Abstract
In the traditional Becker model of employer discrimination, discriminatory behavior arises from a utility-maximizing owner who balances firm profits against the disutility of hiring workers from the disadvantaged demographic group. However, in the modern firm, many human resource decisions are made by agents of the owner (managers) whose actions may not reflect the preferences of even profit-maximizing owners. We present a principal-agent model of discrimination with a profit-maximizing owner and a gender-discriminating manager and show that managerial discrimination is increasing with the degree of risk in the firm’s revenue stream. Empirical tests using a Colombian plant-level dataset support a prediction of our model that female workers should be under-represented in more revenue volatile firms and industries.
Acknowledgements
We are grateful to Ken Troske, two anonymous referees and seminar participants at the Unversité Libre de Bruxelles for many comments and suggestions, as well as to Mark Roberts for making the Colombian manufacturing data available to us.
Appendix
A.1 Hiring Model
As an application, consider the case where the principal (the owner) assigns the task of interviewing and hiring workers to the agent (upper management). Initially, the firm has no workers other than the agent. Each period, the agent is faced with an exogenous pool of applicants consisting of
The agent chooses whether or not to hire each applicant to maximize his expected utility. The agent has exponential utility
The principal wants to incentivise the agent to hire profitable workers, and so the wage paid to the agent,
Since the agent is discriminatory, he faces a tradeoff. Rather than hiring to maximize his expected wage, he prefers to hire fewer female workers, even if they exhibit higher expected profitability than male applicants, in order to decrease the number of female workers. However, he may be unwilling to pass up too many high-productivity females, since this would reduce his wage more significantly. Thus, we model the agents decision as choosing minimum productivity cut-offs for both male (
In this case, the expected (realized) profitability to the firm of a female-applicant is:
with the expected profitability of a male applicant (
Thus, the central limit theorem suggests that firm revenue can be approximated by
Since the expected number of females hired is f =
We first maximize (8) wrt
From (9), we find
From (10), we have
Since b > 0,
The above model makes clear that we are only modeling a link between incentive contracts and employment discrimination in which discrimination results in potentially profitable hiring of some female workers (for both the worker and the firm) not occurring. This is due to the structure of the model in which the worker makes a take-it-or-leave-it wage offer and the only decision by the manager is the hiring decision. Alternatively, one could consider a model of wage discrimination in which the worker and manager engage in wage bargaining and the manager systemically makes lower offers (or bargains harder) with female potential workers. What is interesting is that, to the extent that the manager can successfully hire female workers for lower wages, such wage discrimination would not necessarily be deterred by incentive contracts as it would result in higher profits for the firm. Indeed, this behavior (lower offers to female workers) would only be discouraged to the extent that it resulted in potentially profitable female workers not accepting the position (i.e. to the extent that it resulted in lower than optimal female-shares of the labor force). Thus, we see our model being more about employment discrimination than wage discrimination.
The agent’s certainty equivalent (CE) is the wage received less the disutility from hiring females, and the cost of bearing risk:
The principal’s expected profit is
Substituting for y, total surplus is:
The principal chooses b to maximize (14). The optimal piece rate is the value of b for which
An interior solution is ensured because the necessary second order condition is satisfied:
The optimal salary component of the wage,
Total differentiation of (15) with respect to b and
The numerator of (17) is positive, and the denominator is negative by (16). Consequently, we find that an increase in risk (
Hence, an increase in risk (
A.2 Data
All data are taken from a plant-level dataset produced from the Colombian Manufacturing census by DANE (National Statistical Institute) for the years 1977 through 1991. Starting in 1983, the census covers industrial production for plants with more than 10 employees. Our empirics are a cross-section of plants operating in 1991, although earlier years are used to construct some of the variables, as noted below. For a thorough description of this dataset see Roberts (1996).
All variables are measured at the plant level unless otherwise noted.
Female share: female share of workers.
Productivity: value added for the plant divided by total employment.
Employment: total employment.
Salary: total payroll divided by total employment.
Wage: Average unskilled wage is calculated by total salary and benefits of unskilled workers divided by total number of unskilled workers.
Firm Age: years since the plant’s establishment until 1984.
Exports: plant exports scaled by total sales.
Skill Ratio: share of skilled employment in skilled and unskilled employment.
Capital/Labor Ratio: ratio of fixed capital to total employment. A small number of plants with fixed capital reported as zero are dropped.
Energy Use: one plus the ratio of energy consumed to total employment.
Office Equipment: office equipment’s share of total capital equipment.
Variability: Revenue: the variance of total revenue scaled by its mean for the plant over 1986–90, for all plants with at least two years of non-missing data.
