Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter January 23, 2018

Is There Really a Trade-Off? Family Size and Investment in Child Quality in India

  • Mehtabul Azam EMAIL logo and Chan Hang Saing

Abstract

We address the relationship between number of children and investment in child quality, known as quantity–quality (Q–Q) trade-off, for India. Using a number of investment and outcome measures, we find that the OLS estimates suggest the presence of Q–Q trade-offs in nine out of ten measures considered. Using the gender of the first-born child as an instrument, the trade-offs in all measures disappear. Given the concerns about the exogeneity of the instrument, we apply Oster (2016) bounds to assess the sensitivity of OLS estimates to omitted variables. We find robust trade-off estimates in three measures currently enrolled in school, years of schooling and height-for-age. The results are more robust when observing trade-offs in rural areas. Trade-offs appear in ever enrolled in school, private school attendance, expenditure on education and private coaching in addition to the trade-offs in the three measures for all India sample.

JEL Classification: O11; J13

References

Altonji, J. G., Elder T. E., and Taber C. R. 2005. “Selection on Observed and Unobserved Variables: Assessing the Effectiveness of Catholic Schools.” Journal of Political Economy 113 (1):151–184.10.3386/w7831Search in Google Scholar

Angrist, J., Lavy V., and Schlosser A. 2010. “Multiple Experiments for the Causal Link between the Quantity and Quality of Children.” Journal of Labor Economics 28 (4):773–824.10.1086/653830Search in Google Scholar

Azam, M. 2016. “Explaining Caste Differences in Private School Attendance.” Review of Development Economics. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/rode.12305.http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/rode.12305Search in Google Scholar

Becker, G. S. 1960. “An Economic Analysis of Fertility.” In Demographic and Economic Change in Developed Countries, edited by Becker Gary S. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Becker, G. S., and Lewis H. G. 1973. “On the Interaction between the Quantity and Quality of Children.” Journal of Political Economy 81:S279–S288.10.1086/260166Search in Google Scholar

Bhalotra, S., and Clarke D. 2016. “The Twin Instrument.” IZA DP No. 10405.10.2139/ssrn.2886776Search in Google Scholar

Black, S. E., Devereux P. J., and Salvanes K. G. 2005. “The More the Merrier? The Effect of Family Size and Birth Order on Children’s Education.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 120 (2):669–700.Search in Google Scholar

Bougma, M., LeGrand T. K., and Kobiane J.F. 2015. “Fertility Decline and Child Schooling in Urban Settings of Burkina Faso.” Demography 52 (1):281–313.10.1007/s13524-014-0355-0Search in Google Scholar

Butcher, K., and Case A. 1994. “The Effect of Sibling Sex Composition on Women’s Education and Earnings.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (3):531–563.10.2307/2118413Search in Google Scholar

Cáceres-Delpiano, Julio. 2006. “The Impacts of Family Size on Investment in Child Quality.” Journal of Human Resources 41 (4):738–754.10.3368/jhr.XLI.4.738Search in Google Scholar

Conley, D., and Glauber R. 2006. “Parental Educational Investment and Children’s Academic Risk: Estimates of the Impact of Sibship Size and Birth Order from Exogenous Variation in Fertility.” The Journal of Human Resources 41 (4):722–737.10.3368/jhr.XLI.4.722Search in Google Scholar

Conley, T. G., Hansen C. B., and Rossi P. E. 2012. “Plausibly Exogenous.” Review of Economics and Statistics 94 (1):260–272.10.1162/REST_a_00139Search in Google Scholar

Dahl, G. B., and Moretti E. 2008. “The Demand for Sons.” Review of Economic Studies 75 (4):1085–1120.10.1111/j.1467-937X.2008.00514.xSearch in Google Scholar

Dang, H., and Rogers H. F. 2016. “The Decision to Invest in Child Quality over Quantity: Household Size and Household Investment in Education in Vietnam.” World Bank Economic Review 30 (1):104–142.10.5040/9781350995109Search in Google Scholar

