to Regulate Shadow Banking

  3. Routes to Achieving Optimal Outcomes: Multipolar Supervisory Dialogues

    1. Exploiting Social Dynamics to Overcome Information Asymmetries

    2. Engaging Gatekeepers in a Candid Regulatory Dialogue

    3. Creating Incentives to Participate in a Collaborative Effort

    4. Interim Conclusion

  4. The Example of Credit Funds

    1. Basic Structure, Increasing Leverage and Maturity Transformation

    2. The Use of Subscription Credit Facilities

    3. Mark-to-Market Valuation of Collateral

    4. Consequences of a Fruitful Multi-Polar Supervisory Dialogue

  5. Conclusion

Economic, Legal and Social Dimensions of Regulatory Arbitrage

  1. Introduction – The Economic, Legal and Social Dimension of Regulatory Arbitrage, by Jan Friedrich and Matthias Thiemann, https://doi.org/10.1515/ael-2020-0150.

  2. Regulatory Arbitrage – What’s Law Got To Do With It?, by Katja Langenbucher, https://doi.org/10.1515/ael-2019-0054.

  3. Regulatory Arbitrage and Non-Judicial Debt Collection in Central and Eastern Europe – Tax Sheltering and Potential Money Laundering, by Cătălin-Gabriel Stănescu and Camelia Bogdan, https://doi.org/10.1515/ael-2019-0055.

  4. Ambiguities in Accounting and their Impact on Regulatory Arbitrage: A Study on the Anchoring of the Rights and Obligations Approach in the IASB’s Conceptual Framework, by Tessa Kunkel, https://doi.org/10.1515/ael-2019-0049.

  5. Regulatory Arbitrage in the Intersection of Accounting Standards and Tax Laws: The Case of Synthetic Leases, by Jan Friedrich, https://doi.org/10.1515/ael-2020-0098.

  6. Detecting Tail Risks to Preclude Regulatory Arbitrage – The Case for a Normatively Charged Approach to Regulating Shadow Banking, by Matthias Thiemann and Tobias Tröger, https://doi.org/10.1515/ael-2019-0059.

1 Introduction

Since the financial crisis of 2007 and 2008, the provision of financial services outside the realm of traditional banking has garnered significant attention from regulators around the globe.[1] Scholars from various disciplines have endeavored to provide research-based guidance for these regulatory efforts.[2] Much of this research has been driven by the underlying assumption that non-bank finance poses a discrete challenge to policy makers that has to be met by an original set of new rules and standards which will require regular updates in line with the financial industry’s innovation cycle, leading to the proverbial ride on the seesaw in the race between policy makers intervening by way of regulation and firms seeking to avoid regulatory burdens.[3] In this paper, we explore the viability of a different route towards socially beneficial outcomes. We capitalize on the fundamental distinction between efficiency-enhancing and socially desirable financial (and technological) innovation on the one hand, and activities that intend to exploit regulatory arbitrage opportunities[4] on the other. By so doing, we embrace an ambiguity inherent in the new forms of finance that were originally characterized pejoratively as ‘shadow banks’ and have now become labelled more neutrally as ‘non-bank financial intermediation’.[5] We develop our approach without driving regulators or supervisors into the gargantuan task of gauging the overall welfare effects of new financial products, transaction structures and other innovations ex ante. Instead we show that the crucial divide can be operationalized close to the ground. The suggested approach – which tries to operationalize a functional perspective[6] – requires no comprehensive overhaul of the regulatory framework, but rather a readjustment of an overly formalist approach to supervision that incorporates the normative foundations of prudential regulation more vigorously into the interpretation and enforcement of existing rules.[7] Implementing a functional approach to supervision also allows addressing a key weakness currently afflicting many regulatory regimes around the world which lack sufficient and still proportionate “prudential market supervision”, i. e. the regulatory treatment and supervision of market based finance with a specific view to systemic risks.[8] Targeting specifically only these developments of NBFI practices that contribute to the build-up of tail risks in the financial system reduces systemic fragility on the one hand but remains minimally invasive on the other, because it does not establish bank-like regulatory burdens for all forms of market based finance.

When confronted with a financial innovation, supervisors first must assess the economic function and the inherent risk structure of the given transaction. In particular, they have to determine who will bear its tail risk. We understand tail risks as those risks that have to be borne when very unlikely but severe events occur and markets therefore take decisively negative turns, potentially fed by negative feedback loops that occur when market liquidity – the ease with which an asset trades – and funding liquidity – the ease with which a trader can obtain funding for their trades – are intertwined.[9] If their analysis shows an indispensable link to the traditional banking sector (i. e. if the transaction structure imposes tail risks on regulated financial institutions), supervisors have to then explore how these exposures were treated by existing regulation if banks assumed the same risks on their balance sheet in functionally equivalent transactions. Finally, supervisors have to apply the existing rules at the level of the regulated entities to the innovative transaction just like they would to its functional equivalent. Therefore, at the level of the ultimate risk-bearer, the regulatory costs of the new transactional structure would be identical to those incurred in its traditional equivalent. This levelling of the costs of complying with prudential rules automatically removes the key incentive to engage in regulatory arbitrage without prohibiting new transaction structures that create additional value. Moreover, supervisors do not have to understand exactly what overall welfare effects discrete financial innovations will ultimately entail for society. Instead, it is sufficient to assess their function and risk-structure with respect to the parties involved in the transaction.

The second contribution of this paper is to explore the preconditions that must be fulfilled in order for supervisors to scrutinize the risk-allocating characteristics of NBFI with sufficient information. We use insights from the scholarship on regulatory networks as communities of interpretation to demonstrate how regulators can retrieve the in-depth knowledge of transactional innovations and their risk-allocating features that they need to make the critical determination for the regulatory treatment of specific forms of NBFI. We suggest in particular how supervisors should structure their relationships with semi-public gatekeepers such as lawyers, auditors and consultants to keep abreast of the risk-allocating features of evolving transactional structures.

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. We first demonstrate that the allocation of tail risks should constitute the critical determinant for the regulatory treatment of NBFI. If tail risks incurred in non-bank finance burden public sector backstops, a normatively charged approach to supervision should apply the existing prudential framework to the respective financial innovations. In particular, where regulated entities with access to public sector backstops absorb tail risks, the relevant exposures should be treated akin to similar balance-sheet positions of the regulated entities (Section 2). The Section 2 presents what we consider a practical route for supervisors to implement the approach we suggest. We point to the social structures of regulatory and supervisory networks that could facilitate the key analysis of tail risk-allocation, involving the expertise of semi-public gatekeepers such as lawyers, auditors or rating agencies in a multi-polar procedural analysis. We also show how these regulatory dialogues should be structured to induce a candid participation of all private sector agents involved (Section 3) . We then illustrate how this framework could be implemented in practice. We use the example of credit funds to show the potency of our approach and document the potentially perilous developments in that industry that should induce supervisors to scrutinise tail risk allocation in regulatory dialogues (Section 4). The last section concludes by summarizing the results (Section 5).

2 Tail Risk Allocation at Public Backstops as Critical Determinant of the Regulatory Treatment of Non-Bank Finance

In this section, we pinpoint that the allocation of tail risks constitutes the critical determinant for the adequate regulatory treatment of the various forms of NBFI. For that purpose, we recall the rationale for regulating non-bank finance (Section 2.1), and then demonstrate the specific issues which require regulation of some forms of NBFI (Section 2.2). From these conceptual foundations we move on to the central policy question of how regulators can effectively analyse financial (and technological) innovations and their contractual characteristics, which define the critical features of NBFI that ultimately allocate tail risks (Section 2.3).

2.1 Why Regulate Shadow Banking?

The wide agreement in the regulatory sphere that the observable expansion of non-bank finance[10] deserves advertence is rooted in the concern that the pertinent activities pose a threat to financial stability.[11] Some of the attempts to scope the issue in a more substantiated manner have pegged the regulatory rationale against the normative foundations of traditional prudential rules in banking. They have thus referred to “maturity/liquidity transformation, leverage and flawed credit risk transfer” that occur outside the regular banking sector as the ultimate source of concern.[12] As is the case in banks, leverage (that is the use of debt to finance assets) and liquidity and maturity mismatches (the refinancing of long-term, illiquid assets with shorter-term, easier redeemable debt) carry inherent refinancing risks for NBFI entities. Deeply analysed as run-risks for banks,[13] these refinancing risks are often even more pronounced in NBFIs, which refinance themselves in the wholesale market. Not only are seasoned investors who transact on these markets more prone to run,[14] but the funding liquidity of NBFI entities and the market liquidity of the assets they use to collateralize their balance sheets are also strongly correlated. This potentially creates an ever-accelerating downward liquidity spiral.[15]

Closely related, yet more specific in describing the mechanics that potentially create system-wide crises as a result of non-bank risk transformations are proposals that turn towards the necessity of backstops as the hallmark of shadow banking.[16] Risk-transforming activities leave residual tail risks that ultimate claim-holders sometimes do not want to bear.[17] If the entities involved cannot create the essential risk absorption capacity themselves (e. g. because low margins prevent them from accumulating sufficient internal capital), then they require a credible private or public sector backstop in order to become viable counterparties in financial transactions. Sufficiently large private sector backstops do not pose a specific regulatory challenge, because they allocate losses at investors who ceteris paribus will price the risk adequately and thus align incentives of executives in NBFI. Yet, the literature has established that the presence of public backstops distorts investors’ incentives, dulls market discipline, and hence allows for risk-insensitive funding of (shadow) banking.[18] This observed market failure calls for regulation and supervision to counter the hazards of risk accumulation on a dramatic (systemic) scale.[19] Therefore, the fundamental policy rationale that underpins the potential regulation and supervision of NBFI is akin to the normative foundations of prudential rules and standards enforced vis-à-vis regular banks.[20] This shared normative DNA of the regulation of NBFI and banks carries important consequences, the understanding of which can determine what should be regulated in shadow banking and how this should be done.

2.2 What Should be Regulated in Shadow Banking?

If prudential regulation of banks is an inherent complement to these institutions’ access to public safety nets, attempts to structure transactions that are functionally equivalent to banking in a way that they retain access to public backstops but do not incur the regulatory costs of such a government guarantee are socially undesirable.[21] Therefore, transaction structures in NBFI that are fuelled by an appetite for regulatory arbitrage should not be validated by law. Instead, prudential regulation should treat them with regard to their economic substance and risk structure (i. e. prudential regulation should apply irrespective of legal form).[22]

2.2.1 Paying the Price for Safety Net Access

Where a transaction benefits from the direct or indirect access to public safety nets,[23] it benefits from a subsidy because investors will be willing to provide funding on more favourable terms than they would if the default probability was determined only endogenously in the asset valuation process.[24] To be sure, sound reasons militate in favour of such a lower bound to the value of claims against a bank because it prevents the system-wide destruction of liquidity in times of panic.[25] Yet, from a public policy point of view, the negative effects of risk-insensitive funding (moral hazard) need a counterbalance in a mechanism that ultimately shifts the costs of the guarantor(s) on to the investors.[26]

Conventionally, prudential regulation is regarded as a substitute for deficient debt governance in banks (i. e. it reacts to a market failure that prevents investors from taking care of the financial soundness of the institutions and, ultimately, the continuous and stable provision of liquidity to the real economy).[27] Yet, contemplated from a different angle, compliance with prudential regulation can be understood as the price that investors in bank assets have to pay – indirectly through the increase in the regulated firms’ costs of doing business – for access to public safety nets.[28] Transactions that are deliberately structured to formally fall outside the scope of application of banking regulation but exhibit a risk-structure that ultimately imposes a downside on a covered institution, seek to sever the inherent connection between access to backstops and prudential rules and standards. Infamously successful attempts have been made to bypass prudential regulation and economize on compliance costs in precisely the inefficient manner just described. These can be found in those securitization transactions in which banks ultimately carried the tail risks, although the securitized loan portfolios were held by off-balance sheet vehicles and thus (arguably) provided relief from regulatory capital requirements.[29]

2.2.2 Access to Ad Hoc Public Backstops for Unregulated Entities?

To be sure, many varieties of non-bank risk transformation do not draw indirectly on public safety nets by shifting tail risks on to regulated institutions. Instead of capitalizing on explicit or implicit liabilities of publicly backstopped institutions, these forms of NBFI benefit from direct access to government backstops, albeit not regular ones. Government bail-outs of shadow-banking entities occur when these entities’ market exit threatens to precipitate a decline in economic output.[30] This can be the case either because these entities are themselves important providers of liquidity (too big to fail) or because their failure has knock-on effects for their competitors that would lead to the demise of a critically important fraction in private sector money supply (too interconnected to fail).[31]

An important example of such a scenario is the run-like withdrawals of funds from US constant net asset value (CNAV) money market mutual funds (MMMFs) (CNAV MMMFs) post-Lehman. They were triggered by the announcement of one fund to redeem shares below par (‘breaking the buck’) and led to an ad hoc bail-out of the whole sector by the Federal Reserve and the Treasury.[32] To be sure, a link between MMMFs and the regulated banking sector may exist where banks run reputational risks in case of a fund’s failure and therefore need to support ailing funds (step in-risk) which in turn connects the troubled entities indirectly to the traditional public backstops for financial institutions.[33]

In these instances, our approach that focuses on the allocation of tail risks would yield results that are fully in line with international soft law. Indeed, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) recommends inter alia to bring the interconnection between off-balance sheet entities and banks that induce step-in risk within the remit of prudential regulation (capital requirements, etc.) through accounting standards that force consolidation of the respective vehicles and thereby bring the relevant exposures on to banks’ balance sheets.[34]

Yet, this is not the story of the US MMMF industry, which had no significant reputational links to regulated banks but was systemic as a liquidity feeder for these institutions who refinanced themselves largely through commercial paper bought by MMMFs. In fact, the business model of (U.S.) MMMF was only viable because they mainly absorbed financial instruments (commercial paper) that regulated banks issued as critical short-term refinancing device, to be rolled-over continuously. This feature of the broader transactional structure created the systemic relevance of MMMF for the U.S. financial system. The pivotal tail risk allocation can only be grasped with a contextualized understanding of a specific position on the liability-side of the balance sheet of regulated banks that prima facie looks short-term but is de facto long-term: banks relied on a continuous roll-over of their commercial paper positions in order to refinance their longer-term investments.

The general rationale for applying prudential regulation where transaction structures benefit from the access to (implicit) public backstops certainly holds in these instances, too. It is not obvious, though, that regulator can indeed implement banking policy by the mere enforcement of existing rules.[35] However, we do not need to explore this any further if we put trust in governments’ pledges not to bail-out financial market players in the future, except for those who explicitly enjoy access to public safety nets (and thus bear the costs of prudential regulation).[36] Indeed, where NBFI entities cannot market their products with implicit guarantees, they will discourage investors who do not want to bear tail risks thereby re-instilling some form of market discipline.

Moreover, competent supervisors could rely on our suggested approach to thwart regulatory arbitrage efforts at an early stage, that is, before a new form of NBFI in itself becomes systemically relevant. For instance, supervisors could have treated MMMFs as deposit-taking institutions at the time these funds were first marketed as an alternative to regular bank deposits with an interest rate cap[37] – precisely because they potentially require a public backstop to avoid runs in a confidence crisis as the ultimate investors would not be willing to bear the tail risks. Such an early intervention would eradicate problems that political decision makers could otherwise face later, once the newly-emerging form of NBFI has gained importance with respect to the economy: any regulatory reaction that unhinged the business model of the whole sector of the financial industry would automatically precipitate the systemic crisis that it was seeking to prevent. To achieve the ambitious goal of facilitating effective early-stage intervention, our procedural approach to identifying the allocation of tails risks in a collaborative discourse (see Section 5 below) becomes even more crucial.

2.3 How to Regulate Shadow Banking

Once recognized, circumventing the substance of existing rules should lead to the application of these very rules at the level of the covered institution or innovative NBFI in need of a public backstop. This would automatically level the regulatory cost structures of functionally equivalent transactions and curb the appetite for regulatory arbitrage. This approach reduces the gap between a transaction’s economic properties and its regulatory treatment.[38] On the other hand, the approach would not impede efficient transaction structures, because their comparative advantage vis-à-vis traditional equivalents, by definition, does not hinge on lowering the costs of compliance.

What is primarily required to put this approach into practice is a radical departure from the literalist stance of supervisors in the face of financial and/or legal innovation. Overseers should instead dare to capitalize more vigorously on the normative substance of existing rules in their enforcement.[39] In a sense, this approach can be understood as a reaction to the breach of the implicit regulatory contract[40] between regulators and the regulated industry.

Quite importantly, such a normative approach would not be tantamount to compelling supervisors to assess the overall social welfare effects of specific financial products ex ante.[41] Supervisors only have to determine the ultimate risk-structure of innovative transaction designs and determine whether they impose tail risks on regulated institutions[42] or potentially create the need for extraordinary ad hoc public backstops. This task is greatly facilitated not only by the clear guidance that supervisors receive in terms of what to look for, but also by the observation that the burden of proof lies with the innovating market participants. If these market participants want different treatment for their transaction (e. g. capital relief), they have to show to the supervisor that it indeed has a unique risk-structure in which storm-resilient investors bear the tail risks.

Moreover, the huge advantage of this approach is that it strengthens the supervisors’ involvement ab ovo. Where market participants cannot be sure to steer clear of prudential regulatory requirements by deliberately designing transaction structures to fall outside the narrowly interpreted wording of existing rules, they will naturally engage in a more candid dialogue with supervisors to avoid being taken by surprise later. Nevertheless, supervisory approaches and procedures have to be designed carefully in order to achieve the optimal outcome.

3 Routes to Achieving Optimal Outcomes: Multipolar Supervisory Dialogues

Even though supervisors “only” have to assess the risk-allocating characteristics of the transactional structures observed in NBFI and enforce existing regulation accordingly, their challenge still remains significant. Typically, supervisors will know little about the critical features of the industry’s most recent innovation. The practical question therefore is how to achieve a more nuanced understanding of financial innovations and their ultimate risk-structure, in order to capture those directed at regulatory arbitrage and to enforce equal regulatory treatment.[43]

3.1 Exploiting Social Dynamics to Overcome Information Asymmetries

Our search for an answer draws upon a rich conceptual and empirical literature, predominantly in socio-legal studies, that has analysed the social dynamics and features associated with principles-based, responsive regulation, which is a close relative of the supervisory approach proposed in this paper.[44] This strand of literature emphasises the need for regulators to overcome information asymmetries vis-á-vis the regulated by actively involving the latter in shaping regulatory approaches and supervisory practices to enhance effective compliance. Principles-based regulation could ensure such involvement through regulatory dialogues. Both regulators (due to a lack of in-depth understanding of recent advances in transactional practices) and the regulated (due to a lack of certainty about the pending decisions of the regulator’s treatment of financial innovations) have a strong interest in communicating with each other at nascent stages of a product’s development. This feature of principles-based regulation (mutual interest in engaging in a two-way dialogue to reduce informational asymmetries), which it shares with its slight variation proposed here, namely the normative approach to supervision, allows supervisors to fine-tune the meaning of prudential rules with a view to early-stage developments. Regulation-centred dialogues that involve actors intertwined by a long-term relationship[45] therefore, in principle, provide an ideal platform for limiting the circumvention of existing regulation through financial innovation.[46]

However, the events of 2007/2008 undermined the pre-crisis enthusiasm of scholars who emphasised the possibilities in involving the proprietary knowledge of the regulated to improve the regulatory process, leading such scholars to feel disenchanted.[47] In particular, it was found that a weakness of these regulatory dialogues was the insufficient engagement of supervisors. This can be traced back to the lack of essential skills and institutional sanctioning powers held by supervisors, which they required if they were going to momentously structure these dialogues, according to their mandate, in the public interest.[48] A fundamental research interest of the existing literature then has been to understand how the regulatory community and its dialogues are, and should be, organised to facilitate such steering.

Our contribution seeks to answer this question more succinctly and looks particularly at the pivotal features of the interaction between supervisors and the regulated that allow the former to gain a fuller comprehension of financial innovations, their ultimate risk-structures and their motivations through either efficiency gains or (perceived) regulatory arbitrage opportunities. We argue that this requires monitoring of the production processes that lead to financial innovations and particularly the negotiations that the regulated conduct with semi-public[49] gatekeepers in order to determine the regulatory treatment of new products. If these products are designed to circumvent existing regulations and provide access to public backstops to NBFI, regulatory charges for these transactions should be equivalent to the charges levied on banks for functionally equivalent transactions.

3.2 Engaging Gatekeepers in a Candid Regulatory Dialogue

The first important analytical step is to move away from an overly simplistic perspective of financial markets. Such a view sees these markets essentially as populated exclusively by regulators/supervisors and the regulated. According to this view, the two camps are linked to each other by both entrepreneurs’ desire to develop new products that fall outside of the remit of existing regulation and by regulators’ desire to re-capture them.[50] Instead, financial market regulation and supervision today is largely decentred. For the enforcement of existing regulation, this means that there are several agents (private and public) which are tasked with verifying the compliance of the regulated with the rules. In particular, these agents include auditors, rating agencies and lawyers, which – where commissioned with quasi-supervisory functions – act as semi-public gatekeepers in financial markets.[51] Acknowledging this fact requires us to widen our perspective to embrace the multiple agents in regulatory networks and their interactions that involve private agents on a mezzanine level between public supervisors and the regulated industry.[52] These semi-public gatekeepers play an important role in the creation of financial innovations: they seek to ensure regulatory compliance of the invented products and want to achieve regulatory advantages for the regulated as well. It is therefore in regulatory dialogues that involve not only the regulated themselves but also the private agents of compliance that supervisors can gain a more nuanced understanding of the purpose of financial innovations and the particular contractual structure designed to achieve this.

In their conversations with the regulated and semi-public gatekeepers, supervisors should be incisive, ask simple questions and require simple answers.[53] They should seek and reward honesty.[54] At the same time, in order to bring about openness from the regulated in these dialogues it is important that supervisors do not generally presume criminal behaviour.[55] The literature on principles-based regulation has pointed out that regulatory interventions which are “broad, general and purposive,” and supported by high-level principles as a “backstop,”[56] are conducive to making the regulated seek these regulatory dialogues in good faith, as the regulated depend more heavily on supervisory judgment than in a rules-based prudential environment. The supervisor is the final arbiter of rules.[57] Supervisors are the actors who ultimately determine the interpretation and scope of prudential regulation. Therefore, the regulated are dependent on their decision-making.

Principles-based regulation and its close relative, the normatively charged approach to supervision, requires supervisors and firms to determine the precise meaning and scope of the rules and standards potentially applicable to financial innovations during their implementation and enforcement. Ideally, this leads to a collaborative effort in which joint deliberations carve out the respective laws’ meaning and scope. In this setting, compliance officers and other industry personnel, consultants, accountants, lawyers and supervisors engage in a discourse in which they quasi-negotiate – by exchanging arguments – the context-specific meaning of principles and rules for business practice as they apply to financial innovations; they form the interpretive community central to a principles-based approach.[58] In turn, this means that the ‘battle over interpretive control’ becomes key.[59] Put differently, the question is how the supervisor can maintain control over the content of prudential regulation and its scope (the universe of products to which it should apply) not only in a formal sense, but also with regard to its substance (the “law in action”). Only if supervisors are indeed in a position to knowledgeably exercise such a prerogative of interpretation can they determine which activities need to come under prudential regulation according to its normative foundations. Interpretive control is vested in the agent who ultimately, in full consideration of the material facts, establishes which financial innovations, products, and transactions are governed by existing rules and what compliance with these rules actually means in this context.

See Sections 2.2 and 2.3 above, we are not claiming that supervisors should embrace a profound understanding of the overall stability and welfare implications of a specific financial innovation which the regulated and gatekeepers may or may not have. In fact, we presume that financial innovation frequently is driven by a firm-specific desire for profit-maximization that does not encourage a deep look into the broader repercussions of the new cornucopia. The only thing that we believe supervisors should capitalize on is the proprietary knowledge of the industry and its gatekeepers on the production process of financial innovation. This should provide specific knowledge on the motives pursued by the parties and thereby produce indirect evidence on where tail risks are actually allocated.

3.3 Creating Incentives to Participate in a Collaborative Effort

Understanding the positions of relevant actors in the interpretative community is all the more important when we look closely at the processes that produce (undesirable) financial innovations. Insofar as they are driven by the purpose of evading prudential rules and standards, they are intrinsically tied to the regulatory environment they intend to avoid.[60] These financial innovations face crucial regulatory passage points in order to become viable. At these points, the question that arises is whether they fall under incisive prudential banking regulation or whether the particular contractual structure permits these instruments to sail in less rigidly overseen waters. This is the case, for instance, on capital markets where securities regulation only mandates transparency but does not mandate holding regulatory capital against risky exposures.[61] Financial innovations that aim to circumvent banking regulation need to be designed in a way that brings them outside the scope of prudential rules in order to reap profits from a lower regulatory burden. This requires market participants to tailor these products to fit into the low-regulatory burden environment, which in turn typically requires substantial accounting and legal engineering.[62] Semi-public gatekeepers such as auditors and lawyers are instrumental in providing supportive expert opinions and thereby ensuring (formal) compliance with regulation. Without the privately beneficial regulatory treatment,[63] a financial innovation driven by an appetite for regulatory arbitrage would not survive. Various relevant professions are engaged in the creation of financial innovations from the outset, working as both gatekeepers and advisors who seek to optimize regulatory costs for their clients.[64]

Fitting financial innovations into the regulatory environment in a way that maximizes their profitability for the industry, particularly under the normatively charged approach to supervision advocated here, will typically require intense debates at an early stage of the process between the gatekeepers foreseen in regulation and advisors who provide services for market participants.[65] For instance, determining whether an investment vehicle can be treated as an off-balance sheet entity or needs to be consolidated in the bank’s financial statement for regulatory purposes will require a dialogue between the bank’s auditors, its advisors – including lawyers – and the relevant departments in the bank.[66] While the regulated and their advisors have incentives to seek the lowest regulatory burden conceivable for a financial innovation, gatekeepers in their semi-public function arguably have to guarantee at least minimum standards of substantive compliance with the rules in order to maintain credibility vis-à-vis the supervisor, as otherwise they would imperil the reputational basis on which their public role hinges. These debates often lead to a process of negotiation between the different agents about how financial innovations have to be structured to ensure compliance while keeping the regulatory burden at a minimum. Semi-public gatekeepers in this respect are bound to their clients’ interest[67] and in the end will most likely accept any financial innovation that can reasonably be represented as falling outside the scope of banking regulation. Hence, it is paramount that supervisors are close to these debates and understand how they evolve. This allows them to understand better the new product’s proximity to banking activities and where the risks of these new contractual structures for financial stability may emanate. In other words, it allows them to acquire a deeper understanding of the allocation of tail risk between the different parties to the contract and whether this allocation calls for prudential regulation because it ultimately requires public backstops to absorb losses (see Sections 2.2 and 2.3 above).

Therefore, supervisors should use their powers to gain information about these negotiations, their content and their direction. By opening up channels of communication to those inside the market that hold critical information, supervisors can gain important insights about the drivers behind specific financial innovations. In particular, they should seek to understand if and how new products and transaction structures are construed to avoid the costs of complying with prudential regulation, while, at the same time, they create economically equivalent risk exposures and allocate tail risks in a way that taps into or requires public backstops. This knowledge will in turn facilitate understanding of the product’s ultimate risk structure, which should determine its regulatory treatment.[68] In that sense, gatekeepers and the many other private providers of services providers to the regulated are key to understanding the precise, context-specific interaction between existing prudential regulation and financial innovation. Rating agencies, law firms and audit companies are obvious interlocutors for supervisors in this respect.

To be sure, in our framework gatekeepers are not supposed to perform a quasi-supervisory function.[69] Instead, our starting point is a highly sceptical view of gatekeepers as such. Therefore, we acknowledge that they acquire the relevant information in a self-interested pursuit of their clients’ objectives during the creation of complex financial products. Yet still, we believe gatekeepers can be induced to share this treasure of information with supervisors, without assuming that the incentives to do so can come from a commitment to serve the public good alone, even if such a commitment was enshrined in regulation. The regulatory framework should rather activate the self-interest of gatekeepers as for-profit organizations for that purpose. Quite importantly, the regulatory assessment of and the determination of the adequate supervisory response to financial innovations lies entirely with the (informed) public agencies.

However, opening up channels of communication for a meaningful flow of information requires aligning the supervisor’s goals with those of the gatekeepers. A first step in doing so is to lift the professional secrecy of these gatekeepers in relation to the regulator with respect to innovations that raise concerns about their compliance with the spirit of the law. But, while this is a necessary condition, it by no means creates an incentive for gatekeepers to talk candidly to the regulator.

Inducing gatekeepers to report frankly on their negotiations with the regulated (and their advisors) on the treatment of financial innovation is key to exposing dubious attempts at creative compliance. However, semi-public gatekeepers will not disclose sensitive information voluntarily as long as they fear that doing so would incur negative reputation effects that would potentially imperil their relationships with their clients. Hence, in order to facilitate this flow of information, gatekeepers need to have an overriding interest in acquiring and maintaining a good standing in the eyes of the supervisor. To achieve this goal, a carefully calibrated set of carrots and sticks must be established to induce all agents to provide the input necessary to turn joint deliberative effort into a mutually and socially beneficial endeavour. Supervisors need to make an upfront investment and act as a forthcoming partner ready to help overcome the uncertainty regarding the exact meaning and scope of prudential rules and standards by candidly sharing their views on the regulatory treatment of financial innovations in a timely manner.[70] On the other hand, the price that gatekeepers pay for this hospitable treatment of legitimate information requests is that they become accountable for their information-sharing behaviour towards the supervisor and can be excluded from the interpretative community in the event of misconduct.[71] The upside for well-behaving gatekeepers though is the competitive advantage of being able to provide their clients immediate access to the supervisor’s evaluation during the supervisory discourse. This arrangement ensures that all agents in the interpretative community have an interest in an ongoing honest and candid exchange on relevant matters, making it a proper quid pro quo that reciprocally reduces the informational asymmetries and thus minimizes uncertainty on both sides. The supervisory discourse is based on trust, but should be backed up by adequate sanctions that minimize opportunistic behaviour.

Therefore, the sanctioning power of supervisors should collateralize the pivotal information exchange between gatekeepers and supervisors in a way that makes it in the gatekeepers’ own interest to speak openly with the supervisor about evolving transactional practices and contractual designs, particularly their risk-allocating features. Accordingly, regulators can enroll these semi-public agents for their task of supervision.[72] Supervisors need discretion to exclude certain gatekeepers from their regulation-related mandates if these semi-public agents do not report known material facts discussed during innovation design that determine the risk-structure and allocation of tail risks. The respective agents should communicate relevant considerations voiced during the drafting of transaction structures (e. g. considerations regarding the allocation of tail risks) to the regulator, thereby flagging the need for a proper regulatory assessment of the final contractual allocations.

This proposal is anchored in existing regulation, which, for instance, requires accounting firms to report evidence that indicates certain misbehaviour on the part of the audited institution[73] and gives the prudential supervisor the power to ask for a termination of the auditing mandate in case of misbehaviour.[74] From here, the next logical step appears to be to broaden the communicative obligations of gatekeepers, in particular where this obligation is coupled with the rewards for candid collaboration in the form of expedited answers to legitimate requests for regulatory assessments.[75]

To establish a real threat for gatekeepers that has the capacity to change their behaviour to be more contributive, the expertise of the supervisor becomes important. Indeed, a certain amount of knowledge and skill concerning gatekeeping functions, such as auditing or lawyering, coupled with an understanding of the tail risks involved in NBFI, needs to be present within the supervisory body and ideally should be updated through constant exchange with practising gatekeepers.

In gaining access to the relevant information, regulators can and should exploit the fact that semi-public gatekeepers are themselves complex organizations with internal compliance departments. For example, every auditing company has its own technical departments, which supervise and decide whether new transaction designs developed by auditing partners on the ground with clients comply with applicable auditing standards. Similarly, albeit in a less institutionalized manner, law firms have partner committees and practice group meetings that discuss innovative transaction designs that potentially circumvent prudential regulation. Hence, regulators should also connect to these units to keep abreast of the challenges the latter face, which would inform the regulators about financial innovations and how they interact with the regulatory framework. Knowing about these internal debates could provide a signal inducing supervisors to look thoroughly into the ultimate risk structure of these transactions.

3.4 Interim Conclusion

In sum, it is not only the regulated and their financial innovations, which need to be the subject of supervision. Gatekeepers and their interactions with the regulated over the regulatory status of financial innovations also need to be considered when the regulatory treatment of these innovations is being determined. By incentivizing gatekeepers to keep regulators abreast of current exchanges between gatekeepers and the regulated (and their advisors), the supervisor can avoid a backward-looking perspective that only understands market developments long after they have occurred.[76] Positive incentives to voluntarily provide relevant input on the one hand, and holding both the regulated and the gatekeepers accountable for their compliance decisions on the other, are the crucial elements in setting up this multipolar deliberative relationship for the benefit of market participants and society at large.

We acknowledge that globally integrated financial markets do not only require dialogues with the industry and their advisors, but also call for cross-jurisdictional information sharing and collaboration of regulators and supervisors.[77] However, this necessity is not specific to our approach. In fact, by relieving supervisors from the challenge to understand the systemic risk potentially inherent in financial innovation ex ante (see Section 2.3), our approach significantly facilitates and focusses cross-border cooperation. It centers on rather technical issues of (tail) risk allocation, not immediately prone to political intervention like the application of macroprudential tools.

4 The Example of Credit Funds

Credit funds are a typical example of an ambiguous form of NBFI. These alternative investment vehicles – largely non-present in bank-centred Europe before 2007 – observed a significant upswing after the financial crisis.[78] Policy makers mostly hailed this development and supervisors acquiesced in it, largely because it coincided with the objective of uncloaking liquidity supplies to the economy and stimulating growth by activating market-based finance in an environment where banks that were still wobbly and subject to heavy regulation had cut down on lending.[79] However, the potentially negative flip-side of the coin becomes obvious when the legal design of typical European credit fund operations[80] is analysed carefully with a view to determining where tail risks are allocated. Not only are the typical assets held by the funds (warehoused, pre-packaged loan portfolios) similar to those found in pre-crisis securitisation deals, but the transaction structures also resemble each other in critical dimensions (see Figure 1 below).

Figure 1: 
Basic Transaction Structure of European Credit Funds.
Figure 1:

Basic Transaction Structure of European Credit Funds.

This paper does not set out to scrutinize the risk allocation in all conceivable variations of marketable transaction structures comprehensively. Instead, it highlights the main features that an attuned supervisor should examine deeply in the supervisory discourse when it comes to determining the regulatory treatment of credit funds.

4.1 Basic Structure, Increasing Leverage and Maturity Transformation

The basic structure of credit funds is a progeny of the well-established structure of fund vehicles in general. Specifically it entails a contractual arrangement that sees investors put their money into the shares of the fund, which the latter in turn invests under pre-specified conditions into credit instruments issued by other market participants. Figure 1 sketches the basic structure of credit fund transactions.

Designed carefully not to come under the relevant European definition of a ‘credit institution’[81] and catering mainly to professional investors[82], these funds escape much of the constraining and costly prudential regulation, although they are subject to the AIFM Directive and the implementation thereof in the Member States. The underlying assumption is that these funds operate essentially without leverage and that professional investors are able to take informed investment decisions after the necessary due diligence. It is however important to point out here that investors have the right to withdraw their funds should they become unsatisfied with returns. Where the funds’ assets have longer maturity and are relatively illiquid, such a more or less unrestricted redeemability creates a prototypical run risk in the structure. Yet, this basic structure is what national securities regulators can, and are sometimes eager to; admit under the current regulatory framework[83] for alternative investment funds, in order to position their jurisdiction as a welcoming home to such funds, with Luxembourg being the prime example of this in Europe.[84]

From this point of inception, the underlying structures of these funds have evolved gradually over time with an incremental increase in the maturity mismatch and the leverage these funds entertain. While credit funds originally had only little to no maturity mismatch or leverage, the European credit funds’ leverage in 2018 amounted to a factor of 1.8. This means that on every euro invested by a residual claimant, an additional debt-load worth 1.80 euro is taken on to leverage the available funds and to generate higher returns for equity investors. It is noteworthy that the investment behaviour of a subset of credit funds drives these observations. While in 2018 the vast majority of funds (66%) only used limited to no leverage (with an average debt to equity ratio of 1:1) and matched the maturity of assets and liabilities,[85] large credit funds especially pursued a more aggressive leverage strategy which also coincided with a stronger maturity mismatch, with 17% of longer-term assets being refinanced by liabilities of less than one year. The trend seems to be relatively recent, with the leverage ratio going up from 1.3 to 1.8 from 2017 to 2018.[86] Figure 2 depicts the relatively advanced structure of an originator-driven credit fund transaction.

Figure 2: 
Structure of Loan Originator-Driven, Leveraged Credit Fund.
Figure 2:

Structure of Loan Originator-Driven, Leveraged Credit Fund.

As Figure 2 shows, leverage and maturity mismatch are introduced through issuing debt notes (through the operating company, OpCo) and short-term commercial paper (through the financing company, FinCo) to outside investors in a structure known as the net asset value fund. Here, the fund (the holding company, HoldCo) pledges the loans at their net asset value as the collateral for the funds’ issuance of debt. Encumbered in this way, the loans are sealed off from investors, and serve as guarantees for outside debt investors of the fund. The logical implication of this debt issuance however is that fund investors, while potentially gaining higher returns due to increased leverage and the limited interest rate that needs to be paid for the collateralized debt securities, now have less collateral available in the event they want to exit the fund,[87] thereby increasing the run risks. The situation worsens when the net asset value falls: this could lead to an increase in investor withdrawals which could spur forced sales of loans, which in turn could further depress the value of the portfolio held by the fund. In a leveraged fund, debt holders, whose collateral also depreciates in value, might take the opportunity to accelerate the downward spiral in larger-scale fire-sales. This has the potential to destabilize the financial system in cases where the expanded non-bank credit channel has become systemic. In that scenario, the system could not survive without an implicit public backstop, which would warrant the application of prudential regulation (see Section 3 above).

4.2 The Use of Subscription Credit Facilities

A second way of increasing leverage, which is increasingly coupled with the net asset value collateralization for financing funds, is the use of so-called ‘subscription credit facilities.’ An industry source described their evolution as follows: “While originally developed as a mechanism for funds to ‘bridge’ a funding gap when making an investment, thereby eliminating the risk of any shortfall and providing the fund with certainty that the requisite funds would be available to it at the moment of investment, they are increasingly used in a broader investment context for more general purposes, such as providing debt or bridging debt refinancing, funding follow-on investments or bridging co-investments.”[88]

These facilities act as permanent short-term debt financing instruments at the disposal of the credit funds, as the following remarks from the same industry source clarified: “[t]he facility is usually short term (2–3 years) and aligned with the fund’s investment period” and is usually structured as “a senior, secured revolving credit facility that is renewed at expiry.”[89] Overall, the point of these facilities is to assure the investors in the credit fund, who purchase commercial papers and mezzanine notes, that the capital that these investors provide can always be repaid by the fund, even if there are difficulties in terms of the roll-over of the short-term and medium-term credit instruments in financial markets.[90] In their plainest form, these facilities use the as-yet-uncalled capital of the credit funds as collateral to secure the credit extended by the bank. Other facilities use the net asset value method to determine the value of the portfolio of the fund and then borrow against this net value as collateral. More recently, so-called ‘hybrid facilities’ have combined these two forms of credit facilities.[91]

As a result of the transaction, the loan-originating bank reduces its capital requirements with respect to the loans it thus far had fully on its balance sheet,[92] although it potentially still assumes some of the portfolio’s credit risk as a function of the ‘subscription credit facility.’[93] Depending on the exact contractual arrangement, this may result in an all-too-familiar disappearance of risky exposures from banks’ balance sheets without actual risk transfer taking place.

While, prima facie, the sketched structure in each separate element provides safety to the investors in and to the creditors of the fund, its stability hinges on the correct, risk-adequate and information-insensitive pricing of the portfolio loans in financial markets and the persistent roll-over possibility of the debt. Should a negative credit scenario arise, funds may have to draw indirectly on public safety nets through the institutions that provide the subscription credit facility, at least in systemic crises. For example, should the net asset value of the transferred and pledged loans fall, investors tend to withdraw their capital, and short-term commercial paper creditors will not renew their investments. In both cases, the credit facility, and hence the publicly backstopped banking system, is left as the ultimate absorber of this negative shock.

4.3 Mark-to-Market Valuation of Collateral

In short, what we can observe in the recent evolution of the credit fund industry is that more leverage, more maturity mismatch and more opacity are all emerging incrementally from rather boring, but relatively risk-free, business practices. A good example of this incremental change is evident in the subscription credit facility: originally its main function was to provide bridge funding and liquidity but its main function now is to increase the leverage of the fund. The most radical departure from the original trajectory, however, seems to be the coupling of such credit facilities with the refinancing methods of net asset value (NAV) funds. These entities use the assets in their portfolios based on weekly mark-to-market valuations as the collateral for the extension of credit to the fund. These new structures rebut the argument that risks are fully absorbed by the funds’ equity investors. In fact, the incremental use of leverage and the market valuation of pledged, potentially illiquid assets should at least remind us of the dangerous pre-crisis dynamics that linked solvability of funds to market valuations, coupling funding and market liquidity[94] and leaving the publicly backstopped banking system as the ultimate absorber of negative shocks.

4.4 Consequences of a Fruitful Multi-Polar Supervisory Dialogue

Against this background, supervisors should look into: the transactional design and the contractual arrangements between those granting debt financing and credit funds; the funds’ contractual stipulations regarding investors providing equity (redemption rights); and, finally, the banks providing collateralized financing facilities. Supervisors should seek to prevent structures that only become viable because they benefit from the direct or indirect access to explicit or implicit public safety nets without paying the price of adhering to the full set of prudential regulation.

This look-through to the allocation of tail risks may lead inter alia to the application of regulatory capital requirements in shadow banking, just like in traditional banking business. Under the approach favoured here, the extension of subscription credit facilities by banks could force banks to consolidate credit funds on their balance sheets and, therefore, to hold capital against these exposures in amounts equal to those if the banks directly held the funds’ loan portfolios. However, to arrive at fully informed, socially beneficial decisions, supervisors need to engage in regulatory dialogues with gatekeepers and industry advisors, keeping supervisors abreast of contractual innovations and their consequences with respect to the allocation of tail risks. In fact, we gathered much of the information on fund structures and tail risk allocation provided in this paper from dialogue with members of the accounting profession and the bar. To make these regulatory dialogues a source of valuable information, supervisors need to signal recurrently to the regulated which regulatory stance they are taking in light of incremental changes in transactional structures.

5 Conclusion

This paper has discussed a possible route to regulating and supervising NBFI. We have argued for equal treatment in regulation and normatively charged supervision of activities that allocate tail risks in a way that they have to be ultimately absorbed by (implicit or explicit) public safety nets. Moreover, we outlined how regulators might be able to undertake the required analysis of risk structures in NBFI and showed how a multi-polar regulatory dialogue within the interpretative community can facilitate a real-time continuous understanding of evolving transactional practices and their risk-allocating contractual features. Gatekeepers, such as auditors, law firms and also rating agencies, play a fundamental role in this regard. Our approach can handle the relentless dynamics of the financial sector better than the existing (legalistically enforced) prudential framework. Focussing on the allocation of tail risks provides a simple compass that allows supervisors to tell socially beneficial innovation apart from regulatory arbitrage. At the same time, it does not ask too much from supervisors, because it does not call for an overall social welfare assessment of financial innovation. Finally, our compass works in all segments of NBFI, because the underlying normative idea of tying regulatory burdens to the – direct or indirect – access to public safety nets holds universally and ‘only’ requires a case-by-case assessment of individual forms of non-bank finance using insights from the regulatory dialogues we propose to conduct in the broader interpretative community.

We then illustrated the potential of this framework using the example of credit funds, and pointed to the set of incremental contractual changes that may have led to a replication of banks’ business models and their inherent fragility in this realm of financial market activity. Credit funds today increasingly use maturity mismatch and leverage to increase the profitability of their business, thereby enhancing the run risks and, through their intricate relationships with banks, creating the possibility that public backstops will ultimately have to bear the tail risks.

Credit funds are not yet systemic, but they could become so. This potential development requires a persistent and critical look at the adequacy of such funds’ treatment in prudential regulation, thus making the proposed multi-polar regulatory dialogues all the more essential.


Corresponding author: Matthias Thiemann, Assistant Professor, Assistant Professor of European Public Policy, Sciences Po, Centre for European Studies and Comparative Politics, 27 rue Saint-Guillaume, 75337 Paris Cedex 07, Paris, France, E-mail:

Matthias Thiemann: The paper benefitted greatly from discussions during Thiemann’s stay as a fellow at Goethe University’s CAS LawFin (DFG FOR 2774). Comments and critique from Jan Friedrich, Max Fröhlich and Stijn Claessens as well as conference participants at the University of Mannheim, Centre for Competition and Innovation (MaCCI) were particularly beneficial. Thiemann gratefully acknowledges research support from the CAS LawFin. A prior version of this paper has been published as a SAFE Working Paper titled “It’s the tail risk, stupid”.

The Case for a Normatively Charged Approach to Regulating Shadow Banking based on Multipolar Regulatory Dialogues. It’s the Tail Risk, Stupid! Precluding Regulatory Arbitrage in Shadow Banking With a Normatively Charged Approach to Supervision Capitalizing on Multipolar Regulatory Dialogues.


Funding source: DFG Center for Advanced Studies Law and Finance

References

Acharya, V. V., Schnabl, P., & Suarez, G. (2013). Securitization without risk transfer. Journal of Financial Economics, 107, 515, 519–520. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.09.004.Search in Google Scholar

Adrian, T., & Shin, H. S. (2010). Liquidty and leverage. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 19(3), 418–437. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfi.2008.12.002.Search in Google Scholar

Adrian, T., … (2012). Shadow banking: A review of the literature. [Federal Reserve of NY Staff Report, No. 580].Search in Google Scholar

Anand, A. I. (2009). Rules vs. principles based approaches to financial market regulation. Harvard International Law Journal, 49(7), 111–115.Search in Google Scholar

Antoine, M., Skreie, D., & von Thadden, E.-L. (2014). Repo runs. Review of Financial Studies, 27, 954.10.1093/rfs/hht134Search in Google Scholar

Armour, J., … (2016). Principles of financial regulation (p. 84). OUP.10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198786474.001.0001Search in Google Scholar

Ayres, I., & Braithwaite, J. (1992). Responsive regulation-transcending the deregulation debate. Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Bakk-Simon, … (2012). Shadow banking in the Euro area. ECB Occasional Paper, 133, 8. Retrieved from www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpops/ecbocp133.pdf.10.2139/ssrn.4022867Search in Google Scholar

Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS). (2017). Guidelines: Identification and management of step-in risk. Retrieved from https://www.bis.org/bcbs/publ/d423.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Battaglini, M., … (2019). Tax-evasion facilitators or information hubs. NBER Working Paper No. 25745. Retrieved from https://www.nber.org/papers/w25745.pdf.10.3386/w25745Search in Google Scholar

Beck, G. W., & Kotz, H. H. (2016). Euro area shadow banking activities in a low-interest-rate environment: A flow-of-funds perspective. SAFE Policy White Paper No. 37. Retrieved from https://safe-frankfurt.de/fileadmin/user_upload/editor_common/Policy_Center/Beck_Kotz_Euro_area_shadow_banking_activities.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Beekman, W. B., Bowman, C. A., & Brown, V. G. J. (2014). Considering a subscription credit facility? Here's what you need to know. Debevoise & Plimpton, 2014. Retrieved from https://www.debevoise.com/insights/publications/2014/03/considering-a-subscription-credit-facility-heres__.Search in Google Scholar

Bhattacharya, S., Boot, A. W. A., & Thakor, A. V. (1998). The Economics of bank regulation. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 745, 30. https://doi.org/10.2307/2601127.Search in Google Scholar

Black, J. (2002). Regulatory conversations. Journal of Law and Society, 29(1), 163. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6478.00215.Search in Google Scholar

Black, J. (2003). Enrolling actors in regulatory systems: Examples from UK financial services regulation. Public law, 63.Search in Google Scholar

Black, J. (2010). The rise, fall and fate of principles based regulation. LSE Law Working Paper 17/2010. Retrieved from https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1712862.10.2139/ssrn.1712862Search in Google Scholar

Black, J. (2012). Paradoxes and failures: “New governance” techniques and the financial crisis. The Modern Law Review 1037, 75(6), 1044. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2230.2012.00936.x.Search in Google Scholar

Black, J., & Baldwin, R. (2010). Really responsive risk-based regulation. Law & Policy, 32(2), 181. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9930.2010.00318.x.Search in Google Scholar

Blair, M. M. (2013). Making money: Leverage and private sector money creation. Seattle University Law Review, 36, 417.10.2139/ssrn.2241697Search in Google Scholar

Braithwaite, J. (2008). Regulatory capitalism: How it works, ideas for making it work better. Edward Elgar Publishing.10.4337/9781848441262Search in Google Scholar

Bratton, W. W., & Levitin, A. J. (2013). A transactional genealogy of scandal: From Michael Milken to Enron and Goldman Sachs. S Cal L Rev, 86, 783, 836–841.10.2139/ssrn.2126778Search in Google Scholar

Braun, B. (2018). Central banking and the infrastructural power of finance: The case of ECB support for repo and securitization markets. Socio-Economic Review (forthcoming). https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwy008.Search in Google Scholar

Brunnermeier, M. K., & Pedersen, L. H. (2007). Market liquidity and funding liquidity. NBER Working Paper No. 12939. Retrieved from https://www.nber.org/papers/w12939.10.3386/w12939Search in Google Scholar

Claessensn, S., & Ratnovski, L. (2014). What is shadow banking? International Monetary Fund Working Paper 14/25, 4–5. Retrieved from www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2014/wp1425.pdf.10.5089/9781475597349.001Search in Google Scholar

Coates, J. C. (2015). Cost-benefit analysis of financial regulation: Case studies and implications. The Yale Law Journal, 124, 882.10.2139/ssrn.2375396Search in Google Scholar

Coffee, J. C. (2006). Gatekeepers: The professions and corporate governance. Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Covitz, D., Liang, N., & Suarez, G. A. (2013). The evolution of a financial crisis: Collapse of the asset backed commercial paper market. The Journal of Finance, 68, 815. https://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12023.Search in Google Scholar

Dechert, L. P. P. (2018). The role of private credit managers in supporting economic growth. Financing the Economy, 41. Retrieved from https://www.aima.org/educate/aima-research/fte-2018.html.Search in Google Scholar

Dewatripont, M., & Tirole, J. (1994). The prudential regulation of banks (p. 141). MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar

Diamond, D. W., & Dybvig, P. H. (1983). Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidty. Journal of Political Economy, 91, 401, .10.1086/261155Search in Google Scholar

Endrejat, V., & Thiemann, M. (2020). Reviving the Shadow Banking Chain in Europe: Regulatory agency, technical complexity and the dynamics of cohabitation. Competition and Change. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3237354.Search in Google Scholar

Etienne, J. (2013). Ambiguity and relational signals in regulator-regulatee relationships. Regulation & Governance, 7(1), 30. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1748-5991.2012.01160.x.Search in Google Scholar

European Commission. (2012). Green paper on shadow banking. European Commission, 3–5, 102.Search in Google Scholar

Financial Stability Board. (2011). Shadow banking: Scoping the issue. Financial Stability Board, 3. Retrieved from www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_110412a.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Financial Stability Board. (2018a). Global monitoring report on non-bank financial intermediation 2018. Financial Stability Board, 13–15. Retrieved from https://www.fsb.org/wp-content/uploads/P040219.pdf#page=8.Search in Google Scholar

Financial Stability Board. (2018b). FSB reviews financial vulnerabilities and deliverables for G20 Summit. Retrieved from https://www.fsb.org/wp-content/uploads/R221018.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Fleischer, V. (2010). Regulatory arbitrage. Texas Law Review, 89, 227.10.2139/ssrn.1567212Search in Google Scholar

Ford, C. L. (2008). New governance, compliance, and principles-based securities regulation. American Business Law Journal, 45(1), 1. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1744-1714.2008.00050.x.Search in Google Scholar

Ford, C. L. (2010). New governance in the teeth of human frailty: Lessons from financial regulation. Wisconsin Law Review, 2, 101.Search in Google Scholar

Ford, C. L. (2011). Macro- and micro-level effects on responsive financial regulation. British Columbia L Rev, 44(3), U 589, 617.Search in Google Scholar

Ford, C. L. (2013). Innovation-framing regulation. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 76, 649(1), 91–93. https://doi.org/10.1177/0002716213489249.Search in Google Scholar

Ford, C. (2017). Innovation and the state: Finance, regulation, and justice (pp. 48–50). Cambridge University Press.10.1017/9781139583473Search in Google Scholar

Funk, R. J., & Hirschman, D. (2014). Derivatives and deregulation: Financial innovation and the demise of Glass–Steagall. Administrative Science Quarterly, 59, 69.10.1177/0001839214554830Search in Google Scholar

Gabor, D. (2016). The (impossible) repo trinity: The political economy of repo markets. Review of International Political Economy, 23(6), 967–1000. https://doi.org/10.1080/09692290.2016.1207699.Search in Google Scholar

Gilbert, R. A. (1986). Requiem for regulation Q: What it did and why it passed away. Federal Reserve of St Louis Rev, 68(2), 22, 25. https://doi.org/10.20955/r.68.22-37.zge.Search in Google Scholar

Goldberg, V. P. (1976). Regulation and administered contracts. The Bell Journal of Economics, 426. https://doi.org/10.2307/3003265.Search in Google Scholar

Goodhart, C., & Lastra, R. M. (2010). Border problems. Journal of International Economic Law, 13, 705. https://doi.org/10.1093/jiel/jgq042.Search in Google Scholar

Goodhart, C., … (1998). Financial regulation: Why, how and where now? (p. 50). Routledge.Search in Google Scholar

Gorton, Gary. (2010). Slapped by the invisible hand (p. 59). Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Gorton, G., & Metrick, A. (2012). Securitized banking and the run on repo. Journal of Financial Economics, 104, 425. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2011.03.016.Search in Google Scholar

Group on Financial Markets. (1999). Hedge funds, leverage, and the lessons of long-term capital management. GFM, 10–22. Retrieved from www.treasury.gov/resource-center/fin-mkts/Documents/hedgfund.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Guynn, R. D. (2012). Are bailouts inevitable? Yale Journal on Regulation, 121, 123–129.Search in Google Scholar

Henderson, M. T., & Tung, F. (2012). Pay for regulator performance. S Cal L Rev, 85, 1003, 1023–1026.10.2139/ssrn.1986484Search in Google Scholar

Hershey, R. D.Jr. (1973). Overnight mutual funds for surplus assets. NY Times (New York, 7 January 1973), 5.Search in Google Scholar

Houston, J. F., Lin, C., & Ma, Y. (2016). Regulatory arbitrage and international bank flows. The Journal of Finance, 67, 1845.10.1111/j.1540-6261.2012.01774.xSearch in Google Scholar

Jackson, B. F. (2013). Danger lurking in the shadows: Why regulators lack the authority to effectively fight contagion in the shadow banking system. Harvard Law Review, 127, 729.Search in Google Scholar

Kane, E. J. (1981). Accelerating inflation, technological innovation, and the decreasing effectiveness of banking regulation. The Journal of Finance, 36, 355. https://doi.org/10.3386/w0638.Search in Google Scholar

Keating, F., & Debroise, F. (2019). Fund finance in Luxembourg: The essentials. Ogier, 11 June 2019. Retrieved from https://www.ogier.com/publications/fund-finance-in-luxembourg-the-essentials.Search in Google Scholar

Kroszner, R. S., & Strahan, P. E. (2014). Regulation and deregulation of the US banking industry: Causes, consequences, and implications for the future. In N. L. Rose (Ed), Economic regulation and its reform: What have we learned (p. 485). University of Chicago Press.10.7208/chicago/9780226138169.003.0009Search in Google Scholar

Luck, S., & Schempp, P. (2014). Banks, shadow banking, and fragility. ECB Working Paper No. 1726, Retrieved from https://ssrn.com/abstract=2479948.10.2139/ssrn.2479948Search in Google Scholar

Macey, J. (2012). It’s all shadow banking, actually. Rev Banking & Financial L, 31, 593. https://doi.org/10.4324/9780203115992-9.Search in Google Scholar

Macey, J. R., & Holdcroft, J. P.Jr. (2011). Failure is an option: An Ersatz-Antitrust approach to financial regulation. The Yale Law Journal, 120, 1368, 1375–1378.Search in Google Scholar

MacKenzie, D. (2011). The credit crisis as a problem in the sociology of knowledge. American Journal of Sociology, 116, 1778. https://doi.org/10.1086/659639.Search in Google Scholar

Malatesta, F., Masciantonio, S., & Zaghini, A. (2016). The shadow banking system in the Euro area: Definitions, key features and the funding of firms. Italian Economic Journal, 2, 217. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40797-016-0032-0.Search in Google Scholar

Marjosola, H. (2019). The problem of regulatory arbitrage: A transaction cost economics perspective. University of Helsinki Working Paper.10.1111/rego.12287Search in Google Scholar

Merton, R. C. (1977). An analytical derivation of the cost of deposit insurance and loan guarantees. Journal of Banking & Finance, 1, 3.10.1016/0378-4266(77)90015-2Search in Google Scholar

Merton, R. C. (1995). Financial Innovation and the management and regulation on financial institutions. Journal of Banking & Finance19, 461.10.3386/w5096Search in Google Scholar

Merton, R. C., & Bodie, Z. (1993). Deposit insurance reform: A functional approach. In Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Pub. Pol’y. Vol. 1, (p. 38).10.1016/0167-2231(93)90014-NSearch in Google Scholar

Millo, Y. (2007). Making things deliverable: The origins of index-based derivatives. In M. Callon, F. Muniesa, & Y. Millo (Eds.), Market devices. Vol. 196, (p. 211). Wiley-Blackwell 2007.10.1111/j.1467-954X.2007.00736.xSearch in Google Scholar

Minsky, H. (1986). Stabilizing an unstable economy. Yale University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Minsky, H. (1992). The financial instability hypothesis. Jerome Levy Economics Institute Working Paper No. 74. Retrieved from https://ssrn.com/abstract=161024.Search in Google Scholar

Munday, S., Hu, W., True, T., & Zhang, J. (2018). Performance of private credit funds: A first look. Journal of Alternative Investments, 21(2), 31, 2. https://doi.org/10.3905/jai.2018.21.2.031.Search in Google Scholar

Norton, J., & Leese, B. J. (2019). The global private credit market: 2019 update. Lending & Secured Finance. Retrieved from https://iclg.com/practice-areas/lending-and-secured-finance-laws-and-regulations/19-the-global-private-credit-market-2019-update.Search in Google Scholar

Omorova, S. T. (2012). License to deal: Mandatory approval of complex financial products. Wash U L Rev, 90, 63, 113–139.10.2139/ssrn.1996755Search in Google Scholar

Partnoy, F. (1997). Financial derivatives and the costs of regulatory arbitrage. J Corp L, 22, 211, 227.Search in Google Scholar

Pistor, K. (2010). Host’s dilemma: Rethinking EU banking regulation in light of the global crisis.ECGI Working Paper No. 286/2010, Retrieved from https://ssrn.com/abstract=1631940.10.1515/9783899496321.2339Search in Google Scholar

Posner, E., & Weyl, E. G. (2013). An FDA for financial innovation: Applying the insurable interest Doctrine to 21st century financial markets. Nw U L Rev, 107, 1307.10.2139/ssrn.2010606Search in Google Scholar

Ricks, M. (2010). Shadow banking and financial innovation. Columbia Law and Economics Working Paper No 370. Retrieved from https://ssrn.com/abstract=1571290.10.2139/ssrn.1571290Search in Google Scholar

Ricks, M. (2016). The money problem. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.10.7208/chicago/9780226330464.001.0001Search in Google Scholar

Ricks, M. (2018). The money problem: A rejoinder. Accounting, Economics, and Law, 1, 8. https://doi.org/10.1515/ael-2018-0018.Search in Google Scholar

Riles, A. (2015). Managing regulatory arbitrage: A conflict of laws approach. Cornell Int’l LJ, 47, 63, 66.10.2139/ssrn.2335338Search in Google Scholar

Schwarcz, S. L. (2013). Regulating shadows: Financial regulation and responsibility failure. Washington and Lee Law Review, 70, 1781.Search in Google Scholar

Schwarcz, S. L. (2014). The governance structure of shadow banking: Rethinking assumptions about limited liability. The Notre Dame Law Review, 90, 1.10.2139/ssrn.2364126Search in Google Scholar

Schweikhard, F. A., & Tsesmelidakis, Z. (2012). The Impact of government Interventions on CDS and equity markets. American Finance Association 2012 Chicago Meetings Working Paper. Retrieved from http://ssrn.com/abstract=1573377.10.2139/ssrn.2312183Search in Google Scholar

Tarullo, D. K. (2015). Thinking critically about nonbank financial intermediation. Speech given at the Brookings Institution (Washington, D.C., USA, 17 November 2015). Retrieved from https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/tarullo20151117a.htm.Search in Google Scholar

Thiemann, M. (2018). The growth of shadow banking: A comparative institutional analysis. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/9781316676837Search in Google Scholar

Thiemann, M., & Lepoutre, J. (2017). Stitched on the edge rule evasion, embedded regulators, and the evolution of markets. American Journal of Sociology, 122, 1775. https://doi.org/10.1086/691348.Search in Google Scholar

Tröger, T. H. (2014a). How special are they? Targeting systemic risk by regulation shadow banking. Research Center Sustainable Architecture for Finance in Europe (SAFE) Working Paper 68, 1–2. Retrieved from http://ssrn.com/abstract=2505909.Search in Google Scholar

Tröger, T. H. (2014b). The single supervisory mechanism – panacea or quack banking regulation? European Business Organization Law Review, 15, 449, 473–482.10.1017/S1566752914001244Search in Google Scholar

Tsesmelidakis, Z., & Merton, R. C. (2012). The value of implicit guarantees. Working Paper. Retrieved from http://ssrn.com/abstract=2231317.10.2139/ssrn.2312157Search in Google Scholar

Viñals, J., & Fiechter, J. (2010). The making of good supervision: Learning to say “no”. IMF Staff Position Note 05/2010.10.2139/ssrn.1670831Search in Google Scholar

White, L. J. (2009). The credit-rating agencies and the subprime debacle. Critical Review, 21, 389.10.1080/08913810902974964Search in Google Scholar

White, L. J. (2010). Markets: Credit rating agencies. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24, 211.10.1257/jep.24.2.211Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2020-07-24

© 2020 CONVIVIUM, association loi de 1901

Downloaded on 5.6.2023 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/ael-2019-0059/html
Scroll to top button