Variability: Net income: the variance of net income scaled by its mean for the plant over 1986–90, for all plants with at least two years of non-missing data.
Variability: Profit: the variance of profit scaled by its mean for the plant over 1986–90, for all plants with at least two years of non-missing data.
Market Share Correlation: the correlation between plants’ market share in 1984 and market share in 1991, at the 4-digit industry level. Any plant present in only one year is treated as having a market share of zero in the missing year.
Absolute Value of Market Share Changes: the sum of the absolute value of changes in market share from 1984 to 1991, at the 4-digit industry level. Any plant present in one year is treated as having a market share of zero in the missing year.
Mean, Revenue Variability: the mean of the revenue variability measure for the 4-digit industry.
Type of Enterprise: The data set classifies plants by 10 different enterprise types. We omit firms classified as collectives, cooperatives, official entities, and religious communities (overall, these comprise less than 2 % of the sample). We construct dummy variables for Corporations (this includes plants classified as corporations, de facto corporations, and joint stock companies), Proprietorships, and Partnerships (including limited partnerships and joint partnerships).
References
Aggarwal, R., and A. Samwick. 1999. “The Other Side of the Trade-Off: The Impact of Risk on Executive Compensation.” The Journal of Political Economy 107 (1): 65–105.10.1086/250051Search in Google Scholar
Amuedo-Dorantes, C., and S. de la Rica. 2006. “The Role of Segregation and Pay Structure on the Gender Wage Gap: Evidence from Matched Employer-Employee Data for Spain.” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy 5: 1–34.10.1515/1538-0645.1498Search in Google Scholar
Ashenfelter, O., and T. Hannan. 1986. “Sex Discrimination and Product Market Competition: The Case of the Banking Industry.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 101 (1): 149–74.10.2307/1884646Search in Google Scholar
Baker, G. 2002. “Distortion and Risk in Optimal Incentive Contracts.” The Journal of Human Resources 37: 728–51.10.2307/3069615Search in Google Scholar
Bandiera, O., I. Barankay, and I. Rasul. 2009. “Social Connections and Incentives in the Workplace: Evidence from Personnel Data.” Econometrica 77: 1047–94.10.3982/ECTA6496Search in Google Scholar
Bayard, K., J. Hellerstein, D. Neumark, and K. Troske. 2003. “New Evidence on Sex Segregation and Sex Differences in Wages from Matched Employee-Employer Data.” The Journal of Labor Economics 21: 887–922.10.1086/377026Search in Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. 1957. The Economics of Discrimination. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Search in Google Scholar
Black, D. 1995. “Discrimination in an Equilibrium Search Model.” Journal of Labor Economics 13: 309–34.10.1086/298376Search in Google Scholar
Black, S. E., and E. Brainerd. 2004. “Importing Equality? The Impact of Globalization on Gender Discrimination.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 57 (4): 540–59.10.1177/001979390405700404Search in Google Scholar
Black, S., and P. Strahan. 2001. “The Division of Spoils: Rent-Sharing and Discrimination in a Regulated Industry.” American Economic Review 91: 814–31.10.1257/aer.91.4.814Search in Google Scholar
Bowlus, A. J. 1997. “A Search Interpretation of Male-Female Wage Differentials.” Journal of Labor Economics 15: 627–57.10.1086/209840Search in Google Scholar
Bowlus, A. J., and Z. Eckstein. 2002. “Discrimination and Skill Differences in an Equilibrium Search Model.” International Economic Review 43: 1309–45.10.1111/1468-2354.t01-1-00057Search in Google Scholar
Carrington, W., and K. R.Troske. 1998. “Sex Segregation in U.S. Manufacturing.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 51: 445–64.10.1177/001979399805100305Search in Google Scholar
Castilla, E. 2008. “Gender, Race and Meritocracy in Organizational Careers. American Journal of Sociology 113: 1479–526.10.1086/588738Search in Google Scholar
Catagay, N., and G. Berik. 1991. “Transition to Export-Led Growth in Turkey: Is There a Feminization of Employment?” Review of Radical Political Economics 22: 115–34.10.1177/048661349002200110Search in Google Scholar
Croson, R., and U. Gneezy. 2009. “Gender Differences in Preferences.” Journal of Economics Literature 47: 1–27.10.1257/jel.47.2.448Search in Google Scholar