Dayıoğlu, M., Kirdar M. G., and Tansel A. 2009. “Impact of Sibship Size, Birth Order and Sex Composition on School Enrolment in Urban Turkey.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 71 (3):399–426.10.1111/j.1468-0084.2008.00540.xSearch in Google Scholar

de Haan, M. 2010. “Birth Order, Family Size and Educational Attainment.” Economics of Education Review 29:576–588.10.1016/j.econedurev.2009.10.012Search in Google Scholar

Fitzsimons, E., and Malde B. 2014. “Empirically Probing the Quantity–Quality Model.” Journal of Population Economics 27:33–68.10.1007/s00148-013-0474-8Search in Google Scholar

Government of India. 2006. Social, Economic and Education Status of the Muslim Community of India. New Delhi.Search in Google Scholar

Kang, C. 2011. “Family Size and Educational Investments in Children: Evidence from Private Tutoring Expenditures in South Korea.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 73:59–78.10.1111/j.1468-0084.2010.00607.xSearch in Google Scholar

Kaul, T. 2016. Intra-Household Allocation of Educational Expenses: Gender Discrimination versus Investment for the Future. University of Maryland, mimeo.Search in Google Scholar

Kugler, A. D., and Kumar S. 2017. “Preference for Boys, Family Size and Educational Attainment in India.” Demography 54:835–859.10.1007/s13524-017-0575-1Search in Google Scholar

Lee, J. 2008. “Sibling Size and Investment in Children’s Education: An Asian Instrument.” Journal of Population Economics 21 (4):855–875.10.1007/s00148-006-0124-5Search in Google Scholar

Li, H., Zhang J., and Zhu Y. 2008. “The Quantity–Quality Trade-off of Children in a Developing Country: Identification using Twins.” Demography 45 (1):223–243.10.1353/dem.2008.0006Search in Google Scholar

Liu, H. 2014. “The Quality-Qquantity Trade-off: Evidence from the Relaxation of China’s One-child Policy.” Journal of Population Economics 27 (2):565–602.10.1007/s00148-013-0478-4Search in Google Scholar

Maralani, V. 2008. “The Changing Relationship Between Family Size and Educational Attainment over the Course of Socioeconomic Development: Evidence from Indonesia.” Demography 45 (3):693–717.10.1353/dem.0.0013Search in Google Scholar

Muralidharan, K. 2013, April. “Priorities for Primary Education Policy in India’s 12th five-year Plan.” In India Policy Forum, Vol. 9, 1–46.Search in Google Scholar

Oster, E. 2016a. “Unobservable Selection and Coefficient Stability: Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Business and Economic Statisticshttp://dx.doi.org/10.1080/07350015.2016.1227711http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/07350015.2016.1227711Search in Google Scholar

Oster, E. 2016b. “PSACALC: Stata Module to Calculate Treatment Effects and Relative Degree of Selection Under Proportional Selection of Observables and Unobservables.” Statistical Software Components.Search in Google Scholar

Qian, N. 2009. “Quantity–Quality and the One Child Policy: The Only-Child Disadvantage in School Enrollment in Rural China,” NBER Working Papers 14973.Search in Google Scholar

Rosenzweig, M., and Zhang J. 2009. “Do Population Control Policies Induce More Human Capital Investment? Twins, Birthweight, and China’s ‘One Child’ Policy.” Review of Economic Studies 76 (3):1149–1174.10.2139/ssrn.893056Search in Google Scholar

Rosenzweig, M. R., and Wolpin K. I. 1980. “Testing the Quantity-quality Fertility Model: The Use of Twins as a Natural Experiment.” Econometrica 48 (1):227–240.10.2307/1912026Search in Google Scholar

Sarin, A. 2004. “Are Children from Smaller Families Healthier? Examining the Causal Effects of Family Size on Child Welfare (Unpublished doctoral dissertation).” Irving B. Harris School of Public Policy, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL.Search in Google Scholar

Schultz, T. P. 2008. “Population Policies, Fertility, Women’s Human Capital and Child’s Quality.” In Handbook of Development Economics, edited by Paul Schultz T and Strauss John, Vol. 4. North Holand: Elsevier.Search in Google Scholar

Steelman, L. C., Powell B., Werum R., and Carter S. 2002. “Reconsidering the Effects of Sibling Configuration: Recent Advances and Challenges.” Annual Review of Sociology 28:243–269.10.1146/annurev.soc.28.111301.093304Search in Google Scholar

Appendix

A
Table 1:

Summary statistics of sample children aged 6–18.

(1)(2)(3)
MeanSDN
Outcome variables
Ever enrolled in school (1/0)0.970.1837,756
Currently enrolled in school (1/0)0.890.3137,756
Years of schooling5.113.4537,754
Attend private school (1/0)0.290.4537,764
Private coaching (1/0)0.370.4837,764
Log of education expenditure6.302.9937,764
Log of private coaching expenditure1.693.1237,764
Standardized reading score0.071.019,401
Standardized math score0.061.009,364
Height-for-age z score1.591.9531,128
Explanatory variables
Child is girl (1/0)0.480.5037,764
Child-Age11.753.6137,764
Child-Age squared151.1686.3537,764
Child’s birth order-20.310.4637,764
Child’s birth order-30.190.3937,764
Child’s birth order-40.100.3037,764
Child’s birth rder-5 or more0.080.2737,764
Other backward castes0.360.4837,764
Scheduled castes0.230.4237,764
Scheduled tribes0.080.2737,764
Muslim0.150.3537,764
Log of per capita income9.400.9737,301
Joint-two mother observations from same household0.030.1637,764
Mother’s age36.125.7437,764
Mother’s age squared1,337.25419.7237,764
Mother height in cm151.198.2336,966
Father’s age41.126.5237,764
Father’s age squared1,732.99550.9437,764
Household main income source cultivation (1/0)0.250.4337,764
Household main income source salaried (1/0)0.160.3637,764
Household holds below poverty line card (1/0)0.370.4837,764
Household own TV (1/0)0.590.4937,764
Household own land (1/0)0.480.5037,764
Urban0.310.4637,764
  1. Note: SD: Standard deviation. Survey weights are used.

B
Table 2:

Q–Q Trade-offs.

(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
δ for β=0;δ forOster’s bound,Max
NoRmax=β=0;δ=1,Rmax for
Dependent variablecontrolsControlsIV1.3ŘRmax=1Rmax=1.3Řβ<0
under
δ=1
Ever enrolled in school (1/0)0.014***0.009***0.026*0.9040.028[0.009, 0.003]0.108
(0.001)(0.002)(0.015)
R-squared0.0150.0850.052
Currently enrolled (1/0)0.036***0.031***0.0051.1460.093[0.031, 0.013]0.259
(0.002)(0.003)(0.024)
R-squared0.0340.1920.180
Years of schooling completed0.187***0.230***0.0002.3702.211[ 0.320, 0.230]NA
(0.018)(0.021)(0.161)
R-squared0.0070.7570.753
Attend private school (1/0)0.047***0.031***0.095**0.9380.124[0.031, 0.005]0.381
(0.003)(0.003)(0.038)
R-squared0.0270.2970.230
Private coaching (1/0)0.006**0.0030.0130.4240.036[0.003, 0.021]NA
(0.003)(0.004)(0.041)
R-squared0.0000.2210.221
Log of education expenditure0.491***0.368***0.3660.9340.113[0.368, 0.086]0.333
(0.020)(0.025)(0.232)
R-squared0.0680.2610.214
Log of private coaching expenditure0.326***0.228***0.2840.9820.132[0.228, 0.010]0.388
(0.018)(0.025)(0.246)
R-squared0.0280.3000.277
Standardized reading score0.149***0.109***0.1650.7860.103[0.109, 0.137]0.353
(0.012)(0.016)(0.171)
Observations9,4019,4019,401
R-squared0.0540.2870.248
Standardized math score0.168***0.105***0.1150.6530.093[0.105, 0.200]0.364
(0.011)(0.015)(0.172)
Observations9,3649,3649,364
R-squared0.0700.3070.274
Height-for-age z score0.040***0.058***0.0113.1640.201[0.096, 0.058]NA
(0.012)(0.016)(1.188)
Observations31,12831,12831,128
R-squared0.0010.1730.172
  1. Note: Standard errors in parentheses are calculated taking survey design into account and are clustered at the mother level. The coefficients refer to the coefficients of family size. The number of observations in each regression except for the last three dependent variables is 37,764. Control variables include district fixed effects, age and age squared of child, child’s gender, indicators for birth order of child (second, third, fourth and fifth), indicator if two mothers reside in same household, indicators for other backward castes, scheduled castes, scheduled tribes and Muslim, log of per capita income, age and age squared of mother, mother’s height, age and age squared of father, indicators for household main income source being cultivation or salary, indicator for household having below poverty line status and urban dummy. In column (3), sex of first-born child is used as an instrument for family size. Sample is restricted to children aged 6–18 for all outcomes, except for reading and math test, the sample of which is restricted in children aged 8–11 as tests were administered to only 8–11 age group children. ***p<0.01, ** p<0.05, *p<0.1.

C
Table 3:

Q–Q trade-off, rural sample.

(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
δ for β=0;δ forOster’s bound,Max
NoRmax=β=0;δ=1,Rmaxfor
Dependent variablecontrolsControlsIV1.3ŘRmax=1Rmax=1.3Řβ<0
under
δ=1
Ever enrolled in school (1/0)0.013***0.010***0.0231.0420.035[0.010; 0.000]0.121
(0.002)(0.002)(0.019)
R-squared0.0120.0930.068
Currently enrolled (1/0)0.031***0.027***0.0041.3300.108[0.027; 0.017]0.279
(0.003)(0.004)(0.030)
R-squared0.0230.1980.190
Years of schooling completed0.174***0.201***0.1522.3201.918[0.251; 0.201]NA
(0.022)(0.025)(0.196)
R-squared0.0070.7330.733
Attend private school (1/0)0.023***0.026***0.088**2.1140.214[0.031; 0.026]NA
(0.004)(0.004)(0.044)
R-squared0.0080.2450.172
Private coaching (1/0)0.0010.0010.0201.3090.132[0.001; 0.004]NA
(0.004)(0.005)(0.050)
R-squared0.0000.2520.250
Log of education expenditure0.362***0.315***0.2971.2450.127[0.314; 0.185]0.318
(0.024)(0.029)(0.276)
R-squared0.0400.2300.190
Log of private coaching0.222***0.209***0.3081.5810.239[0.208; 0.181]0.480
expenditure(0.022)(0.029)(0.283)
R-squared0.0160.3240.293
Standardized reading score0.130***0.088***0.2930.7780.980[0.088; 0.091]0.350
(0.015)(0.019)(0.235)
Observations6,4446,4446,444
R-squared0.0410.2850.187
Standardized math score0.137***0.094***0.1880.7760.100[0.094; 0.104]0.331
(0.013)(0.018)(0.232)
Observations6,4196,4196,419
R-squared0.0490.2870.229
Height-for-age Z-score0.0230.063***0.09974.6905.125[0.132; 0.063]NA
(0.016)(0.019)(0.221)
Observations21,16521,16521,165
R-squared0.0000.1840.183
  1. Note: Standard errors in parentheses are calculated taking survey design into account and are clustered at the mother level. The coefficients refer to the coefficients of family size. The number of observations in each regression except for the last three dependent variables is 25,568. Control variables include district fixed effects, age and age squared of child, child’s gender, indicators for birth order of child (second, third, fourth and fifth), indicator if two mothers reside in same household, indicators for other backward castes, scheduled castes, scheduled tribes and Muslim, log of per capita income, age and age squared of mother, mother’s height, age and age squared of father, indicators for household main income source being cultivation or salary and indicator for household having below poverty line status. In column (3), sex of first-born child is used as an instrument for family size. Sample is restricted to children aged 6-18 for all outcomes, except for reading and math test, the sample of which is restricted children aged 8-11 as tests were administered to only for 8-11 age group children. ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.1.

D
Table 4:

Correlation between first-born girl and household characteristics (mother-level).

Dependent variable: First born is girl
Other backward castes0.005
(0.011)
Scheduled castes0.017
(0.011)
Scheduled tribes0.004
(0.019)
Muslim0.010
(0.016)
Log of per capita income0.029***
(0.005)
Joint-two mother observations from same household0.014
(0.022)
Mother’s age0.018**
(0.009)
Mother’s age squared0.000***
(0.000)
Mother’s height in cm0.001
(0.000)
Father’s age0.004
(0.007)
Father’s age squared0.000
(0.000)
Household main income source cultivation (1/0)0.004
(0.012)
Household main income source salaried (1/0)0.001
(0.012)
Household holds below poverty line card (1/0)0.031***
(0.009)
Household own TV (1/0)0.019**
(0.009)
Household own land (1/0)0.007
(0.011)
Urban0.017
(0.013)
Constant0.893***
(0.157)
Observations18,935
R-squared0.025
  1. Note: Each observation represents a mother. Standard errors in parentheses are calculated taking survey design into account and clustered at the district level. The model also includes district-fixed effects. ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.1.

E
Table 5:

Q–Q trade-offs. IV method.

(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)
Dependent variablesEverCurrentlyYears ofAttendPrivateLog oflog ofStandardizedStandardizedHeight-
attendedenrolledschoolingprivatecoachingeducationprivatereadingmath scorefor-age
schoolin school(1/0)school(1/0)expenditurecoachingscoreZ-score
(1/0)(1/0)expenditure
First stage
First-born girl0.195***0.195***0.195***0.195***0.195***0.195***0.195***0.166***0.166***0.206***
(0.021)(0.021)(0.021)(0.021)(0.021)(0.021)(0.021)(0.027)(0.027)(0.022)
Weak identification test
Cragg–Donald Wald F statistic364.57364.57364.43365.00365.00365.00365.0076.9075.71333.13
Kleibergen–Paap Wald rk F statistic88.0888.0888.0488.1788.1788.1788.1737.5736.9185.17
2 SLS results
Family size0.0260.005-0.0010.095**0.0130.3380.28537.5700.1160.013
(0.015)(0.024)(0.161)(0.038)(0.042)(0.232)(0.246)(0.172)(0.173)(0.188)
Observations3775637756377543776436,96037764377649401936431128
R-squared0.0530.1810.7530.2310.2220.2140.2770.2490.2740.173
  1. Note: Standard errors in parentheses are calculated taking survey design into account and are clustered at the mother level. Control variables include district-fixed effects, age and age squared of child, child’s gender, indicators for birth order of child (second, third, fourth and fifth), indicator if two mothers reside in the same household, indicators for other backward castes, scheduled castes, scheduled tribes and Muslim, log of per capita income, age and age squared of mother, mother’s height, age and age squared of father, indicators for household main income source being cultivation or salary, indicator for household having below poverty line status and urban dummy. Sample is restricted to children aged 6-18 for all outcomes, except for reading and math test. Reading and math test score sample consists of children aged 8-11, as tests were administered to only 8-11 age group children. ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.1.

Published Online: 2018-1-23

© 2018 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 28.5.2023 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2017-0098/html
Scroll to top button