Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter August 6, 2019

Horizontal Mergers in a Dynamic Cournot Market: Solving the Free Riding Issue Without Efficiency Gains

  • Marc Escrihuela-Villar and Walter Ferrarese ORCID logo EMAIL logo

Abstract

We discuss horizontal mergers in a linear, homogeneous, symmetric Cournot market where the new entity repeatedly competes with outside firms over an indefinite horizon and efficiency gains are ruled out. If the degree of collusion among the outside firms is large enough, then, despite the large payoff of each outsider, we obtain output configurations solving both the profitability and the free riding issues. Such a result requires that mergers involve a sufficiently small number of firms, which is in sharp contrast with the findings in the literature and rationalize the empirical fact that relatively small mergers, even in absence of synergies, do actually occur and that, although outside firms may benefit from the merger of their rivals, insiders end up being better off. Finally, we show that merging can often be a more advantageous alternative than a fully collusive agreement, in which, moreover, the free riding component is not solved.

JEL Classification: L11; L13; C73

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Carmen Bevia, Berardino Cesi, Lapo Filistrucchi, Alberto Iozzi, Antonio Nicoló, Luca Panaccione, Francesco Ruscitti, Francois Salanié, Helder Vasconcelos and the seminar audience at the University of Rome Tor Vergata.

Appendix

A Stick and Carrot Strategies

Grim trigger strategies are unforgiving and an everlasting punishment may seem unrealistic. Stick and carrot strategies are forgiving and overcome the issue. We here show that all output configurations in Proposition 2, and not just the restriction to those of Proposition 3, can be produced in equilibrium under stick and carrot strategies (Abreu 1986, 1988). In these strategies, if a firm deviates from the cooperative path, firms expand output for one period and then go back to cooperation, provided that no further deviation from the punishment path occurred. Although here firms do not produce the same output in the cooperative phase, we show that an equilibrium in which all firms produce the same punishment quantity exists. Let:

(15)ΠIp=πIp+δ1δΠIc;
(16)ΠIp=πIp+δ1δΠIc,o = 1,...,nm,

denote the present discounted values of future profits in the punishment period and along the following cooperative paths for the merged entity and each outsider respectively. The incentive compatibility constraints write:

(17)11δΠIc(QI,qo)ΠId(QId,qo)+δ(ΠIp(QIp,qop)+δ1δΠIc(QI,qo));
(18)11δΠoc(QI,qo)Πod(QIc,qo,qod)+δ(Πop(QIp,qop)+δ1δΠoc(QI,qo)),o=1,,nm.

Constraints ensuring that firms do not deviate from the punishment path are also needed. These write:

(19)ΠIpΠIdp+δΠIp;
(20)ΠopΠodp+δΠop,o=1,...,nm.

The following proposition describes the equilibrium of the repeated game:

Proposition 6.

Let:

(21)δoIC(n,m,qo)=(1(nm2)qo)28qo(1(nm)qo16((1(nm)qo2)qo+1(nm)2);
(22)δoP(n,m,qo)=1(nm)2(1(nm)qo2)qo+1(nm)2.

Provided thatmax{δoIC,δoP}<1, then ifδ(max{δoIC,δoP},1), an output configurations whereqo(qo_,qo¯)andQI(qo)=1(nm)qo2is produced in equilibrium in the infinitely repeated Cournot game under stick and carrot strategies.

B  

Proof of Proposition 1.

Consider the system:

(23){(1QI(nm)qo)QI1(n+1)2;(1QI(nm)qo)qo1(n+1)2,o=1,...,nm;(1QI(nm)qo)QIm(1QI(nm)qo)qo.

The first two conditions ensure that both the merged entity and each outsider obtain at least the pre-merger CN profit and the third condition ensures that the single insider obtains at least the same profit of an outsider. System (23) can be rewritten as:

(24){(1QI(nm)qo)QI1(n+1)2;(1QI(nm)qo)qo1(n+1)2,o=1,...,nm;QImqo.

System (24) is solved by the output configuration (qo,QI(qo)) of Proposition 1.   □

Proof of Proposition 2.

The first step is to solve [P]. The Lagrangian of the problem is:

L=ΠIc+λ(ΠocΠiCN(nm+1))+γ(ΠIcΠiCN(nm+1))+ω(ΠIcmΠoc),

where (λ, γ, ω) are the Lagrange multipliers. Since we focus on an interior solution, then λ=γ=ω=0. The Karush–Kuhn–Tucker first order conditions write:

(25)LQI=1(nm)qo2QI=0;
(26)QILQI=0;
(27)Lλ=(1(nm)qoQI)qo(1nm+2)2>0;
(28)λLλ=0;
(29)Lγ=(1(nm)qoQI)QI(1nm+2)2>0;
(30)γLγ=0;
(31)Lω=QImqo>0;
(32)ωLω=0.

First notice that condition (31) is just a simpler way of rewriting ΠIcmΠoc>0. From (25):

(33)QI=1(nm)qo2.

Plugging (33) in (27), yields:

(34)(1(nm)qo2)qo(1nm+2)2>0.

Plugging (33) in (29), yields:

(35)(1(nm)qo2)2(1nm+2)2>0.

Plugging (33) in (31), yields:

(36)qo<1n+m.

System (34)–(36) has solutions if m2,n>n¯(m) and qo(qo_,qo¯). It remains to show the existence of a discount factor δ ∈ (0, 1) such that (7) and (8) hold. First remember that (7) is always satisfied. Turning to (8), pick any qo(qo_,qo¯) and also remember that, according to [P], Πoc=(1(nm)qo2)qo. We now compute each outsider’s deviation profit. Let:

(37)qod=argmaxqod¯(1QI(nm1)qoqod¯)qod¯,

from which qod=1QI(nm1)qo2. Substituting QI=1(nm)qo2 in qod and plugging back into the deviation profit, one obtains that Πod=(1(nm2)qo4)2. Hence, (8) becomes:

(38)11δ(1(nm)qo2)qo(1(nm2)qo4)2+δ1δ(1nm+2)2.

Solving (38) w.r.to δ, yields:

(39)δ(nm+2)2(1qo(nm+2))(mn+2)(mn6+qo((mn)24))=δv(n,m;qo).

   □

Proof of Proposition 3.

From the output configurations provided in (12) and (13), the profit of an outside firm can be written as Πoc(n,m,δ)=(A2)4+2(A24)2δ(A6)(2+A)2(3A2)δ2((A2)3(A2)(2+A)2δ)2, with Am – n. It is easy to check that Πoc(n,m,δ) increases with δ if δ<δ^(n,m), decreases with δ if δ>δ^(n,m) and, therefore, reaches its maximum at δ=δ^(n,m). Then, from Proposition 2, we can evaluate δv(n,m;qo) at qo_ and qo¯ respectively to obtain the range of the discount factor such that the merger is profitable and the free riding issue is solved. We obtain that δv(n,m;qo_)=1 and δv(n,m;qo¯)=δ~. Finally, we just have to check that δ~ is smaller than δ^(n,m), as, otherwise, we know from (12) that outside firms would not produce within the required range. It is immediate to check that δ~<δ^(n,m)iffn ≥ 3m.   □

Proof of Proposition 4.

From the output configurations provided in (12) and (13), the market share of the insiders sI=δ(3m3n2)(2+mn)+(2m+n)2δ(2+mn)(m22+n(3+n)m(3+2n))(mn1)(2m+n)2. First we check that sI always increases with δ, as sIδ=4(mn2)3(nm)(2+mn)((mn1)(2m+n)2δ(2+mn)(m22+n(3+n)m(3+2n)))2>0 whenever n ≥ 3m. Finally, we just have to check that sI = m/n if δ=δ~ and sI = 1/3 if δ=δ^.   □

Proof of Proposition 5.

From the output configurations provided in (12) and (13), Π^Ic(n,2,δ)=(n2+δ(n4)(3n4))2n2(n2δ(n4)2)2. From (14), Πfc(n,δ)=((1+n)2δ(n1)(3+n))((1+n)2+δ(n1)(1+3n))(1+n)2((1+n)2δ(n1)2)2. Then, since both Π^Ic(n,2,δ) and Πfc(n,δ) increase monotonically with δ if δ<δ^(n,m), we just have to check that the equation Π^Ic(n,2,δ)2=Πfc(n,δ) has a unique root in δ, which is always larger than δ~ if n ≥ 8. This can be easily proved with a standard mathematical software. We used the program Wolfram Mathematica 7.0. Details are available from the authors upon request.   □

Proof of Proposition 6.

When the representative outsider and the merged entity deviate from the punishment phase, they choose their deviation quantities qodp and QIdp in order to maximize:

(40)Πodp=(1(nm1)qopQIpqodp)qodp;
(41)ΠIdp=(1(nm)qopQIdp)QIdp.

Thus, when the merged entity deviates from the punishment phase its production is QIdp=1(nm)qop2 and its profit is ΠIdp=(1(nm)qop2)2. This profit is equal to zero if qop=1nm.

When the representative outsider deviates from the punishment phase its production is qodp=1(nm1)qopQIp2 and its payoff is Πodp=(1QIp(nm1)qop2)2. Substituting qop=1nm in Πodp, yields Πodp=((nm)(1QIp)(nm1)2(nm))2. This profit is equal to zero if QIp=1nm. Moreover, straightforward calculation shows that if QIp=qop=1nm, then the punishment profits of the representative outsider and the merged entity are Πop=ΠIp=1(nm)2.

As ΠIc=ΠId, (17) becomes ΠIcΠIp, which is always satisfied. Constraints (18)–(20) write:

(42)δ1(nm)2(1(nm)qo2)2+1(nm)2=δIP;
(43)δ(1(nm2)qo)28qo(1(nm)qo)16((1(nm)qo2)qo+1(nm)2)=δoIC;
(44)δ1(nm)2(1(nm)qo2)qo+1(nm)2=δoP.

By construction ΠIc>Πoc, thereby (42) is redundant. Thus, provided that max{δoIC,δoP}<1, when δ(max{δoIC,δoP},1) collusion is feasible.   □

References

Abreu, D. 1986. “Extremal Equilibria of Oligopolistic Supergames.” Journal of Economic Theory 39: 191–225.10.1016/0022-0531(86)90025-6Search in Google Scholar

Abreu, D. 1988. “On the Theory of Infinitely Repeated Games with Discounting.” Econometrica 56: 383–96.10.2307/1911077Search in Google Scholar

Abreu, D., D. Pearce, and E. Stacchetti. 1993. “Renegotiation and Symmetry in Repeated Games.” Journal of Economic Theory 60: 217–40.10.1006/jeth.1993.1042Search in Google Scholar

Andrade, G., M. Mitchell, and E. Stafford. 2001. “New Evidence and Perspectives on Mergers.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 15: 103–20.10.1257/jep.15.2.103Search in Google Scholar

Banerjee, A., and W. Eckard. 1998. “Are Mega-Mergers Anticompetitive? Evidence From the First Great Merger Wave.” The RAND Journal of Economics 29: 803–27.10.2307/2556095Search in Google Scholar

Bloch, F. 2002. “Coalitions and Networks in Industrial Organization.” The Manchester School 70: 36–55.10.1111/1467-9957.00282Search in Google Scholar

Brito, D., and M. Catalão-Lopes. 2011. “Small Fish Become Big Fish: Mergers in Stackelberg Markets Revisited.” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy 11: 1–18.10.2202/1935-1682.2817Search in Google Scholar

Budzinski, O., and J. P. Kretschmer. 2016. “Implications of Unprofitable Horizontal Mergers: A Positive External Effect Does Not Suffice to Clear a Merger.” Contemporary Economics 10: 13–26.10.5709/ce.1897-9254.195Search in Google Scholar

Cesi, B. 2010. “Horizontal Mergers: A Solution of the Insiders’ Dilemma.” Bulletin of Economic Research 62: 171–80.10.1111/j.1467-8586.2009.00322.xSearch in Google Scholar

Cheung, F. K. 1992.“Two Remarks on the Equilibrium Analysis of Horizontal Mergers.” Economics Letters 40: 119–23.10.1016/0165-1765(92)90254-VSearch in Google Scholar

Compte, O., F. Jenny, and P. Rey 2002. “ Capacity Constraints, Mergers and Collusion.” European Economic Review 46: 1–29.10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00099-XSearch in Google Scholar

Cunha, M., and H. Vasconcelos. 2015. “Mergers in Stackelberg Markets with Efficiency Gains.” Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 15: 105–34.10.1007/s10842-014-0182-4Search in Google Scholar

Clougherty, J. A., and Duso, T. 2009. “The Impact of Horizontal Mergers on Rivals: Gains to Being Left Outside the Merger.” Journal of Management Studies 46: 1365–95.10.1111/j.1467-6486.2009.00852.xSearch in Google Scholar

Davies, S. W., and Olczak, M. 2008. “Tacit Versus Overt Collusion. Firm Asymmetries and Numbers: What’s the Evidence?” Competition Policy International 4: 175–200.10.2139/ssrn.1295973Search in Google Scholar

Daughety, A. F. 1990. “Beneficial Concentration.” American Economic Review 80: 1231–37.Search in Google Scholar

Deneckere, R., and C. Davidson. 1984. “Horizontal Mergers and Collusive Behavior.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 2: 117–32.10.1016/0167-7187(84)90026-2Search in Google Scholar

Deneckere, R., and C. Davidson. 1985. “Incentives to form Coalitions with Bertrand Competition.”The RAND Journal of Economics 16: 473–86.10.2307/2555507Search in Google Scholar

Dockner, E., and A. Gaunesdorfer. 2001. “On the Profitability of Horizontal Mergers in Industries with Dynamic Competition.” Japan and the World Economy 16: 119–23.10.1016/S0922-1425(01)00061-5Search in Google Scholar

Escrihuela-Villar, M. 2008. “Partial Coordination and Mergers Among Quantity-Setting Firms.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 26: 803–10.10.1016/j.ijindorg.2007.06.002Search in Google Scholar

Escrihuela-Villar, M. 2016. “On Merger Profitability and the Intensity of Rivarly.” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy 16: 1203–11.10.1515/bejeap-2015-0209Search in Google Scholar

Escrihuela-Villar, M., and R. Faulí-Oller. 2008. “Mergers in Asymmetric Stackelberg Markets.” Spanish Economic Review 10 (4): 1–10.10.1007/s10108-007-9038-ySearch in Google Scholar

Faulí-Oller, R. 1997. “On Merger Profitability in a Cournot Setting.” Economics Letters 54: 75–79.10.1016/S0165-1765(96)00944-5Search in Google Scholar

Farrell, J., and C. Shapiro. 1990. “Horizontal Mergers: An Equilibrium Analysis.” American Economic Review 80: 107–26.Search in Google Scholar

Fee, E. C., and S. Thomas. 2004. “Sources of Gains in Horizontal Mergers: Evidence from Customer, Supplier, and Rival Firms.” Journal of Financial Economics 74: 423–60.10.1016/j.jfineco.2003.10.002Search in Google Scholar

Fridolfsson, S. O., and J. Stennek. 2005. “Why Mergers Reduce Profits and Raise Share-Prices: A Theory of Preemptive Mergers.” Journal of the European Economic Association 3: 1083–104.10.1162/1542476054729455Search in Google Scholar

Friedman, J. W. 1971. “A Non-Cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames.” Review of Economic Studies 28: 1–12.10.1017/CBO9780511528231.011Search in Google Scholar

Ganslandt, M., L. Persson, and H. Vasconcelos. 2012. “Endogenous Mergers and Collusion in Asymmetric Market Structures.” Economica 79: 766–91.10.1111/j.1468-0335.2012.00937.xSearch in Google Scholar

Gelves, A. 2008. “Horizontal Merger with An Inefficient Leader.” The Manchester School 78: 379–94.10.1111/j.1467-9957.2009.02144.xSearch in Google Scholar

Gowrisankaran, G. 1999. “A Dynamic Model of Endogenous Horizontal Mergers.” The RAND Journal of Economics 30: 56–83.10.2307/2556046Search in Google Scholar

Gugler, K., D. C. Mueller, B. Yurtoglu, and C. Zulehner. 2003. “The Effects of Mergers: An International Comparison.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 21: 625–53.10.1016/S0167-7187(02)00107-8Search in Google Scholar

Hennessy, D. A. 2000. “Cournot Oligopoly Conditions Under Which Any Horizontal Merger is Profitable.” Review of Industrial Organization 17: 277–84.10.1023/A:1007804129800Search in Google Scholar

Heywood, J. S., and M. McGinty 2007a. “ Convex Costs and the Merger Paradox Revisited.” Economic Inquiry 45: 342–49.10.1111/j.1465-7295.2006.00010.xSearch in Google Scholar

Heywood, J. S., and M. McGinty 2007b. “ Mergers Among Leaders and Mergers Among Followers.” Economics Bulletin 12: 1–7.Search in Google Scholar

Heywood, J. S., and M. McGinty 2008. “Leading and Merging: Convex Costs, Stackelberg and the Merger Paradox.” Southern Economic Journal 74: 879–93.10.1002/j.2325-8012.2008.tb00869.xSearch in Google Scholar

Huck, S., K. Konrad, and W. Muller 2001. “Big Fish Eat Small Fish: On Mergers in Stackelberg Markets.” Economics letters 73: 213–17.10.1016/S0165-1765(01)00490-6Search in Google Scholar

Huck, S., K. Konrad, W. Muller and H. T. Normann. 2007. “The Merger Paradox and Why Aspirations Level Let it Fail in the Laboratory.” Economic Journal 117: 1073–95.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02067.xSearch in Google Scholar

Huck S., K. Konrad, and W. Muller. 2008. “Mergers Without Cost Advantages.” In 2 Issues in Competition Law and Policy 1575 (ABA Section of Antitrust Law 2008, Chapter 64).10.2139/ssrn.713281Search in Google Scholar

Kamien, M. I., and I. Zang. 1990. “The Limits of Monopolization Through Acquisition.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 105: 465–99.10.2307/2937796Search in Google Scholar

Kamien, M. I., and I. Zang. 1991. “Competitively Cost Advantageous Mergers and Monopolization.” Games and Economic Behavior 3: 323–38.10.1016/0899-8256(91)90031-9Search in Google Scholar

Kamien, M. I., and I. Zang 1993. “Monopolization by Sequential Acquisition.” Journal of Law, Economics & Organization 9: 205–29.Search in Google Scholar

Lindqvist, T., and J. Stennek. 2005. “The Insiders’ Dilemma: An Experiment on Merger Formation.” Experimental Economics 8: 267–84.10.1007/s10683-005-1466-7Search in Google Scholar

Osborne, D. K. 1976. “Cartel Problems.” American Economic Review 66: 835–44.Search in Google Scholar

Perry, M. K., and R. H. Porter. 1985. “ Oligopoly and the Incentive for Horizontal Mergers.” American Economic Review 75: 219–27.Search in Google Scholar

Posada, P., and O. R. Straume. 2004. “Merger, Partial Collusion and Relocation.” Journal of Economics 83 (3): 243–65.10.1007/s00712-004-0091-9Search in Google Scholar

Salant, S., S. Switzer, and R. J. Reynolds. 1983. “Losses from Horizontal Mergers: The Effects of an Exogenous Change in Industry Structure on Cournot-Nash Equilibrium.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98: 185–99.10.2307/1885620Search in Google Scholar

Shaffer, J. C. 2007. “Competition Law and Policy in Mexico 2004.” OECD Journal: Competition Law and Policy 8 (3): 7–68.10.1787/clp-v8-art6-enSearch in Google Scholar

Simon, H. A. 1955. “A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 69: 99–118.10.2307/1884852Search in Google Scholar

Simon, H. A. 1959. “Theories of Decision Making in Economics and Behavioral Science.” American Economic Review 49: 253–83.Search in Google Scholar

Stigler, G. J. 1950. “Monopoly and Oligopoly by a Merger.” American Economic Review 40: 23–34.Search in Google Scholar

Tichy, G. 2001. “What do We Know About Success and Failure of Mergers?” Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 1: 347–94.Search in Google Scholar

Vasconcelos, H. 2005. “Tacit Collusion, Cost Asymmetries and Mergers.” The RAND Journal of Economics 36: 39–62.Search in Google Scholar

Verboven, F. 1997. “Collusive Behavior with Heterogeneous Firms.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 33: 121–36.10.1016/S0167-2681(97)00025-5Search in Google Scholar

Vives, X. 1999. “Oligopoly Pricing: Old Ideas and New Tools.” The MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2019-08-06

© 2019 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 6.6.2023 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2018-0321/html
Scroll to top button