de la Rica, S., J. Dolado, and R. Vegas. 2015. “Performance Pay and the Gender Wage Gap: Evidence from Spain.” The Annals of Economics and Statistics 41–59.10.15609/annaeconstat2009.117-118.41Search in Google Scholar
Ederington, J., J. Minier, and K. R. Troske. 2010. “Where the Girls are: Trade and Labor Market Segregation.” Manuscript.10.2139/ssrn.1395078Search in Google Scholar
Elvira, M., and R. Towns. 2001. “The Effects of Race and Worker Productivity on Performance Evaluations.” Industrial Relations 40: 571–90.10.1111/0019-8676.00226Search in Google Scholar
Fang, T., and J. Heywood. 2006. “Output Pay and Ethnic Wage Differentials: Canadian Evidence.” Industrial Relations 45: 173–93.10.1111/j.1468-232X.2006.00423.xSearch in Google Scholar
Garen, J. 1994. “Executive Compensation and Principal-Agent Theory.” Journal of Political Economy 102: 1175–99.10.1086/261967Search in Google Scholar
Gibbons, R. 1997. “Incentives and Careers in Organizations.” In Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, edited by D. Kreps and K. Wallis. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Gort, M. 1963. “Analysis of Stability and Change in Market Shares.” Journal of Political Economy 71 (1): 51–63.10.1086/258734Search in Google Scholar
Hellerstein, J., D. Neumark, and K. Troske. 2002. “Market Forces and Sex Discrimination.” Journal of Human Resources 37: 353–80.10.2307/3069651Search in Google Scholar
Heywood, J., and U. Jirjahn. 2002. “Payment Schemes and Gender in Germany.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 56: 44–64.10.1177/001979390205600103Search in Google Scholar
Heywood, J., and P. O’Halloran. 2005. “Racial Earnings Differentials and Performance Pay.” Journal of Human Resources 40: 435–52.10.3368/jhr.XL.2.435Search in Google Scholar
Holmstrom, B., and P. Milgrom. 1987. “Aggregation and Linearity in the Provision of Intertemporal Incentives.” Econometrica 55: 303–28.10.2307/1913238Search in Google Scholar
Holmstrom, B., and P. Milgrom. 1991. “Multitask Principal-Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership and Job Design.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 7: 24–52.10.1093/jleo/7.special_issue.24Search in Google Scholar
Hymer, S., and P. Pashigan. 1962. “Turnover of Firms as a Measure of Market Behavior.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 44 (1): 82–87.10.2307/1926627Search in Google Scholar
Javdani, M. 2015. “Glass Ceilings or Glass Doors: The Role of Firms in Male-Female Wage Disparities.” Canadian Journal of Economics 48: 529–60.10.1111/caje.12135Search in Google Scholar
Jirjahn, U., and G. Stephan. 2004. “Gender, Piece Rates and Wages: Evidence from Matched Employer-Employee Data.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 28: 683–704.10.1093/cje/beh027Search in Google Scholar
Madden, J. 2012. “Performance-Support Bias and the Gender Pay Gap Among Stockbrokers.” Gender and Society 26: 488–518.10.1177/0891243212438546Search in Google Scholar
Méon, P.-G., and A. Szafarz. 2011. “The Modern Corporation as a Safe Haven for Taste-Based Discrimination: An Agency Model of Hiring Decisions.” Labour Economics 18: 487–97.10.1016/j.labeco.2010.12.002Search in Google Scholar
Nickell, S. 1996. “Competition and Corporate Performance.” Journal of Political Economy 104: 724–46.10.1086/262040Search in Google Scholar
Oster, S. 1975. “Industry Differences in the Level of Discrimination Against Women.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 89: 215–29.10.2307/1884425Search in Google Scholar
Ozler, S. 2000. “Export Orientation and Female Share of Employment: Evidence from Turkey.” World Development 28 (7): 1239–48.10.1016/S0305-750X(00)00034-6Search in Google Scholar
Prendergast, C. 2002. “The Tenuous Trade-Off Between Risk and Incentives.” The Journal of Political Economy 110: 1071–102.10.1086/341874Search in Google Scholar
Roberts, M. J. 1996. “Colombia, 1977-85: Producer Turnover, Margins, and Trade Exposure.” In Industrial Evolution in Developing Countries: Micro Patterns of Turnover, Productivity, and Market Structure, edited by M. J. Roberts, and J. R. Tybout,, 227– 259. Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Schmidt, K. 1997. “Managerial Incentives and Product Market Competition.” Review of Economic Studies 64: 191–213.10.2307/2971709Search in Google Scholar
Schnedler, W. 2008. “When is it Foolish to Reward for a While Benefiting from B.” Journal of Labor Economics 26: 595–619.10.1086/591150Search in Google Scholar
© 2019 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston