Abstract
This article proposes a new approach to measuring the deterrent effect of cartel law enforcement by combining a game-theoretic model with Monte Carlo simulations. The game-theoretical analysis shows which type of perfect Bayesian Nash equilibria is obtained depending on the parameter setup: perfect compliance, imperfect compliance or zero compliance. For each equilibrium, we also derive the probabilities of type I (false-positive) and type II (false-negative) errors committed by the cartel authority. To account for the uncertainty and the vague knowledge concerning the model parameters, we perform Monte Carlo simulations based on parameter ranges extracted from the related literature. The simulations indicate that zero compliance dominates the picture and that the error probabilities are high for type II and negligible for type I errors. The results are fairly robust against correlation in the input parameters. Further robustness studies and interactive visualizations can be obtained with a supplemental web application.
Acknowledgements
We are indebted for helpful comments and suggestions to Andrea Günster, Ronald Heiner, Jenny Helstroffer, Roland Kirstein, Stefan Klößner, Christian Koboldt, Christian Pierdzioch, Maarten Pieter Schinkel, Edmund Schuster, Stefan Voigt, Ansgar Wohlschlegel, Wouter Wils and Daniel Zimmer for helpful comments. We also thank two anonymous referees for their very valuable suggestions which improved the presentation considerably.
Appendix
A (Equilibria)
In the first row of Table 1, the equilibrium for the parameter constellation PC1 is depicted. Equilibrium 1, denoted EQ 1, is realized if the condition
In this case, F perfectly complies with the competition law by choosing a compliance level
The second row of Table 1 describes the possible equilibria in parameter constellation PC 2. The equilibrium set EQS 2.1 is reached if the condition
In every equilibrium out of this set F chooses a legal agreement with probability
Here, the firm chooses a compliance level
In the third row of Table 1, the equilibria for the parameter constellation PC3 are depicted. If the condition
In equilibrium EQ 3.1, the firm chooses to form a legal agreement with probability
If the condition
Each of these equilibria implies the firm choosing to form a legal agreement with probability
Finally, in the fifth row of Table 1, the equilibrium of parameter constellation PC5 is depicted. If the condition
B (Equilibrium Selection)
Let us first consider parameter constellation PC2. Here we face a twofold equilibrium selection problem: (1) There are two sets of equilibria EQS 2.1 and EQS 2.2. (2) Within these sets of equilibria, there exist an infinite number of equilibria which differ only with respect to the firm’s compliance level while the Commission’s action remains unchanged. It is worthwhile noting that the multiple equilibria within one set have an interesting feature: they all lead to the same payoff for the firm irrespective the concrete value taken by F’s behavioral strategy
Let us now turn to the second problem in this parameter constellation. Reducing the equilibrium sets EQS 2.1 and EQS 2.2 to one equilibrium each does not fully solve the equilibrium selection problem; there still exist two equilibria in parameter constellation PC2, namely EQ 1 and EQ 3.2. Which of those will be realized? Both equilibria are consistent combinations of equilibrium strategies and corresponding beliefs and therefore are both equally feasible. Still, EQ 1 features a focal point quality which EQ 3.2 does not. The firm’s payoff is higher in EQ 1 than in EQ 3.2.[35] To resolve the selection problem, we refer to a concept known as virtual observability.[36] In our model, the firm is a first-mover as its “real life” move lies before the Commission’s choice, but due to imperfect information the Commission cannot observe the firm’s choice – a situation which is typical of simultaneous games. However, the Commission can anticipate this behavior assuming that the firm will try to reach an equilibrium that maximizes its expected payoff. Thus, the second-mover acts as if the moves of the first-mover were observable. This kind of equilibrium selection is not only intuitively reasonable, but numerous experiments have also provided evidence for it. Hence, the multiple equilibria in parameter constellation PC2 can be reduced to one single equilibrium, namely EQ 1.
In parameter constellation PC3, three different equilibria exist, namely EQ 3.1, EQ 3.2 and EQ 3.3. The concept of virtual observability can again be applied as the firm’s payoff in EQ 3.1 is higher than the ones realized in EQ 3.2 and EQ 3.3.[37] Thus, equilibrium EQ 3.1 dominates the other two equilibria.
In parameter constellation PC4, the equilibrium set EQS 4.1 and the equilibrium EQ 4.2 exist. Within EQS 4.1, the firm’s expected payoff amounts to a single value regardless of the compliance level
C (Parameters)
Control probability (detection probability)
The following estimates can be found in the literature: 10 % (Werden and Simon 1987), 13–17 % (Bryant and Eckard 1991; sample of cartels indicted in the United States between 1961 and 1988). Combe, Monnier, and Legal (2008), applying the same methodology as Bryant and Eckard, calculate a probability of detection in a given year lying between 12.9 % and 13.2 % (sample of all cartels convicted by the European Union between 1969 and 2007). In a recent study, Combe and Monnier propose to use a detection probability of 15 % (Combe and Monnier 2009: 19). This probability is also assumed in the simulation run by Buccirossi and Spagnolo (2007). According to Connor and Bolotova (2006: 9), most evidence seems to suggest a probability between 10 % and 20 %.[38]Connor and Lande (2012) – reviewing the relevant literature – report the following figures: 20.8 %–27.2 % (quantitative economic studies) and 25.6 % (opinions of cartel scholars). Opinion surveys deliver “non-quantifiable but low estimates that are roughly consistent with the first two estimates” (Connor and Lande 2012: 465). Ormosi, applying a method commonly referred to as capture–recapture model or mark and recapture analysis, which is widely used for population studies in ecology, finds that less than a fifth of cartels have been detected in the EU between 1985 and 2005 (Ormosi 2014: 565).
As the number of cartels remaining undetected is unknown, the probabilities of detection are only vague estimates. Moreover, what actually matters is the subjective probability of a cartel getting caught. Note that the detection of a cartel does not necessarily lead to an infliction of fines. Therefore, the detection probability should be discounted by the conviction rate. Using a conviction rate of 75 % would lead to a probability of being fined of 7.5–15 %. Private enforcement as well as the leniency program might increase this range to 11.25–18.75 %. We run a simulation for the control probability range
Reversal probability
Camesasca et al. (2013) consider a sample of 510 parties fined in the period 1998–2009 directed against fines, procedure, facts and substantive assessment: only 29 parties had their fine annulled by the GC) and 2 had it annulled by the CJ; in 104 and 65 cases the GC and the CJ, respectively, upheld the fine and dismissed the case. The remaining parties are still awaiting a judgment or had their appeals removed (Camesasca et al. 2013: 217). Overall, from 1081 pleas that have been filed (against fines, procedure, facts and substantive assessment), only 94 have been successful (Camesasca et al. 2013: 217), which gives a success rate of about 9 %. This is also the overall success rate of pleas directed against fines. The authors conclude: “Regarding the overall success rate, our findings confirm common knowledge – that Commission decisions are upheld on appeal, save for rare exceptions” (Camesasca et al. 2013: 217).
Harding and Gibbs (2005: 365) share this view in principle. From 200 appeals (1995–2004), 6 % are – formally – categorized as successful, 61 % as partly successful (fine reduction) and 33 % as unsuccessful. But they add that a closer reading of the cases termed “partly successful” might suggest that this category should be renamed “largely unsuccessful” (Harding and Gibbs 2005: 366).
Hüschelrath and Smuda (2014) use data of 467 firm groups in 88 cartels convicted by the European Commission between 2000 and 2012: 50 % decided to file an appeal, with 47 % being successful in the sense of receiving a reduction in the fine originally imposed by the Commission (Hüschelrath and Smuda 2014: 17–18). These figures imply that about 25 % of the firm groups successfully appealed and received a fine reduction. But again – as mentioned above – some cases might better be termed “largely unsuccessful”.
Smuda, Bougette, and Hüschelrath (2014) use data of 234 firm groups that participated in 63 cartels convicted by the European Commission between 2000 and 2012. They find that in sum 109 of the 325, i. e. 34 %, first-stage appeals were successful, whereas only 5 % were successful in second-stage appeals.
According to the divergent results of the studies presented above, it seems reasonable to assume in our simulations a reversal rate ranging from 10 to 40%.
