Skip to content
Publicly Available Published by De Gruyter March 24, 2015

Violence in Illicit Markets: Unintended Consequences and the Search for Paradoxical Effects of Enforcement

  • James E. Prieger EMAIL logo and Jonathan Kulick

Abstract

The textbook competitive model of drug markets predicts that greater law enforcement leads to higher black market prices, but also to the unintended consequences of greater revenue and violence. These predictions are not in accord with the paradoxical outcomes evinced by recent history in some drug markets, where enforcement rose even as prices fell. We show that predictions of the textbook model are not unequivocal, and that when bandwagon effects among scofflaws are introduced, the simple predictions are more likely to be reversed. We next show that even simple models of noncompetitive black markets can elicit paradoxical outcomes. Therefore, we argue that instead of searching for assumptions that lead to paradoxical outcomes, which is the direction the literature has taken, it is better for policy analysis to choose appropriate assumptions for the textbook model. We finish with performing such an analysis for the case of banning menthol cigarettes. Under the most plausible assumptions enforcement will indeed spur violence, although the legal availability of electronic cigarettes may mitigate or reverse this conclusion.

1 Introduction

The problem of violence in black markets for prohibited goods has vexed policymakers in the United States at least since Prohibition. While violence may be endemic in markets for any illegal or smuggled good, illicit drugs provide a prime example of the relationships between banning sale of a good and violence. Illicit drug markets are prone to violence because the high value of the illegal goods, coupled with the lack of recourse to the legal system to settle conflicts, creates instabilities, uncertainties, and distrust in the market (Miron and Zwiebel, 1995; Andreas and Wallman, 2009). This is exacerbated by illicit-market participants’ pre-existing experiences with violence; participants tend to be recruited from communities with above-average rates of violence (Moeller and Hesse, 2013).[1]

If violence stems from trafficking in illicit drugs, then it may seem that enforcement of laws against trafficking should reduce violent crime. However, both practical experience and economic theory show that enforcement against illegal activity in drug markets may have the unintended consequence of exacerbating violence. Systematic reviews of the empirical literature show that nearly all studies find evidence of an adverse impact of drug law enforcement on levels of violence (Werb et al. 2011; Hawken et al. 2013). The theoretical literature offers a number of explanations for why stricter enforcement targeting illicit drug markets might increase violence. To begin with, increased enforcement disrupts the market. Destabilizing established hierarchies renews competition, and violence can follow as participants jostle for exclusive territory (“turf”) and market share (Rasmussen and Benson, 1994; Costa Storti and De Grauwe, 2008; Papachristos, 2009) and try to deter entry (Levitt and Venkatesh, 2000). Furthermore, stricter enforcement increases the risk of detection and punishment, which in turn increases the risk premium and therefore profitability of sales (Kuziemko and Levitt, 2004). Revenue becomes worth fighting for: Increasing the share of total cost attributed to enforcement risk can increase the incentive for violence, because violence may deter enforcement agencies and potential informants (Caulkins et al. 2010; Kleiman, 2011). A third economic argument postulates that prohibition and enforcement lower the marginal cost of violence, since evading apprehension for violent crime is complementary to evading arrest for trafficking in the illicit good (Miron and Zwiebel, 1995).

This article explores the economic link between enforcement and violence in illicit markets. We begin with the “textbook analysis”:[2] enforcement, which is typically directed primarily at suppliers, raises opportunity costs by increasing risks for suppliers (Reuter and Kleiman, 1986) and shifts the supply curve up, and therefore raises prices. When demand is inelastic, as it typically is estimated to be for goods like illicit drugs and tobacco, revenue rises with the market price (Becker et al. 2006). Given the reasons mentioned above that violence might increase with illicit revenue, greater enforcement therefore can have the unintended consequence of increasing violence. The textbook analysis relies on straightforward arguments based on supply and demand, and the predictions are clear enough that many authors assume or assert that enforcement in black markets leads to more violence (e.g., Reuter and MacCoun, 1995). The textbook model of a competitive drug market lies at the heart of much applied policy research (Rydell and Everingham, 1994; Caulkins et al. 1997; Moore et al. 2005; Becker et al. 2006).

While higher revenue and violence are unintended consequences of enforcement, the experience of the 1980s and the first half of the 1990s showed that there can be paradoxical outcomes as well. That period was a time of greatly increased enforcement effort in the “War on Drugs” but also a time when the street prices of cocaine and heroin fell dramatically.[3] That so much enforcement effort, which mostly targeted the supply chain, was coincident with sharply falling prices is therefore a puzzle. The divorce between the theoretical predictions from the standard economic analysis and the reality on the streets sparked a vigorous effort among researchers to build models of black markets that exhibit paradoxical outcomes. Some research in this vein suggests or develops models in which additional enforcement causes prices to fall or quantities consumed to rise (e.g., Lee, 1993; Skott and Gepsen, 2002; Poret, 2003; Caulkins and Reuter, 2006; Jacobsson and Naranjo, 2009). Others look specifically at violence, and construct economic models in which more enforcement reduces violence through non-price channels (Caulkins et al. 2006). The latter finding is (perhaps paradoxically, to non-economists) also paradoxical, given that the textbook economic analysis predicts that additional enforcement increases violence.

Therefore, on the one hand, the textbook analysis offers simple predictions about how enforcement affects prices, revenues, and violence, while on the other hand, the “paradoxical outcomes” literature seeks models that internally generate opposite conclusions. In the textbook model, targeting supply for enforcement leads to a higher price and revenue, and therefore violence; there are no other issues complicating the simple analysis. When the standard competitive model is replaced with models embodying different assumptions, which include downward-sloping supply curves (Caulkins and Reuter, 2006), imperfectly competitive vertically differentiated supply chains (Poret, 2003), demand-side switching costs (Skott and Gepsen, 2002), market power over product demand characterized by contest success functions (Jacobsson and Naranjo, 2009), and enforcement that induces larger quantities per purchase (Lee, 1993), paradoxical outcomes instead are the result.

We re-examine both the textbook model and the “paradoxical outcomes” literature. We also discuss an application to menthol cigarettes, which face an imminent ban in the European Union and possible bans in the United States and Canada. We proceed in five steps, beginning with an examination of a model of a competitive illicit drug market. We first show that the textbook model is in reality more nuanced than is often presented. Whenever enforcement creates risks for buyers as well as sellers, inelastic demand is a necessary but no longer a sufficient condition for revenue and violence to rise with enforcement. When the demand curve itself moves, there is a countervailing demand-shifting effect that can reduce revenue even when demand is inelastic. Second, we derive a paradoxical outcome of our own: when there are bandwagon effects in abiding by the law, even though each scofflaw creates a negative externality for society by discouraging others from following the law, violence is less likely to rise with enforcement. Third, we show that non-standard assumptions about the primitives of the market are not required for models of illicit markets to exhibit paradoxical outcomes. In fact, the search for paradoxical outcomes is over almost before it begins; even the simplest noncompetitive models, monopolistic competition and Cournot oligopoly, lead to the literature’s “desired” paradoxical outcome that revenue and violence can fall with enforcement. Fourth, we therefore argue that instead of searching for assumptions that lead endogenously to desired modeling outcomes, it is most helpful for analysis of public policy to choose appropriate assumptions for the basic model.

We finish with performing such an analysis for the current policy issue of banning menthol cigarettes. The most plausible assumptions for this case are competitive markets, enforcement that will be aimed mostly at supplier instead of demanders, and a relatively inelastic supply function. Under these conditions, the demand-shifting effect from enforcement is small enough so that price, revenue, and violence all rise when enforcement increases. We conclude that it is likely that enforcement will indeed spur violence, although the legal availability of electronic cigarettes may mitigate or reverse this conclusion.

We proceed in the next section by examining the textbook model of an illicit market with two additional features, demand-side enforcement (which is sometimes omitted from the textbook analysis) and bandwagon effects among scofflaws. In Section 2 we show how the demand-shifting effect may reverse the typical textbook conclusions, and also show that bandwagon effects make such reversal more likely. In Section 3, we turn to a brief examination of three of the simplest models possible for illicit markets: the textbook competitive market (the model from Section 2 without the bandwagon effects), a monopolistically competitive market, and a Cournot oligopoly. No more than these three models is necessary to generate the full range of outcomes from supply-side enforcement: it increases revenue and violence in the competitive market, has no impact in the monopolistically competitive market when all enforcement is against suppliers, and decreases revenue and violence in the oligopolistic market. In Section 4, we return to competitive model and apply it to a potential prohibition on menthol cigarettes, showing that plausible choices for the parameters of the model imply that violence indeed increases with enforcement.

2 A Competitive Illicit Market with Bandwagon Effects

We present a relatively simple model of a black market characterized by enforcement action against trafficking in the good, violence driven by revenue in the market, and bandwagon effects among scofflaws. Like Becker et al. (2006) and Reuter and Kleiman (1986), we assume the illicit market is competitive. The model here is an extension of that examined in Prieger and Kulick (2014).

2.1 The Model

Consider a competitive market for an illicit drug. Enforcement against trafficking in the good is a continuous variable, e0. For analytical convenience, enforcement e is not differentiated according to the target (producer, importer, dealer, or user) and so represents total effort or money expended on law enforcement against trafficking. We do not, however, assume that enforcement targets only one side of the market or that it affects both sides equally, as will be made clear below. Instead, any difference in the amount of enforcement directed at the supply and demand sides is subsumed into the functions describing how total enforcement raises costs for suppliers and consumers. Section A.1 in the appendix formalizes this.

2.1.1 Supply

Each homogeneous seller has a cost function cqi with derivative cqi0 that represents the physical costs of procuring, processing, and distributing the good. Enforcement against the illicit market raises the effective cost of doing business by a multiple φe1. These additional costs include the monetization of the perceived risks of arrest, sanction, fine, and incarceration, as well as any supply-disruptive activity following from enforcement, such as product seizure, as discussed in Reuter and Kleiman (1986). The costs are created only by enforcement: we assume that φ0=1 and dφ/de0. We typically expect that φ rises with enforcement; the case dφ/de=0 pertains when enforcement is directed exclusively toward buyers.

Marginal production costs for each firm i are therefore φcqi, and the firm’s supply curve is qSipS=k1p/φ, where kq=cq.[4] Here, pS=p/φ is the net price sellers receive after accounting for enforcement risk, and price p is the monetary price exchanging hands in the market. Summing the firms’ supply curves yields the market supply curve, qSpS=iqSipS. Denote the supply elasticity with ηS=qSpSpS/qSpS. Defining ψ=φ1, the quantity supplied under enforcement is thus:

[1]QSp,e=qSψep

The properties of φ imply that ψe>0, ψ0=1 and dψ/de0.

The impact of enforcement on the supply curve is illustrated in Figure 1. With no enforcement, the supply curve is S0. Enforcement raises costs by multiple φ to new supply curve S1. Thus the quantity supplied at a price such as p′′ falls from qSp′′ to qSψp′′, as marked in the figure.

Figure 1: The impact of enforcement on equilibrium in a competitive market.
Figure 1:

The impact of enforcement on equilibrium in a competitive market.

2.1.2 Demand

In the absence of a ban, the market quantity demanded for the good is qD, a downward-sloping function of the market price. When the good is banned, there are two changes to demand. First, we assume that a fraction 0,1 of consumers are law-abiding, in the sense that, regardless of the street price of the banned good, they would never purchase any in an illicit market. These consumers either switch to legal substitutes or cease consuming altogether. We assume that the demand of these consumers is completely typical, so that after a ban the market demand curve for the illicit good is only 1 what it was before the ban.

Unlike Becker et al. (2006), who assume that all enforcement is on the supply side, we also consider demand-side impacts. As on the supply side, on the demand side we must also distinguish between the market price p and the inclusive price consumers must pay, pD. If enforcement affects buyers, then the perceived inclusive expenditure on the product is higher than the transacted market price p by a multiple ρe. This “risk tax” on buyers acts like an expenditure tax of rate ρ1. We assume the risk tax satisfies ρ0=1 and dρ/de0. We typically expect that ρ rises with enforcement; the case dρ/de=0 pertains only when enforcement is directed exclusively toward sellers. Thus reflects moral, religious, or social reasons for reduction in market demand, while ρ incorporates the direct impact of economic disincentives to consume, such as the expected legal consequences, to reduce demand.

Demand elasticity is ηD=qDpDpD/qDpD>0, and, in keeping with much of the literature on addictive substances, demand is presumed to be inelastic: 0ηD<1. We justify this assumption for our application to cigarette markets below in Section 4. The quantity demanded at black market monetary price p, accounting for buyers’ risk from enforcement and the loss of the law abiders from the market, is:

[2]QDp,e=1qDρep

There are bandwagon effects among scofflaws: the more the illegal good is consumed in the market, the lower the fraction of consumers who abide by the law.[5] The bandwagon effects may come from social considerations (“if everyone is breaking the law, why shouldn’t I?”) or the rational calculation that for any given amount of enforcement, the expected cost to the violator of detection and punishment of illegal activity must fall (Kleiman’s (1993) “enforcement swamping” effect). We take fraction to be a downward sloping function of QD, with limQD0. Thus eq. [2] only implicitly defines QD, since it enters the right side through QD.

The impact of enforcement on the demand curve is illustrated in Figure 1. With no enforcement, the demand curve is D0. If were identically zero, then enforcement raises costs by multiple ρ, shifting the demand curve in to D1. When is nonzero as assumed above, then the demand curve shifts again to the left by amount qD, to D2. The amount of the shift at any given price depends on , which increases at quantity demanded increases. Thus, <′′ as drawn on the graph.

2.1.3 Violence

Since the insights of Goldstein (1985), it is common in models of illicit drug markets to assume that violence rises with illicit revenue R earned in the market. We thus assume that violence can be measured with a function V that is strictly increasing in R. We set aside any direct beneficial effect of enforcement effort on violence (V/e=0), since we model specific enforcement against trafficking and not general law enforcement against violent crime.

2.2 The Impact of Enforcement on Violence

Now we examine how prices, revenue, and violence change as enforcement activity increases.

2.2.1 Impact on Market Price

Define excess demand as

[3]Gp,e=QDp,eQSp,e

Then applying the implicit function theorem to the equilibrium condition Gp,e=0 gives an expression for how the equilibrium price changes with enforcement:

[4]dpde=G/eG/p=p(ωSψ/ψsupply-side effect+[ωDρ/ρ1+(QD)qD]demand-sideeffect)

where ωD=ηD/ηD+ηS, ωS=1ωD, and the elasticities are understood to be evaluated at the effective prices ρp and ψp (see Appendix for proof). As labeled, enforcement creates supply-side and demand-side effects.

2.2.1.1 The Supply-Side Effect

The supply-side effect is positive since ψ is decreasing in e, assuming the supply curve does not slope down. Enforcement raises costs on the supply side and shifts the supply curve up, increasing the equilibrium price. This is the (only) outcome of the textbook model with supply-side enforcement only. The decrease in quantity and the increase in price from the supply-side effect in isolation is shown in Figure 1 with the movement from point A to point B on the graph.

2.2.1.2 The Demand-Side Effect

The demand-side effect in expression [4] is negative. We distinguish two cases. Case 1 applies when there are no bandwagon effects. Without contagion among scofflaws, =0 and so the demand-side effect is clearly negative. This corresponds to the simple textbook case of enforcement shifting the demand curve down, so that the equilibrium price falls in response to demand-side enforcement. In Figure 1, this corresponds to moving from point B to point C on the graph.

Case 2 is for when the bandwagon effect is present. However, we exclude the possibility that QDqD1, which would imply that the bandwagon effects are so strong that demand function QD slopes up in price.[6] In this case, the demand-side effect in expression [4] remains negative. However, since the denominator of the demand-side effect is smaller than in case 1, the bandwagon effect amplifies the demand-side effect. The decrease in demand causes the quantity consumed to fall. When scofflaws respond to total demand, some of them will “fall off the bandwagon,” rises, and total demand QD falls even further. The greater fall in quantity from the bandwagon effect is depicted in Figure 1. Starting from point B, the risk tax alone moves equilibrium from point B to point C, and then the bandwagon effect moves equilibrium further to point D.

2.2.1.3 The Total Effect on Price

The sign of dp/de is determined by the relative magnitudes of the demand- and supply-side effects on price. The appendix shows that the sign of the expression in [4] is positive, so that

[5]dpde>0ηDϵρ1+qD<ηSϵψ

where ϵf is the elasticity of function f with respect to enforcement. Both sides of the inequality on the right side of [5] are positive. The left side captures the demand-side price sensitivity to changes in enforcement, while the right side reflects the supply side. Whether the market price will increase with marginal increases in enforcement depends on the relative magnitudes involved. Thus, when enforcement has demand-side effects in addition to those on the supply side, enforcement can lead to higher or lower prices. The price effect of increased enforcement is ambiguous in general. If demand is elastic enough, consumers are highly sensitive to enforcement risk, or bandwagon effects are strong enough, the demand-side effects can cause the market price to fall. The opposite case is depicted in Figure 1, where moving from the initial, no-enforcement equilibrium at point A to the equilibrium with enforcement at point D increases the price.

2.2.2 Impact on Revenue

If the demand curve does not shift, and demand is inelastic as assumed, then the direction of the price change alone determines how revenue and violence change. However, when the demand curve shifts downward in response to enforcement, there is a countervailing effect on revenue. Equilibrium revenue can be written as R=pˆQDpˆ,e, where pˆ is the equilibrium price given enforcement level e. The total impact on violence of a marginal change in enforcement level is

[6]dVde=dVdRdRde=dVdRdpˆdeQ+pˆQDpdpˆde+QDe=dVdRQ+pˆQDpdpˆdepriceeffect+pˆQDedemand\hypshiftingeffect

We have dV/dR>0 by assumption. The first term in the brackets in the final expression in eq. [6] is the price effect. When enforcement rises, the price changes in accord with eq. [5], which has a marginal impact on revenue. The term in parentheses in the price effect is the usual marginal revenue term for an increase in price. For the assumed inelastic demand, where ηD<1, this term is always positive:

[7]Q+pˆQDp=Q1ηD>0

Thus, with only supply-side enforcement, revenues changes in the same direction as price. This is usually assumed in the textbook analysis of illicit markets and violence.[7]

However, the second term in eq. [6], the direct impact of enforcement on the demand curve (the “demand-shifting” effect, or DSE) is negative whenever enforcement has any effect on consumers (so that ϵρ>0). From implicit differentiation of eq. [2], we can derive:

[8]DSE=pˆQDe=ηDRϵρe1+QDqD<0

where it is again assumed that bandwagon effects are mild enough that the expression in square brackets is positive (see the appendix for derivation). This term is the offsetting effect on revenue of the demand curve shifting down in response to enforcement risk. Thus, even when the sign on the price change is clear from inequality [4], the total effect on revenue and violence is ambiguous. If the DSE is great enough, revenue falls in response to a price increase even with inelastic demand.

Note that the presence of bandwagon effects in demand can lead to a paradoxical result. At first blush, bandwagon effects among scofflaws would appear to work against policymakers wishing to reduce consumption of the illicit good. Each scofflaw creates a negative externality for society (assuming consumption is indeed socially harmful) by discouraging others from following the law. However, the existence of the bandwagon effect makes the DSE larger and therefore makes it easier for prices to fall. Revenue and violence are therefore less likely to rise with enforcement when there are bandwagon effects.

3 Three Simple Models Yielding All Possible Outcomes

In this section, we compare the impact of enforcement on violence with three models of competition. The results show that non-standard assumptions tailored to the unique characteristics of particular drug markets are not required to generate the full range of outcomes regarding enforcement and violence. For simplicity, and to make clear that the conclusions are not driven by any non-standard assumptions, here we assume all consumers are scofflaws. If buyers care only about the direct economic incentives provided by consumption and risk, there is no bandwagon effect, and ==0.

3.1 The Competitive Model without Bandwagon Effects

Setting aside the bandwagon effect, the condition for the effect of enforcement on market price from [5] is:

[9]dpde>0ηDϵρ<ηSϵψ

Rearranging terms, this condition for a positive price change can be expressed as:

[10]ηDηS<ϵψϵρ

Recalling that ϵψ<0, it is thus sufficient for the market price to rise with more enforcement that (1) demand be less elastic than supply and (2) enforcement have more impact on the supply side than on the demand side, as measured by the impacts on risk-adjusted prices given by the elasticity ratios on the right side. The appendix shows that the latter condition holds when the proportion of enforcement directed at the demand side is small.

The condition for the total effect of enforcement on revenue (the part inside the square brackets in eq. [6]), expressed as a revenue elasticity, can be written as:

[11]dRdeeR=ωD1+ηSϵρωS1ηDϵψ

(see the appendix), where ωD and are as defined above after eq. [4]. The first term is negative and the second term is positive if demand is inelastic. This expression is positive if and only if

[12]ηDϵρ<ηSϵψ1ηD1+ηS

Comparing this condition with inequality [10], we see that the condition for revenue and therefore violence to rise with enforcement is stricter than the condition for price to rise.[8] This is because the demand shifting effect in the revenue impact is always negative. Examination of condition [12] shows that inelastic demand is a necessary but not sufficient condition for violence to rise with enforcement. We therefore consider various market situations.

3.1.1 Case 1: No Direct Enforcement on Consumers

If enforcement is focused entirely on suppliers and consumers are left alone, then ϵρ=0, conditions [10] and [12] are satisfied. Prices and violence both rise with enforcement effort. This is the textbook analysis, depicted in Figure 1 with the movement from point A to point B.

3.1.2 Case 2: The Long Run in a Constant-Cost Industry

In the long run in a competitive constant-cost industry the supply curve is horizontal. With infinite ηS, inequality [10] is satisfied and greater enforcement of a ban leads to higher prices. The limit of condition [12] as supply becomes infinitely elastic is

[13]ηD1ηD<ϵψϵρ

which is easier to satisfy the more inelastic is demand or the higher the supplier-side enforcement elasticity is relative to the consumer-side enforcement elasticity. As Section A.1 in the Appendix shows, the ratio on the right side will be large when there is little demand-side enforcement.

3.1.3 Case 3: Completely Inelastic Demand

If all consumers with any sensitivity to price (at least in the relevant range of market prices) have left the market, then the demand curve is vertical. In the drug literature, it is sometimes assumed for simplicity that the hardest-core addicts have completely inelastic demand.[9] Then since ηD=0, inequality [12] is satisfied and violence rises with enforcement.

3.2 Monopolistic Competition

If consumers in the black market do not in fact treat goods sold by different sellers as identical, then a model with market power on the part of sellers becomes appropriate. Perhaps the simplest such model is the monopolistic competition model of Dixit and Stiglitz (1977). There is a continuum of sellers of measure n, with the quantity sold by seller ι denoted qι. The representative consumer likes variety, and views any two of the goods as equally substitutable. A taste for variety may seem to be an odd assumption for black-market drugs, in which many users cultivate exclusive relationships with dealers. However, given that sellers in drug markets often have geographical monopolies (their “turf”) and that buyers are geographically distributed, in the aggregate a taste for variety for the fictional representative consumer is appropriate. In the most basic form of the monopolistic competition model,[10] the utility of the representative consumer is

[14]U=q01μ0nqιrdι1rμ

where q0 is the outside good representing all purchases made outside the black market. Here, r measures the substitutability between the goods of the black market sellers and parameter μ is between zero and one. As in the perfect competition model, the monetary price of each good, pι, is marked up to include enforcement risk (if any) so that the consumer treats the price as being ρepι.

While it is possible to solve for the profit-maximizing quantities offered for sale by each firm, the equilibrium price, and the resulting equilibrium revenue, the simple form of preferences in eq. [14] makes the calculations unnecessary. Given the Cobb–Douglas form of preferences for the outside good and the composite black market good defined by the expression within the square brackets of eq. [14], it follows that parameter μ is the share of the consumer’s income I spent on black market goods. Since the risk tax from demand-side enforcement raises the effective price for the consumer to ρp, total expenditure (including the psychic “payment”) of μI yields total (monetary) revenue in the black market of only μI/ρ.[11] Therefore the impact of enforcement on violence is:

[15]dVde=dVdRdRde=dVdRμIρ2ρe=dVdRμIeρϵρ0

That is, violence falls when enforcement increases, as long as consumers are sensitive in any way to enforcement. If there is no demand-side enforcement, then violence does not change at all when enforcement ramps up. Supply-side enforcement plays no role in these results, for while raising cost on the supply side changes price, quantities, and profits in equilibrium (as well as the number of suppliers if entry is free), prices and total quantity purchased are offset in such a manner that revenue remains unaffected by the supply side. Under the assumption that all enforcement is on the supply side, therefore, the standard monopolistic competition model implies that enforcement has no effect on violence, regardless of the elasticity of demand.[12]

3.3 Cournot Oligopoly

Some authors use the Cournot oligopoly model of quantity setting to model imperfect competition in black markets (e.g., Chiu et al. 1998; Poret, 2003, 2009; Jacobsson and Naranjo, 2009). In contrast to the monopolistic competition model, consumers view the goods sold by different sellers as perfectly substitutable. On the supply side, sellers exercise market power and raise their profits by limiting the quantities they put on the market. The restricted quantities drive the price up, raising profits for all sellers. As opposed to the model of monopolistic competition, in which sellers choose a price for their goods and the quantity sold is determined by demand, a Cournot seller chooses an amount of product to put on the market and the price (common to all goods) is determined from inverse market demand for the total quantity produced. The notion of supply elasticity is meaningless in a market in which firms exercise market power, because firms do not have a supply function. Therefore, the Nash equilibrium of the quantity-setting game must be found in order to derive a condition analogous to condition [12] for violence to rise with enforcement.

Inverse market demand, from eq. [2], is

[16]PQ,e=fQ/ρe

where Q=qi and f=qD1. To guarantee the existence of a Nash equilibrium, we assume that the Novshek (1985) conditions are satisfied.[13] In the symmetric Cournot model with undifferentiated demand, the profit function for each of n firms is

[17]πiqi,e=qiPQ,eφecqi

where as in the competitive model, φ is the cost multiple from enforcement risk and c is the firm’s cost function. Then the condition for the profit maximizing choice of quantity, qic, is

[18]PQ,eφcqicPQ,e=siρηD=1nρηD

where si is the seller’s market share, qic/Q. This is the familiar Cournot markup condition (derived in the appendix), modified only by the introduction of enforcement risk. The second equality follows from the symmetry of the Nash equilibrium. Equation [18] implicitly defines the market quantity Qc=qic in equilibrium, from which the market price and revenue can be derived.

Now examine how revenue varies with enforcement. Since equilibrium market revenue is RQce=PQce,eQce, we have

[19]dRde=dRdQcdQcde=dRdQci=1ndqicde

The first term is marginal revenue, which must be positive for the Cournot model; firms restrict quantity until demand is in the elastic range. An expression for dqic/de is derived in the appendix. Putting the pieces together, under standard assumptions about the concavity of the profit function it can be shown that the condition for revenue to fall with enforcement is

[20]dRde<0ρeρeMRi<φecqic

where MRi is marginal revenue for firm i. However, since ρ>0, MRi>0, φ>0, and c>0, this condition is always satisfied. Thus revenue, and therefore violence, always falls in the Cournot model when enforcement increases. This result does not depend on the elasticity of supply or demand,[14] and holds whether all enforcement is on the demand side (in which case the right side of the inequality in expression [20] is zero), all enforcement is on the supply side (in which case the left side of the inequality in expression [20] is zero), or enforcement is mixed.

4 Discussion and Application to Tobacco Control

The examination of the simple models for competitive, monopolistically competitive, and oligopolistic markets in the previous section reveals that these three models cover all possible outcomes for the impact of enforcement on violence in illicit markets. For example, consider the case in which all enforcement is on the supply side. The first model predicts unequivocally that revenue and violence increase with enforcement, the second yields the irrelevance result that there is no impact at all, and the third predicts unequivocally that revenue and violence decrease with enforcement. Therefore one need not include non-standard assumptions about the workings of illicit drug markets to find any outcome, paradoxical or not.[15]

Plausible reasons for the great decline of prices in major illicit drug markets in the last 35 years appear to be readily at hand without recourse to models of non-competitive markets or other departures from standard assumptions. It is likely that improvements in crop yields have driven down the supply curve in illicit drug markets. Given the illicit nature of the markets, hard data on production and supply-side costs are unavailable. However, some evidence suggests that the yields of illicit crops have increased dramatically. For example, Mejía and Posada (2008) report that a UN study found that there was a 40% increase in the yields of coca (the raw ingredient for cocaine) per hectare in the early 2000s. In addition to the direct impact on the cost curves for cocaine, another benefit of increased productivity for producers of illicit crops is that supply can be grown on smaller plots of land, making aerial discovery and eradication by law enforcement more difficult. The reduced risks of eradication further lower the cost curves. Such exogenous changes in supply could easily negate or overwhelm the direct impact of enforcement on the supply curve.

Furthermore, the presence of exogenous supply shifters does not change the basic message from the analysis of the competitive market above: more enforcement still leads to more violence, ceteris paribus. That fact that in reality other things were not held constant does not falsify the model or reduce its utility for policy analysis. The competitive model has two advantages for purposes of presenting policy analysis to policymakers. Given the widespread familiarity of the Marshallian cross among even non-economists, the reasoning behind the results can be readily understood by most policymakers. This is the main reason that the textbook model is applied so often in policy research (Rydell and Everingham, 1994; Caulkins et al. 1997; Moore et al. 2005; Becker et al. 2006). Furthermore, the prediction of the model that greater enforcement leads to more violence is in accord with nearly all of the empirical literature, as discussed in the introduction. We now consider the competitive model’s predictions regarding violence resulting from enforcement of a ban on menthol cigarettes.

Menthol cigarettes are facing possible prohibition by the FDA in the United States (Tavernise, 2013), an imminent ban in the European Union (Dalton and Esterl, 2013), and a current ban in Brazil.[16] Menthol cigarettes constitute about one-third of the overall US cigarette market (O’Connor et al. 2012) and account for approximately $25 billion in annual retail sales (Esterl, 2011). If menthol is banned in cigarettes, consumers will either quit tobacco altogether, switch to non-menthol cigarettes, switch to other mentholated tobacco products,[17] or continue consumption illegally on the black market.[18]O’Connor et al. (2012) report that 25% of menthol smokers said they would “find a way to buy a menthol brand,” indicating their willingness to purchase menthol cigarettes on the black market. Given the likely underreporting of illegal intentions, this estimate is probably understated, possibly to a large degree. Tobacco-company representatives and industry-supported studies argue that severe negative impacts on public health, criminal activity, and tax revenues will ensue should a menthol ban pass, while anti-tobacco proponents contend that benefits to public health outweigh the possible social harms.[19] In the remainder of this article, we comment on the likely link between enforcement against trafficking in illicit menthol cigarettes and violence.

To apply an economic model to cigarettes, four aspects of the market and model require consideration: competition, the nature of enforcement, the elasticities involved, and the possibility of large exogenous shifts in supply. Modeling the market as competitive appears to be appropriate, for several reasons. Moeller and Hesse (2013) assert that low levels of enforcement tend to result in monopolistic markets, dominated by a few well-organized suppliers. The crackdown on tobacco smuggling in the United States, however, has had the opposite effect of shifting supply toward smaller enterprises.[20] Furthermore, Reuter (1983) argues that concentration is unusual in illegal drug markets because pressure from law enforcement stimulates competition among suppliers. Finally, any noncompetitive model requires that demand be in its elastic region, which does not appear to apply to illicit drug markets[21] or (as will be noted below) the cigarette markets we consider here. The assumption that demand for any single supplier’s product is elastic is defensible, and indeed is a feature in all three models considered here.[22] However, the requirement that market demand in aggregate be elastic – as in the Cournot model – appears to be untenable. For all these reasons, we adopt the competitive model for our policy analysis.

We may expect that enforcement against trafficking in menthol cigarettes would follow the pattern set by current practice aimed at smuggled tobacco products, which is to target suppliers. As with other illicit drug markets, nearly all enforcement effort is expended to disrupt supply in the market for illegal cigarettes. While possession of illegal cigarettes is also a crime for buyers, law-enforcement agencies such as the Bureau of Alcohol, Tobacco, Firearms and Explosives (ATF) typically focus their investigations on suppliers to reduce the incidence of organized crime (USDOJ OIG, 2009). Furthermore, Miron and Zwiebel (1995) argue that the supply-side effects of enforcement in illicit drug markets are likely to be much larger than the demand-side effects.

Demand for smoking cigarettes is generally measured to be inelastic. Chaloupka and Warner (2000) summarize the literature (after excluding a few outlying studies) as finding results in the relatively narrow band of demand elasticities between −0.3 and −0.5. More recent work by Chiou and Muehlegger (2008) also finds demand elasticities in the same inelastic range (−0.29 to −0.56). For menthol cigarettes in particular, Tauras et al. (2010) conclude that “menthol and non-menthol cigarettes are not close substitutes” (p. 121), based on an econometric estimate of the switching elasticity between the two.[23] Given that illegal menthol cigarettes would not be subject to the high taxes levied on legal cigarettes, the illegal product may not be much more expensive – or may even be cheaper – than the legal substitute. A small price increase (if any) and lack of close substitutes[24] thus suggest that a ban on menthol cigarettes may not decrease demand for them much.[25] We revisit the assumption regarding a lack of good substitutes below when discussing electronic cigarettes.

What about bandwagon effects in illicit consumption? There is a large but also largely unconvincing literature across the social sciences purporting to find peer effects in illicit drug use, smoking, drinking, and criminal behavior, typically among youths or college students. However, until recently most studies did not adequately control for the severe self-selection problems inherent in such research.[26]Duncan et al. (2005) draw on the natural experiment provided by random assignment of roommates in college dormitories to conclude that peer effects exist for binge drinking but not for marijuana use. Sacerdote (2014) summarizes the best-designed recent studies on peer effects as suggesting that peer effects on social outcomes such as crime and drinking are larger than on educational achievement, but nevertheless cautions that not enough is yet known about peer effects to shape policy around them. Almost nothing is known about peer or bandwagon effects among adults. For these reasons, we set aside the bandwagon effect for our analysis and instead use the simpler competitive model from Section 3, although as more research becomes available on herding behavior and peer effects in illegal activity this may be a fruitful area of research to revisit.

Inequality [10] shows that if, as argued above, enforcement has more impact on the supply side, then if demand is less elastic than supply the market price must rise with enforcement. We have argued above that demand is relatively inelastic. Supply is likely to be more elastic in cigarette markets, particularly in the long run, although estimates of supply elasticities are rarer than for demand. There are no great diseconomies of scale in the tobacco-products industry, and the supply of unprocessed tobacco leaves is elastic.[27]Sumner and Wohlgenant (1985) found in a rigorous study of supply and demand conditions for cigarettes in the United States that “the derived supply curve for cigarettes is nearly horizontal” (p. 241), even when the domestic supply of raw tobacco is inelastic due to agricultural quotas. Given the easy conversion from producing menthol to non-menthol cigarettes, it is quite likely that the supply function for menthol cigarettes is similarly highly elastic, or at the very least elastic relative to demand.

Under these conditions – competitive markets, enforcement aimed mostly at the supply side, and more elastic supply than demand – the analysis in Section 3.1 shows that violence increases with enforcement. Under these conditions, the demand-shifting effect is small enough so that revenue and price both rise when enforcement increases. Thus, we conclude that the social calculus regarding a ban on menthol cigarette should include the likelihood that enforcement will create violence in the market, and that higher levels of enforcement will engender greater amounts of violence. As with cocaine and heroin, exogenous supply shifters may confound this analysis. However, radical exogenous cost reductions appear to be unlikely in the markets for illicit tobacco, since the crop is grown legally in the United States with well established, modern methods of farming, and would continue to be so after a ban on menthol cigarettes. Crop yields of tobacco in the US grew an average of only 0.5% per annum from 1980 to 2012.[28]

The results from the modeling exercise do not allow precise prediction of the scale of violence that might result from any given level of enforcement. However, it is reasonable to expect that larger markets are associated with more violence. Given that the current market for menthol cigarettes is larger than the illicit markets for heroin or methamphetamine, the potential for violence from banning menthol cigarettes is not trivial.[29]

One important policy decision may change the conclusions of the analysis above. The growing market for the presently unregulated electronic cigarettes (“e-cigarettes”) poses interesting policy questions, and the FDA is currently deciding whether to regulate e-cigarettes.[30] E-cigarettes, which are currently unregulated, can also be mentholated. If menthol e-cigarettes were not subject to the same usage restrictions as combustible cigarettes, the elasticity of demand for banned menthol cigarettes would likely rise in the presence of the substitute, because e-cigarettes create a user experience quite similar to that of combustible menthol cigarettes. This might have two consequences. Without a highly inelastic demand for the banned good, prices and revenues might not rise (or might not rise as much) in the illicit market, removing or attenuating the deleterious effect of enforcement on violence. Furthermore, e-cigarettes can likely reduce the harm of smoking or provide an “exit ramp” from smoking altogether for some smokers. Research on the health effects of e-cigarettes is ongoing, but the available evidence suggests that they are not as harmful to the smoker’s health as combustible cigarettes (Cahn and Siegel, 2011; Hajek et al. 2014).[31] The relationship between an individual’s use of electronic and combustible cigarettes is also nascent, but some studies indicate that e-cigarettes may aid in cessation of smoking (Hajek et al. 2014; Biener and Hargraves, forthcoming).[32] However, if the FDA were to regulate e-cigarettes or ban menthol e-cigarettes in addition to a ban on combustible menthol cigarettes, this potentially beneficial exit ramp will be closed.[33]

The unintended consequence of enforcement leading to violence does not, by itself, mean that access to menthol cigarettes (or any other drug) should be unrestricted. A complete cost–benefit analysis of a ban is beyond the scope of this paper. Furthermore, if the good is banned, our conclusion does not imply that the optimal level of enforcement is zero. Optimal enforcement under simple assumptions has been considered by Becker et al. (2006) and Poret (2009). However, Caulkins and Reuter (2010) and Feichtinger and Tragler (2001) contend that there are multiple equilibria to which the regulation/enforcement system may settle, due to path dependency. Thus, the question of optimal enforcement may be much more complex than previous analyses have indicated.

Funding statement: Funding: This study was funded by Cornerstone Research under contract to Altria Client Services. The funding source had no role in the writing of these papers and exercised no editorial control.

Appendix

A.1 A.1 Enforcement Targeting

In the model, any differential between the impact of enforcement on suppliers and demanders is subsumed into the functions ρ and ψ, so that we can think of the ratio ϵψ/ϵρ (as from inequality [13]) as being large when most of the enforcement is on the supply side. The justification for this is provided here.

Assume that fraction α of total enforcement e is directed toward the demand side, and define eD=αe to be the amount of demand-side enforcement. Let ρ˜eD be the “risk tax” on buyers as a function of demand-side enforcement. Then the risk tax function in the text is ρe=ρ˜αe, and clearly the elasticity of ρ˜ with respect to eD equals ϵρ. Denote the former elasticity with ϵρ˜. Assuming that the derivative of ρ˜ is finite at eD=0 and is continuous, ϵρ˜ can be made arbitrarily small by making α small, because ϵρ˜=eDρ˜eD/ρ˜eD and ρ˜0=1 by assumption. Thus, when few resources are devoted to demand-side enforcement, so that α and eD are small, ϵρ˜ and therefore ϵρ are small.

A.2 A.2 Perfect Competition Model

Given the distinction between market and effective prices, two identities will be useful for the derivations to follow. When evaluated at effective price ρp, we have ηDρp=ρpqDρp/QD by definition of demand elasticity ηD above. Hence,

[21]pqD=ηDqD/ρ

where qD and qD are understood to be evaluated at effective price ρp. Similarly, we also have

[22]pqS=ηSqS/ψ

where qS and qS are evaluated at effective price ψp.

A.2.1 A.2.1 Derivation of the DSE, eq. [8]

Define qˆDρe and QˆDe to be the pre- and post-ban demand functions when treated as functions of e alone, holding price fixed. Total differentiation of the equation QˆD=1QDqˆDρe yields

dQˆD=QˆDdQˆDqˆD+1QˆDqˆDepρede

Rearranging terms gives

[23]dQˆDde=1QˆDpqˆDeρe1+QˆDqˆD

Dropping the hats on QD and qD to allow p to vary again, and therefore writing the derivative as a partial instead of a total allows derivative [23] to be written as

[24]QDe=1ηDqDϵρ/e1+QDqD

where identity [21] and ϵρ=ρee/ρ are used. After substituting QˆD for 1qˆD in the numerator of the right side, and then substituting revenue R for pQD, eq. [8] for the DSE follows directly from eq. [24] multiplied by p.

A.2.2 A.2.2 Derivation of dp/de, eq. [4]

Using definitions [1] and [2], excess demand from eq. [3] changes with price as:

[25]Gp=1qDρpρqSψpψ

Using identities [21] and [22], this can be written

[26]Gp=1qDρpρqSψpψ

Excess demand from eq. [3] changes with enforcement as:

[27]Ge=QDeeqSψep=QDeqSpψ

Making use of eqs [22] and [24], this is

[28]Ge=1ηDqDρ/ρ1+qDηSqSψ/ψ

Combining eqs [26] and [28] via the implicit function theorem yields:

[29]dpde=G/eG/p=1qDηDρ/ρ1+qDqSηSψ/ψ1qDηDpqSηS/p

Using eqs [1] and [2] and recognizing that QD=QS in equilibrium transforms [29] into:

[30]dpde=pηDρ/ρ1+qDηSψ/ψηD+ηS

With ωD=ηD/ηD+ηS and ωS=1ωD, eq. [30] can be written as in eq. [4].

A.2.3 A.2.3 Derivation of the condition for dp/de >0, inequality [5]

The denominator of [29], G/p, is clearly negative if supply does not slope up. Therefore the sign of [29] is the same as the sign of the numerator G/e. Using eqs [1] and [2] and recognizing that QD=QS=Q in equilibrium transforms eq. [28] into

[31]Ge=ηDρ/ρ1+qDηSψ/ψQ

Converting the enforcement cost function expression to elasticities and dividing by Q, we see that [31] has the same sign as

ηDϵρ/e1+qDηSϵψ/e

Dividing by e, we arrive at condition (5).

A.2.4 A.2.4 Derivation of the revenue effect without bandwagon effects, eq. [11] and inequality [12]

The revenue effect of a price change, from (6), is

[32]dRde=Q+pˆQDpdpˆde+pˆQDe=R1ηDωDρρ+ωSψψηDRϵρ

where eqs [4], [7], and [8] are used for the latter equality. Using elasticities for all expressions involving derivatives yields:

[33]dRdeeR=1ηDωDϵρ+ωSϵψηDϵρ

After combining the terms involving ϵρ, eq. [11] follows. Inequality [12] follows directly from multiplying the right side of eq. [11] by ηD+ηS.

A.3 A.3 Cournot Model

A.3.1 A.3.1 Derivation of FOC for Profit Maximization

Define Riqi,qi=qifqi+qi/ρ as revenue for firm i, where qi=jiqj and inverse demand is from eq. [16]. From the profit function [17], the first-order condition for profit maximization given e is:

[34]πiqi,eqi=Riqi,qiqiφecqi=0

where under the Nash assumption that other sellers’ quantities are invariant to changes in qi we have

[35]Riqi,qiqi=MRi=wfQ+qifQ=P+qifQ

In the expression, for convenience w=1/ρ. From the inverse function theorem and eq. [21], fQ=P/wηDQ, and so we have

[36]MRi=P1qiQwηD=P1siwηD

Combining [34] and [36] yields

[37]P1siwηDφecqi=0PφcP=siwηD

from which the Cournot markup condition [18] readily follows. Incidentally, the equation on the left side of [37] also shows that MRi must be positive.

A.3.2 A.3.2 Derivation of dqic/de and dR/de, expression [20]

To derive dqic/de, first write the first-order condition [34] as:

[38]PQ,eφc+qicPQ=0

Then apply the implicit function theorem to eq. [38] to yield:

[39]dqicde=Peφc+qic2PQen+1PQ+φc′′qicn2PQ2

Under standard assumptions for the existence of Cournot Nash equilibrium, discussed below, the denominator of eq. [39] is positive and the sign of dqic/de is determined by the numerator. Recall that w=ρ1. Then, since from [16] we have PQ,e=wefQ, the numerator of [39] is

[40]wfφc+qicwf=wwwf+qicfφc=wwMRiφc=ρρMRiφc

In eq. [19], we know that the marginal revenue term (defined in eq. [35]) is positive and dqic/de is the same for all sellers because of symmetry. Therefore, the condition that dR/de>0 is the same as the condition that eq. [40] is greater than zero, hence inequality [20].

Above it was claimed that the denominator of eq. [39] is positive, which is to say that

[41]nPQφc′′+PQ+Qc2PQ2<0

The first term in parentheses is negative if demand slopes down and cost is weakly convex.[34] The second term in parentheses is non-positive under assumption [3] of Novshek (1985), which he shows is equivalent to the assumption that each firm’s marginal revenue is not increasing in qi (see footnote 13). Thus follows the inequality.

References

Andreas, Peter, and Joel Wallman. 2009. “Illicit Markets and Violence: What Is the Relationship?” Crime, Law and Social Change 52 (3): 225–29.10.1007/s10611-009-9200-6Search in Google Scholar

Becker, Gary S., Kevin M. Murphy, and Michael Grossman. 2006. “The Market for Illegal Goods: The Case of Drugs.” Journal of Political Economy 114 (1): 38–60.10.1086/498918Search in Google Scholar

Biener, Lois, and J. L. Hargraves. Forthcoming. “A Longitudinal Study of Electronic Cigarette Use in a Population-Based Sample of Adult Smokers: Association with Smoking Cessation and Motivation to Quit.” Nicotine & Tobacco Research.Search in Google Scholar

Bullen, Christopher. 2014. “Electronic Cigarettes for Smoking Cessation.” Current Cardiology Reports 16: 538–45.10.1007/s11886-014-0538-8Search in Google Scholar

Cahn, Zachary, and Michael Siegel. 2011. “Electronic Cigarettes as a Harm Reduction Strategy for Tobacco Control: A Step Forward or a Repeat of Past Mistakes?” Journal of Public Health Policy 32: 16–31.10.1057/jphp.2010.41Search in Google Scholar

Caulkins, Jonathan P., Mark A. R. Kleiman, and Jonathan D. Kulick. 2010. Drug Production and Trafficking, Counterdrug Policies, and Security and Governance in Afghanistan. Center on International Cooperation, New York: New York University.Search in Google Scholar

Caulkins, Jonathan P., C. Peter Rydell, William L. Schwabe, and James Chiesa. 1997. Mandatory Minimum Drug Sentences: Throwing Away the Key or the Taxpayers’ Money? Santa Monica, CA: RAND.10.7249/MR827Search in Google Scholar

Caulkins, Jonathan P., and Peter Reuter. 2006. “Illicit Drug Markets and Economic Irregularities.” Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 40: 1–14.10.1016/j.seps.2004.08.002Search in Google Scholar

Caulkins, Jonathan P., and Peter Reuter. 2010. “How Drug Enforcement Affects Drug Prices.” In Crime and Justice – A Review of Research, vol. 39, edited by Michael Tonry, 213–72. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago.10.1086/652386Search in Google Scholar

Caulkins, Jonathan P., Peter Reuter, and Lowell J. Taylor. 2006. “Can Supply Restrictions Lower Price? Violence, Drug Dealing and Positional Advantage.” Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 5 (1): Article 3.Search in Google Scholar

Chaloupka, Frank J., Rosalie L. Pacula, Matthew C. Farrelly, Lloyd D. Johnston, and Patrick M. O‘Malley. 1999. “Do Higher Cigarette Prices Encourage Youth to Use Marijuana?” NBER Working Paper No. 6939.10.3386/w6939Search in Google Scholar

Chaloupka, Frank J., and Kenneth E. Warner. 2000. “The Economics of Smoking.” In Handbook of Health Economics, Vol. 1B, edited by A. J. Culyer and J. P. Newhouse, Ch. 29 1539–627. Amsterdam: Elsevier.10.1016/S1574-0064(00)80042-6Search in Google Scholar

Chiou, Lesley, and Erich J. Muehlegger. 2008. “Crossing the Line: The Effect of Cross-Border Cigarette Sales on State Excise Tax Revenues.” BE Journal – Economic Analysis and Policy (Contributions) 8: 1. Article 4810.2202/1935-1682.2027Search in Google Scholar

Chiu, Stephen, Edward C. Mansley, and John Morgan. 1998. “Choosing the Right Battlefield for the War on Drugs: An Irrelevance Result.” Economics Letters 59 (1): 107–11.10.1016/S0165-1765(98)00009-3Search in Google Scholar

Christopoulou, Rebekka, and Philip Vermeulen. 2012. “Markups in the Euro Area and the US over the Period 1981–2004: A Comparison of 50 Sectors.” Empirical Economics 42 (1): 53–77.10.1007/s00181-010-0430-3Search in Google Scholar

Compass Lexecon. 2011. “Estimating Consequences of a Ban on the Legal Sale of Menthol Cigarettes.” Accessed March 17, 2015. http://www.fda.gov/downloads/AdvisoryCommittees/CommitteesMeetingMaterials/TobaccoProductsScientificAdvisoryCommittee/UCM243622.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Costa Storti, Cláudia, and Paul De Grauwe. 2008. “Modeling Disorganized Crime: The Cannabis Market.” Bulletin on Narcotics: Measurement Issues in Drug Policy Analysis 60: 79–100.Search in Google Scholar

Dalton, Matthew, and Mike Esterl. 2013. “Cigarette Bans to Hit Europe.” The Wall Street Journal, July 11.Search in Google Scholar

Decker, S. L., and A. E. Schwartz. 2000. “Cigarettes and Alcohol: Substitutes or Complements?” NBER Working Paper, No. 7535.Search in Google Scholar

Dixit, A. K., and J. E. Stiglitz. 1977. “Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity.” American Economic Review 67 (3): 297–308.Search in Google Scholar

Duncan, Greg J., Johanne Boisjoly, Michael Kremer, Dan M. Levy, and Jacque Eccles. 2005. “Peer Effects in Drug Use and Sex among College Students.” Journal of Abnormal Child Psychology 33 (3): 375–85.10.1007/s10802-005-3576-2Search in Google Scholar

Esterl, Mike. 2011. “Cigarette Sales May Be off, but Lorillard Still Rolls on.” Wall Street Journal, December 2.Search in Google Scholar

Federal Trade Commission (FTC). 2013. Federal Trade Commission Cigarette Report for 2011. Washington, DC: Federal Trade Commission.Search in Google Scholar

Feichtinger, Gustav, and Gernot Tragler. 2001. Multiple Equilibria in an Optimal Control Model for Law Enforcement. Vienna: Institute for Econometrics, Operations Research and Systems Theory, Vienna University of Technology.Search in Google Scholar

Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) of the United Nations. 2003. Issues in the Global Tobacco Economy: Selected Case Studies. Rome: FAO.Search in Google Scholar

Fulginiti, Lilyan E., and Richard K. Perrin. 1993. “The Theory and Measurement of Producer Response under Quotas.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 75: 97–106.10.2307/2109630Search in Google Scholar

Goldstein, Paul J. 1985. “The Drugs/Violence Nexus: A Tripartite Conceptual Framework.” Journal of Drug Issues 15 (4): 493–506.10.1177/002204268501500406Search in Google Scholar

Grana, Rachel, Neal Benowitz, and Stanton A. Glantz. 2014. “E-Cigarettes: A Scientific Review.” Circulation 129 (19): 1972–86.10.1161/CIRCULATIONAHA.114.007667Search in Google Scholar

Guevara, Marina Walker. 2008. “Overview: Tobacco Is the Most Widely Smuggled Legal Substance, and It’s (sic) Trafficking Fuels Organized Crime and Corruption.” Entry dated October 20. Accessed March 17, 2015. http://www.publicintegrity.org/2008/10/20/6337/overview.Search in Google Scholar

Hajek, Peter, Jean-François Etter, Neal Benowitz, Thomas Eissenberg, and Hayden McRobbie. 2014. “Electronic Cigarettes: Review of Use, Content, Safety, Effects on Smokers and Potential for Harm and Benefit.” Addiction 109 (11): 1801–10.10.1111/add.12659Search in Google Scholar

Hawken, Angela, Jonathan D. Kulick, and James E. Prieger. 2013. “Unintended Consequences of Cigarette Taxation and Regulation.” Pepperdine University, School of Public Policy Working Papers. Paper 47.Search in Google Scholar

Jacobsson, A., and A. Naranjo. 2009. “Counter-Intuitive Effects of Domestic Law Enforcement Policies in the United States.” Economics of Governance 10 (4): 323–43.10.1007/s10101-009-0062-2Search in Google Scholar

Kilmer, Beau, Susan S. Everingham, Jonathan P. Caulkins, Gregory Midgette, Rosalie Liccardo Pacula, Peter H. Reuter, Rachel M. Burns, Bing Han, and Russell Lundberg. 2014. What America’s Users Spend on Illegal Drugs: 2000–2010. RR-534-ONDCP. Santa Monica: RAND Corporation.10.7249/RR534Search in Google Scholar

Kleiman, Mark A. R. 1993. “Enforcement Swamping: A Positive-Feedback Mechanism in Rates of Illicit Activity.” Mathematical and Computer Modelling 17 (2): 65–75.10.1016/0895-7177(93)90240-YSearch in Google Scholar

Kleiman, Mark A. R. 2011. “Surgical Strikes in the Drug Wars.” Foreign Affairs Sep/Oct: 89–101.Search in Google Scholar

Kuziemko, Ilyana, and Steven D. Levitt. 2004. “An Empirical Analysis of Imprisoning Drug Offenders.” Journal of Public Economics 88 (9–10): 2043–66.10.3386/w8489Search in Google Scholar

Lee, L. W. 1993. “Would Harassing Drug Users Work?” Journal of Political Economy 101 (5): 939–59.10.1086/261910Search in Google Scholar

Levitt, Steven D., and Sudhir Alladi Venkatesh. 2000. “An Economic Analysis of a Drug-Selling Gang’s Finances.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (3): 775–89.10.3386/w6592Search in Google Scholar

Mejía, Daniel, and Carlos Esteban Posada. 2008. Cocaine Production and Trafficking: What Do We Know? The World Bank Development Research Group, Policy Research Working Paper 4618.10.1596/1813-9450-4618Search in Google Scholar

Miron, Jeffrey A., and Jeffrey Zwiebel. 1995. “The Economic Case against Drug Prohibition.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (4): 175–92.10.1257/jep.9.4.175Search in Google Scholar

Moeller, Kim, and Morten Hesse. 2013. “Drug Market Disruption and Systemic Violence: Cannabis Markets in Copenhagen.” European Journal of Criminology 10 (2): 206–21.10.1177/1477370812467568Search in Google Scholar

Moore, T., J. Caulkins, A. Ritter, P. Dietze, S. Monagle, and J. Pruden. 2005. Heroin Markets in Australia. DPMP Monograph Series. Monograph No. 09. Fitzroy: Turning Point Alcohol and Drug Centre.Search in Google Scholar

Neary, J. P. 2004. “Monopolistic Competition and International Trade Theory.” In The Monopolistic Competition Revolution in Retrospect, edited by Steven Brakman and Ben J. Heijdra, 159–84. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511492273.009Search in Google Scholar

Novshek, William. 1985. “On the Existence of Cournot Equilibrium.” The Review of Economic Studies 52 (1): 85–98.10.1017/CBO9780511528231.009Search in Google Scholar

O’Connor, Richard J., Maansi Bansal-Travers, Lawrence P. Carter, and K. Michael Cummings. 2012. “What Would Menthol Smokers Do if Menthol in Cigarettes Were Banned? Behavioral Intentions and Simulated Demand.” Addiction 107 (7): 1330–38.10.1111/j.1360-0443.2012.03822.xSearch in Google Scholar

Office of National Drug Control Policy (ONDCP). 2001. The Price of Illicit Drugs, 1981–Second Quarter 2000. Washington, DC: ONDCP.Search in Google Scholar

Papachristos, Andrew V. 2009. “Murder by Structure: Dominance Relations and the Social Structure of Gang Homicide in Chicago.” American Journal of Sociology 115 (1): 74–128.10.2139/ssrn.855304Search in Google Scholar

Poret, Sylvaine. 2003. “The Illicit Drug Market: Paradoxical Effects of Law Enforcement Policies.” International Review of Law and Economics 22 (4): 465–93.10.1016/S0144-8188(02)00115-1Search in Google Scholar

Poret, Sylvaine. 2009. “An Optimal Anti-Drug Law Enforcement Policy.” International Review of Law and Economics 29 (3): 221–28.10.1016/j.irle.2009.01.005Search in Google Scholar

Prieger, James E., and Jonathan D. Kulick. 2014. “Unintended Consequences of Enforcement in Illicit Markets.” Economics Letters 125: 295–97.10.1016/j.econlet.2014.09.025Search in Google Scholar

Rasmussen, David W., and Bruce L. Benson. 1994. The Economic Anatomy of a Drug War: Criminal Justice in the Commons. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield.Search in Google Scholar

Reuter, Peter. 1983. Disorganized Crime – the Economics of the Visible Hand. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.10.2307/1288721Search in Google Scholar

Reuter, Peter. 1991. On the Consequences of Toughness. RAND note. Santa Monica: RAND.Search in Google Scholar

Reuter, Peter, and Mark A. R. Kleiman. 1986. “Risks and Prices: An Economic Analysis of Drug Enforcement.” In Crime and Justice, Vol. 7, edited by M. Tonry and N. Morris, 289–340. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago.10.1086/449116Search in Google Scholar

Reuter, Peter, and Robert J. MacCoun. 1995. “Lessons from the Absence of Harm Reduction in American Drug Policy.” Tobacco Control 4: S28–S32.10.1136/tc.4.suppl2.S28Search in Google Scholar

Rydell, C. Peter, and Susan S. Everingham. 1994. Controlling Cocaine: Supply Versus Demand Programs. Santa Monica: RAND.10.7249/MR331Search in Google Scholar

Sacerdote, Bruce. 2014. “Experimental and Quasi-Experimental Analysis of Peer Effects: Two Steps Forward?” Annual Review of Economics 6: 253–72.10.1146/annurev-economics-071813-104217Search in Google Scholar

Shrestha, Vinish. 2014. “Do Young Adults Substitute Alcohol for Cigarettes? Learning from the Master Settlement Agreement.” Dept. of Economics Working Paper, Emory University.Search in Google Scholar

Skott, P., and G. T. Gepsen. 2002. “Paradoxical Effects of Drug Policy in a Model with Imperfect Competition and Switching Costs.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organizations 48 (4): 335–54.10.1016/S0167-2681(01)00238-4Search in Google Scholar

Sumner, Daniel A., and Michael K. Wohlgenant. 1985. “Effects of an Increase in the Federal Excise Tax on Cigarettes.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 67 (2): 235–42.10.2307/1240674Search in Google Scholar

Tauras, John A., David Levy, Frank J. Chaloupka, Andrea Villanti, Raymond S. Niaura, Donna Vallone, and David B. Abrams. 2010. “Menthol and Non-Menthol Smoking: The Impact of Prices and Smoke-Free Air Laws.” Addiction 105 (Suppl. 1): 115–23.10.1111/j.1360-0443.2010.03206.xSearch in Google Scholar

Tavernise, Sabrina. 2013. “F.D.A. Closer to Decision About Menthol Cigarettes.” The New York Times July 24.Search in Google Scholar

Transactional Records Access Clearinghouse (TRAC), Syracuse University. 2000. “Breakdown of National Drug Control Budget by Function (1981–1998).” Accessed November 1, 2014. http://trac.syr.edu/tracdea/findings/national/drugbudn.html.Search in Google Scholar

United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (UNODC). 2014. World Drug Report 2014. United Nations publication, Sales No. E.14.XI.7.Search in Google Scholar

United States Department of Justice, Office of the Inspector General (USDOJ OIG). 2009. The Bureau of Alcohol, Tobacco, Firearms and Explosives’ Efforts to Prevent the Diversion of Tobacco, Evaluation and Inspections Division, Report Number I-2009-005. Accessed March 17, 2015. Available at http://www.justice.gov/oig/reports/ATF/e0905.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Werb, Dan, Greg Rowell, Gordon Guyatt, Thomas Kerr, Julio Montaner, and Evan Wood. 2011. “Effect of Drug Law Enforcement on Drug Market Violence: A Systematic Review.” International Journal of Drug Policy 22 (2): 87–94.10.1016/j.drugpo.2011.02.002Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2015-3-24
Published in Print: 2015-7-1

©2015 by De Gruyter

Downloaded on 4.6.2023 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2014-0184/html?lang=en
Scroll to top button