Legal profit
Since we are not aware of any estimates of the profitrate associated with legal agreements, we refer to the competitive markup (competitive price–cost margin) used in the literature on the deterrent effect of cartel fines: 1 % to 15 % (Buccirossi and Spagnolo 2007: 95), 5 % to 20 % (Allain et al. 2015), 10 % and a rescaled markup ranging from 17 % to 27 % (Allain et al. 2011).
We assume in our simulations an interval 5 %–20 % for G.
Illegal profit
Illegal profits are estimated as a fixed percentage of the affected market, ranging from 10 % (Werden and Simon 1987) over 20 % (Wils 2006) and 29 % (Connor and Bolotova 2006) up to 150 % (Veljanovski 2007).
Illegal profits result from cartel overcharges. Therefore, cartel overcharges – defined as the difference between the collusive price and the counterfactual “but for” price, in general the competitive price – are also used to estimate illegal profits. Connor (2004) reports a median overcharge for all types of cartels over all time periods (based on 674 observations of long-run overcharges) of 25 % (18 % for domestic cartels, 32 % for international cartels and 28 % for all successful cartels). As for overcharges outside the United States (based on 62 decisions of commissions), the median (mean) turns out to be 29 % (49 %). Based on numerous empirical studies, Combe and Monnier (2009) find it reasonable to assume a 20 % and 30 % average price increase for national and international cartels, respectively.[39]Connor and Bolotova (2006) – surveying more than a thousand estimates of cartel overcharges throughout the centuries worldwide – estimate an average overcharge close to 22 %, with a median of 20 % (see also Bolotova 2009; Schinkel 2007). Allain et al. (2011) argue that the estimates of Connor and Bolotova suffer from an upward bias and calculate a mean value of 17.5 % (see also Katsoulacos and Ulph (2013)). Smuda (2012) calculates mean and median overcharge rates for the European market of 20.70% and 18.37% of the selling price.
Schinkel (2007) concludes: “(It) is likely to be conservative to conclude that a representative cartel manages to establish (annual) illegal gains of roughly 25 % of total annual affected commerce” (Schinkel 2007:144).
For the simulation, we assume an interval for A ranging from 10 % to 30 %.
Fines
From the beginning of cartels prosecution on the European level up to the end of 2008, the average fine amounts to 116 million euros per cartel (Combe and Monnier 2009: 3). Carree, Günster, and Schinkel (2010), Combe and Monnier (2009) and Schinkel (2007) report an upward trend in the level of fines in Europe per type of economic conduct per enforcement period. Since 2006, average fines per cartel exceed 300 million euros (Combe and Monnier 2009: 4).
Cartel fines are set in a two-step procedure according to the 2006 “Guidelines on the method of setting fines” (European Commission 2006). In the first step, a so-called basic amount is determined by “referring to the value of the sales of goods or services to which the infringement relates (European Commission 2006, Introduction, point 6). According to recital 19 of the Guidelines “(the) basic amount will be related to a proportion of the value of sales, depending on the degree of gravity of the infringement, multiplied by the number of years of infringement.” The Commission can take a proportion of up to 30 % of the value of sales (European Commission 2006, recital 21) – usually it chooses 15 %–20 %. For deterrence reasons, the Commission “will include in the basic amount a sum of between 15 % and 25 %” of the relevant value of sales (European Commission 2006, recital 25). So-called entry-fee.
In the second step, this basic amount can be adjusted upward (due to aggravating circumstances, European Commission 2006, recital 28) or downward (due to mitigating circumstances, European Commission 2006, recital 29).
Article 23 of Regulation No 1/2003 stipulates a maximum of the fine of 10 % of total turnover in the preceding business year.
We run a simulation for parameter range
References
Abele, S., and K.-M. Ehrhart. 2005. “The Timing Effect in Public Good Games.” Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 41 (5): 470–481.10.1016/j.jesp.2004.09.004Search in Google Scholar
Allain, M.-L., M. Boyer, R. Kotchoni, and J.-P. Ponssard 2011. “The Determination of Optimal Fines in Cartel Cases. The Myth of Underdeterrence.” Working Paper 2011s-34, CIRANO Scientific Series.10.2139/ssrn.1919006Search in Google Scholar
Allain, M.-L., M. Boyer, R. Kotchoni, and J.-P. Ponssard. 2015. “Are Cartel Fines Optimal? Theory and Evidence from the European Union.” International Review of Law and Economics 42 (2015): 38–47.10.1016/j.irle.2014.12.004Search in Google Scholar
Armstrong, M., and D.E. Sappington. 2007. Recent Developments in the Theory of Regulation, Handbook of Industrial Organization. Vol. 3. ch. 27. 1557–1700. Elsevier: Amsterdam.10.1016/S1573-448X(06)03027-5Search in Google Scholar
Baker, J., and D. Rubinfeld. 1999. “Empirical Methods in Antitrust Litigation: Review and Critique.” American Law and Economics Review 1: 386–435. DOI: 10.1093/aler/1.1.386.Search in Google Scholar
Barros, P. 2003. “Looking behind the Curtain – Effects from Modernization of European Union Competition Policy.” European Economic Review 47 (4): 613–624.10.1016/S0014-2921(02)00289-1Search in Google Scholar
Becker, G. 1968 . “Crime and Puniment: An Economic Approach.” Journal of Political Economy 76: 169– 217.10.1086/259394Search in Google Scholar
Becker, M. (2018). “SimEUCartelLaw: Simulation of Legal Exemption System for European Cartel Law.” R package version 1.0.1. https://CRAN.R-project.org/package=SimEUCartelLawSearch in Google Scholar
Bergman, M. 2008. “Quis Custodiet Ipsos Custodes? or Measuring and Evaluating the Effectiveness of Competition Enforcement.” De Economist 156 (4): 2008.387–409.10.1007/s10645-008-9101-6Search in Google Scholar
Besanko, D., and D. Spulber. 1989. “Antitrust Enforcement under Asymmetric Information.” The Economic Journal 99: 408–425.10.2307/2234033Search in Google Scholar
Bigoni, M., S.-O. Fridolfsson, Coq Ch. Le, and G. Spagnolo. 2012. “Fines, Leniency, and Rewards in Antitrust, RAND.” Journal of Economics 43 (2): 368–390.Search in Google Scholar
Bigoni, M., S.-O. Fridolfsson, Coq Ch. Le, and G. Spagnolo 2014. “Trust, Leniency and Deterrence. Konkurrensverket Working Paper 2014:2.”10.2139/ssrn.2469778Search in Google Scholar
Bijlsma, M., and R. Van Elk 2008. “Opportunistic Competition Law Enforcement.” CBP Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis Discussion Paper No 110.Search in Google Scholar
Bolotova, Y. 2009. “Cartel Overcharges: An Empirical Analysis.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 70 (1–2): 321–341.10.1016/j.jebo.2009.02.002Search in Google Scholar
Bos, I., and J.E. Harrington. 2015. “Competition Policy and Cartel Size.” International Economic Review 56 (1): 133–153.10.1111/iere.12097Search in Google Scholar
Bos, I., W. Letterie, and D. Vermeulen. 2015. “Antitrust as Facilitating Factor for Collusion.” Berkeley Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy 15 (2): 797–814.10.1515/bejeap-2014-0023Search in Google Scholar
Bos, I., and M.P. Schinkel. 2007. “On the Scope for the European Commission’s 2006 Fining Guidelines under the Legal Maximum Fine.” Journal of Competition Law and Economics 2 (4): 673–682.10.2139/ssrn.940107Search in Google Scholar
Bryant, P., and W. Eckard. 1991. “Price Fixing: The Probability of Getting Caught.” Review of Economics and Statistics 73: 531–540.10.2307/2109581Search in Google Scholar
Buccirossi, P., L. Ciari, T. Duso, G. Spagnolo, and C. Vitale 2009. “Deterrence in Competition Law.” GESY Discussion Paper No. 285.10.1142/9789814616362_0015Search in Google Scholar
Buccirossi, P., L. Ciari, T. Duso, G. Spagnolo, and C. Vitale. 2011. “Measuring the Deterrence Properties of Competition Policy Indexes.” Journal of Competition Lawê 7 (1): 165–204.10.1093/joclec/nhq021Search in Google Scholar
Buccirossi, P., and G. Spagnolo. 2006. “Antitrust Sanction Policy in the Presence of Leniency Programs.” Concurrences 4: 25–29.Search in Google Scholar
Buccirossi, P., and G. Spagnolo. 2007. “Optimal Fines in the Era of Whistleblowers. Should Price Fixers Still Go to Prison?.” In Contributions to Economic Analysis vol. 282, edited by V. Ghosal and J. Stennek, Elsevier: North Holland. 81–122.Search in Google Scholar
Camesasca, P.D., J. Ysewyn, Weck Th., and B. Bowman. 2013. “Cartel Appeals to the Court of Justice. The Song of the Sirens?.” Journal of European Competition Law & Practice 4 (3): 215–223.10.1093/jeclap/lpt016Search in Google Scholar
Carree, M., A. Günster, and M.P. Schinkel. 2010. “European Antitrust Policy: An Analysis of Competition Decisions, 1964-2004.” Review of Industrial Organization 36 (2): 97–131.10.1007/s11151-010-9237-9Search in Google Scholar
Chang, W., J. Cheng, J.J. Allaire, Y. Xie, and J. McPherson 2017. “Shiny: Web Application Framework for R. R Package Version 1.0.5.” https://CRAN.R-project.org/package=shinySearch in Google Scholar
Chopard, B., E. Marion, and L. Roussey. 2014. Appeals Process, Judicial Errors and Crime Deterrence. Working Paper, University of Paris Ouest: Nanterre.Search in Google Scholar
Growitsch, Christian, N. Nulsch, and M. Rammerstorfer. 2012. “Preventing Innovative Cooperations: The Legal Exemptions Unintended Side Effects.” European Journal of Law and Economics 33: 1–22.10.1007/s10657-010-9184-9Search in Google Scholar
Combe, E., and C. Monnier 2009. “Fines against Hard Core Cartels in Europe: The Myth of over Enforcement.” PRISM-Sorbonne Working Paper (June 2009).10.2139/ssrn.1431644Search in Google Scholar
Combe, E., C. Monnier, and R. Legal 2008. “Cartels: The Probability of Getting Caught in the European Union.” Bruges European Economic Research Papers, No 12.10.2139/ssrn.1015061Search in Google Scholar
Connor, J. 2006. Optimal Deterrence and Private International Cartels. Working Paper. West Lafayette: Purdue University.10.2139/ssrn.1103598Search in Google Scholar
Connor, J., and Y. Bolotova. 2006. “Cartel Overcharges: Survey and Meta-Analysis.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 25 (6): 1109–1137.10.1016/j.ijindorg.2006.04.003Search in Google Scholar
Connor, J., and R. Lande. 2005. “How High Do Cartels Raise Prices? Implications for Optimal Cartel Fines.” Tulane Law Review 80: 513–570.Search in Google Scholar
Connor, J., and D.J. Miller 2010. “Determinants of EC Antitrust Fines for Members of Global Cartels (Paper Presented at the 3rd LEAR Conference on the Economics of Competition Law, Rome, June 25-26, 2009.”10.2139/ssrn.2229358Search in Google Scholar
Connor, J.M. 2004. “Price-Fixing Overcharges: Legal and Economic Evidence.” American Antitrust Institute Working Paper 04–05.10.1016/S0193-5895(06)22004-9Search in Google Scholar
Connor, J. M., and R. Lande. 2012. “Cartels as Rational Business Strategy: Crime Pays.” Cardozo Law Review 34: 427–489.Search in Google Scholar
Cyrenne, Ph. 1999. “On Antitrust Enforcement and the Deterrence of Collusive Behaviour.” Review of Industrial Organization 14: 257–272.10.1023/A:1007714728676Search in Google Scholar
Davies, St., and P.L. Ormosi. 2012. “A Comparative Assessment of Methodologies to Evaluate Competition Policy.” Journal of Competition Law and Economics 8 (4): 769–803.10.1093/joclec/nhs025Search in Google Scholar
Davies, St., and P.L. Ormosi. (2014a).CCP Working Paper 14-6 The Deterrent Effect of Anti-Cartel Enforcement: A Tale of Two Tails.10.2139/ssrn.2471425Search in Google Scholar
Davies, St, and P.L. Ormosi. The Economic Impact of Cartels and Anti-Cartel Enforcement. http://ssrn.com/abstract=2520014 2014b Available at SSRN:.10.2139/ssrn.2520014Search in Google Scholar
De Alessi, L. 1995. “The Public-Choice Model of Antitrust Enforcement.” In The Causes and Consequences of Antitrust: The Public-Choice Perspective, 189-200, edited by F.S. McChesney and W.F. Shugart II, The University of Chicago Press: Chicago, London.Search in Google Scholar
Di Federico, G., and P. Manzini. 2004. “A Law and Economics Approach to the New European Antitrust Enforcing Rules.” Erasmus Law and Economics Review 1 (2): 143–164.Search in Google Scholar
European Commission 2006. “Guidelines on the Method of Setting Fines Imposed Pursuant to Article 23 (2)(A)Of Regulation No 1/2003 (2006/C 210/02).”.Search in Google Scholar
European Commission 2009a. “Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council.” Report on the functioning of Regulation 1/2003 (Com(2009) 206 final, 29. 4. 2009).Search in Google Scholar
European Commission 2009b. “Commission Staff Working Paper Accompanying the Report on the Functioning of Regulation 1/2003 (SEC(2009) 574 Final, 29. 4. 2009).”Search in Google Scholar
European Commission 2011. “European Commission’s Guidelines (OJ 2011 C11, 14.01.2011).”10.1016/S0306-3747(11)70156-7Search in Google Scholar
Garoupa, N. 1997. “The Theory of Optimal Law Enforcement.” Journal of Economic Surveys 11 (3): 267–295.10.1111/1467-6419.00034Search in Google Scholar
Geradin, D., and N. Petit 2011. “Judicial Review in European Union Competition Law: A Quantitative and Qualitative Assessment.” TILEC Discussion Paper 2011-008.10.2139/ssrn.1698342Search in Google Scholar
Gilli, M., D. Maringer, and E. Schumann. 2011. Numerical Methods and Optimization in Finance. Amsterdam: Academic Press.10.1016/B978-0-12-375662-6.00010-9Search in Google Scholar
Hahn, V. 2000. “Antitrust Enforcement: Abuse Control or Notification?.” European Journal of Law and Economics 10 (1): 69–91.10.1023/A:1018790822256Search in Google Scholar
Harding, C., and A. Gibbs. 2005. “Why Go to Court in Europe? an Analysis of Cartel Appeals, 1995-2004.” European Law Review 30: 349–362.Search in Google Scholar
Harrington, J. E. 2005. “Optimal Cartel Pricing in the Presence of an Antitrust Authority.” International Economic Review 46: 145–169.10.1111/j.0020-6598.2005.00313.xSearch in Google Scholar
Harrington, J.E., and M.-H. Chang. 2009. “Modeling the Death and Birth of Cartels with an Application to Evaluating Competition Policy.” Journal of the European Economic Association December 2009. 7 (6): 1400–1435.10.1162/JEEA.2009.7.6.1400Search in Google Scholar
Hüschelrath, K., and Florian Smuda. 2014. The Appeals Process: An Empirical Assessment. Discussion Paper No. 14-063. Centre for European Economic Research: Mannheim.Search in Google Scholar
Katsoulacos, Y., E. Motchenkova, and D. Ulph. 2015. “Penalizing Cartels: The Case for Basing Penalties on Price Overcharge.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 42: 70–80.10.1016/j.ijindorg.2015.07.007Search in Google Scholar
Katsoulacos, Y., E. Motchenkova, and D. Ulph 2016. “Measuring the Effectiveness of Anti-Cartel Intervention: A Conceptual Framework.” Paper presented at the Conference “Looking Beyond the Direct Effects of the Work of Competition Authorities: Deterrence and Macroeconomic Impact”, 17–18 September 2015. Brussels. Tilburg University - TILEC Discussion Paper DP 2016-001.10.2139/ssrn.2714238Search in Google Scholar
Katsoulacos, Y., and D. Ulph. 2011. “Optimal Enforcement Structures for Competition Policy: Implications of Judicial Reviews and of Internal Error Correction Mechanisms.” European Competition Journal 7: Number 1. 71–88.10.5235/174410511795887624Search in Google Scholar
Katsoulacos, Y., and D. Ulph. 2013. “Antitrust Penalties and the Implications of Empirical Evidence on Cartel Overcharges.” The Economic Journal 123: issue 572. F558–F581.10.1111/ecoj.12075Search in Google Scholar
Katsoulacos, Y., and D. Ulph. 2016. “Legal Uncertainty, Competition Law Enforcement Procedures and Optimal Penalties.” European Journal of Law and Economics 41: 255–282.10.1007/s10657-015-9504-1Search in Google Scholar
Kornhauser, L. A. 2000. “Appeal and Supreme Courts.” In Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, edited by B. Bouckaert and G. De Geest, Vol. V. 45–62. Edward Elgar: Cheltenham.Search in Google Scholar
La Casse, C. 1995. “Bid Riging and the Threat of Government Prosecution.” Rand Journal of Economics 26: 398–417.10.2307/2555995Search in Google Scholar
Levy, G. 2005. “Careerist Judges and the Appeals Process.” RAND Journal of Economics 36 (2): 275–297.Search in Google Scholar
Lianos, I., and C. Genakos. 2013. “Econometric Evidence in EU Competition Law: An Empirical and Theoretical Analysis.” In edited by Handbook on European Competition Law, I. Lianos and D. Geradin, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing. 1–137.Search in Google Scholar
Loss, F., E. Malavolti-Grimal, T. Vergé, and F. Bergès-Sennou. 2008. “European Competition Policy Modernization: From Notifications to Legal Exception.” European Economic Review 52 (1): 77–98.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2007.02.001Search in Google Scholar
Mändmaa, P. 2014. “Assessing the Effectiveness of Competition Law Enforcement Policy in Relation to Cartels.” Journal of Arts & Humanities 03: 11. 33–50.Search in Google Scholar
Motta, M. 2008. “On Cartel Deterrence and Fines in the EU.” European Competition Law Review 29 (4): 209–220.Search in Google Scholar
Neven, D.J. 2002. “Removing the Notification of Agreements: Some Consequences for Ex Post Monitoring.” In European Integration and International Co-Ordination. Studies in Transnational Economic Law in Honour of Claus-Dieter Ehlermann, edited by V. Bogdandy, A. P. M. Mavroidis, and Y. Mény, 351– 362. The Hague: Kluwer Law International.Search in Google Scholar
Official Journal of the European Communities, “2003/L1/1: COUNCIL REGULATION (EC) No 1/2003 of 16 December 2002 on the Implementation of the Rules on Competition Laid down in Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty.”Search in Google Scholar
Official Journal of the European Union. 2012/C326/1: Consolidated Version of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union 2012.Search in Google Scholar
OFT. 2011. The Impact of Competition Interventions on Compliance and Deterrence. Final Report. London: OFT.Search in Google Scholar
Ormosi, P.L. 2012. “Evaluating the Impact of Competition Law Enforcement.” OECD Working Papers DAF/COMP/WP2(2012)5.Search in Google Scholar
Ormosi, P.L. 2014. “A Tip of the Iceberg? the Probability of Catching Cartels.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 29 (4): 549–566.10.1002/jae.2326Search in Google Scholar
Osborne, M.J. 2004. An Introduction to Game Theory. Oxford University Press: New York, Oxford.Search in Google Scholar
Pirrung, M. 2004. “EU Enlargement Towards Cartel Paradise? an Economic Analysis of the Reform of European Competition Law.” Erasmus Law and Economics Review 1 (1): 77–109.Search in Google Scholar
Polinsky, M.A., and S. Shavell. 2007. “The Economic Theory of Public Enforcement of Law.” In Handbook of Law and Economics, edited by M.A. Polinsky and S. Shavell, Vol. 1. 403–454. North Holland: Amsterdam.10.1016/S1574-0730(07)01006-7Search in Google Scholar
Posner, R. 1993. “What Do Judges Maximize? (The Same Thing Everybody Else Does).” Supreme Court Economic Review 3: 1–41.10.1086/scer.3.1147064Search in Google Scholar
R Core Team. 2017. R: A Language and Environment for Statistical Computing. R Foundation for Statistical Computing: Vienna, Austria. URL. https://www.R-project.org/.Search in Google Scholar
Rapoport, A. 1997. “Order of Play in Strategically Equivalent Games in Extensive Form.” International Journal of Game Theory 26 (1): 113–136.10.1007/BF01262516Search in Google Scholar
Schinkel, M. P. 2007. “Effective Cartel Enforcement in Europe.” In The More Economic Approach to European Competition Law, edited by D. Schmidtchen et al., 131–170. Mohr Siebeck: Tübingen.10.1628/186183407785978440Search in Google Scholar
Schinkel, M.P., and J. Tuinstra. 2006. “Imperfect Competition Law Enforcement.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 24 (6): 1267–1297.10.1016/j.ijindorg.2006.04.008Search in Google Scholar
Shavell, S. 1995. “The Appeals Process as a Means of Error Correction.” Journal of Legal Studies 24 (2): 379–426.10.1086/467963Search in Google Scholar
Shavell, S. 2006. “The Appeals Process and Adjudicator Incentives.” Journal of Legal Studies 35 (1): 1–29.10.1086/500095Search in Google Scholar
Shepsle, K., and M. Bonchek. 1997. Analyzing Politics. Rationality, Behavior, and Institutions. W.W. Norton: New York, London.Search in Google Scholar
Smuda, F. 2012. “Cartel Overcharges and the Deterrent Effect of EU Competition Law.” Discussion Paper No. 12-050. Centre for European Economic Research, Mannheim.10.2139/ssrn.2118566Search in Google Scholar
Smuda, F., P. Bougette, and K. Hüschelrath (2014). “Determinants of the Duration of European Appelate Court Proceedings in Cartel Cases.” Discussion Paper No. 14-062. Centre for European Economic Research, Mannheim.Search in Google Scholar
Soetaert, K. 2016. “plot3Drgl: Plotting Multi-Dimensional Data - Using ‘Rgl’. R Package Version 1.0.1.” https://CRAN.R-project.org/package=plot3DrglSearch in Google Scholar
Sokol, D.D. 2012. “Cartels, Corporate Compliance, and What Practitioners Really Think about Performance.” Antitrust Law Journal 78 (1): 201–240.Search in Google Scholar
Spulber, D. 1989. Regulation and Markets. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar
Van Der Noll, Rob, and Barbara Baarsma. 2017. “Compliance with Cartel Laws and the Determinants of Deterrence – An Empirical Investigation.” European Competition Journal 13 (2–3): 336–355.10.1080/17441056.2017.1387450Search in Google Scholar
Veljanovski, C. 2007. “Cartel Fines in Europe: Law Practice and Deterrence.” World Competition 30: 65–86.10.54648/WOCO2007004Search in Google Scholar
Watson, J. 2002. Strategy. An Introduction to Game Theory. New York: London. W.W. Norton & Company.Search in Google Scholar
Weber, R., C. Camerer, and M. Knez. 2004. “Timing and Virtual Observability in Ultimatum Bargaining and “Weak Link” Coordination Games.” Experimental Economics 7 (1): 25–48.10.1023/A:1026257921046Search in Google Scholar
Werden, G., and M. Simon. 1987. “Why Price Fixers Should Go to Prison.” The Antitrust Bulletin 32: 917–937.10.1177/0003603X8703200403Search in Google Scholar
Wils, W. 2006. “Optimal Antitrust Fines: Theory and Practice.” World Competition 29: 183–208.10.54648/WOCO2006014Search in Google Scholar
Wils, W. 2007. “Leniency in Antitrust Enforcement: Theory and Practice.” In The More Economic Approach to European Competition Law, edited by D. Schmidtchen et al., 203–248. Mohr Siebeck: Tübingen.10.1628/186183407785978422Search in Google Scholar
Wils, W. P. J. 2002. “Notification, Clearance and Exemption in EC Competition Law.” In The Optimal Enforcement of EC Antitrust Law: Essays in Law & Economics. European Monographs, edited by W.P.J. Wils, et al., Vol. 33, 82– 104. The Hague: Kluwer Law International.Search in Google Scholar
Witt, A. (2018). “The Enforcement of Article 101 TFEU – What Has Happened to the Effects Analysis?.” University of Leicester - Leicester Law School Research Paper No. 18-01.10.54648/COLA2018032Search in Google Scholar
© 2018 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston