Abstract
This paper studies the design of investment policies in defined contribution retirement systems. I estimate a dynamic system of correlated equations of lifecycle behavior that fully models the individual’s decision-making process to account for estimation biases. In the model, individuals make decisions that impact their retirement wealth within the Chilean retirement system. Behaviors are allowed to depend on risk preferences while modeling other sources of nonlinear unobserved heterogeneity. The estimated decision-making process allows us to simulate the effects of policy experiments (ex ante), such as defaulting individuals into riskier investment strategies or increasing contribution rates. The results indicate that individuals react by opting into safer plans despite their observed inertia and that increases in mandatory contributions generate little crowding out of other behaviors. Not modeling risk aversion and its endogeneity with behavior leads to substantial simulation biases.
Funding source: UdeC-VRID
Award Identifier / Grant number: 2021000177INI
Funding source: ANID - Millennium Science Initiative Program
Award Identifier / Grant number: NCS2021_072
Acknowledgement
I thank the Chilean Subsecretary of Social Prevision for providing and authorizing the use of the data. No conflicts of interest need to be declared. This work was funded by ANID - Millennium Science Initiative Program - NCS2021_072 and by UdeC-VRID 2021000177INI.
Appendix A: Figures

Timing of decisions, subjective assessments, and stochastic realizations.
Appendix B: Data Description
B.1 Construction of Elicited Risk Aversion
The questions asked in waves 2, 3, and 4 of the EPS follow. The first question asks, “Suppose that you are the only income earner in the household. You need to choose between two jobs. Which option do you prefer? (Option A) a job with a lifetime-stable and certain salary or (Option B) a job where you have the same chances of doubling your lifetime income or earning only 1/4 of your lifetime income”. If the answer to the question is “option A”, the interviewer continues. “Now, what do you prefer? (Option A) a job with a lifetime-stable and certain salary or (Option B) a job where you have the same chances of doubling your lifetime income or earning only half of your lifetime income”.
The least risk-averse categories come directly from question 1. Elicited risk aversion equals 3 for individuals who selected “option B” in the first question. If the individual chooses “option A” in the first question, the risk aversion index is constructed using the second question. Individuals who chose “option B” in the second question belong to the second category (elicited risk aversion of 2), and individuals who chose “option A” in the second question belong to the most risk-averse category because individuals assigned to this category exhibited that they are not willing to accept any gamble (elicited risk aversion equals 1).
Wave 1 uses “decreasing up to 75%”. Because the first wave is used to set the initial conditions, observed risk aversion from wave 1 does not enter the model. Only one specification exists in which initial elicited risk aversion is modeled. Although the questions are mathematically equivalent, to prevent loss aversion biases through changes in the wording,[32] the specification accounts for measurement error, among other potential sources of bias.
B.2 Sample Construction
Construction of research sample.
Sample | # Individuals |
---|---|
Whole sample | 21,051 |
Reference sample | |
Age between 25 and 59 years old in 2002I | 13,178 |
And observed in 3 consecutive periods | |
First three waves | 8545 |
Last three waves | 8869 |
And no attrition no death | |
Observed in all four wavesII | 7238 |
And information available for key variables | |
Research sampleIII | 7168 |
-
(a) IIndividuals who show up in more than one period. IIDeath rates are low for individuals aged between 25 and 59 years in 2002. IIINo missing information on health status, optional savings decisions, work experience, marital status, and region of residence.
Summary statistics for demographic variables between reference and research sample (2002).
Variable | Reference sample | Research sample | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | Std. Dev. | Mean | Std. Dev. | |
Age | 40.633 | 9.461 | 40.715 | 9.275 |
Female | 0.497 | 0.500 | 0.462 | 0.499 |
Education category | ||||
Less than high school | 0.413 | 0.492 | 0.531 | 0.499 |
High school | 0.259 | 0.438 | 0.285 | 0.452 |
Technical college | 0.104 | 0.305 | 0.109 | 0.311 |
College or Post-college | 0.067 | 0.250 | 0.065 | 0.247 |
Missing | 0.158 | 0.365 | 0.010 | 0.098 |
B.3 Summary Statistics
Summary statistics of dependent variables for research sample.
Variable | Estimator | Mean | Std. Dev. | Min. | Max. | N |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Employment (e t ) | mlogit | 21,504 | ||||
Full-time employed | 0.690 | 0.462 | 0 | 1 | ||
Part-time employed | 0.031 | 0.174 | 0 | 1 | ||
Not working | 0.278 | 0.448 | 0 | 1 | ||
Occupation (o t ) (if working) | mlogit | 15,327 | ||||
Elementary occupations | 0.219 | 0.414 | 0 | 1 | ||
Legis., prof., tech., other | 0.185 | 0.388 | 0 | 1 | ||
Clerical support workers | 0.107 | 0.309 | 0 | 1 | ||
Service and sales workers | 0.147 | 0.354 | 0 | 1 | ||
Agricultural, craft and trade | 0.057 | 0.231 | 0 | 1 | ||
Operators and assemblers. | 0.286 | 0.452 | 0 | 1 | ||
Investment (i t ) | Logit | 21,504 | ||||
Account A (riskier) | 0.104 | 0.305 | 0 | 1 | ||
Account B | 0.231 | 0.422 | 0 | 1 | ||
Account C | 0.495 | 0.500 | 0 | 1 | ||
Account D | 0.215 | 0.411 | 0 | 1 | ||
Account E (safest) | 0.037 | 0.189 | 0 | 1 | ||
Savings outcomes (s t ) | Logit | 21,490 | ||||
Any optional savings | 0.263 | 0.441 | 0 | 1 | ||
Duration of Life
|
ols | 75.780 | 10.091 | 30 | 110 | 17,287 |
Elicited Risk Aversion (r t ) | mlogit | 20,557 | ||||
Most risk-averse | 0.747 | 0.435 | 0 | 1 | ||
Intermediate risk-averse | 0.076 | 0.265 | 0 | 1 | ||
Least risk-averse | 0.177 | 0.381 | 0 | 1 | ||
Log of wage (w t ) | Ols | 0.657 | 1.440 | −10.219 | 5.255 | 14,705 |
Marital status (mt+1) | Logit | 21,504 | ||||
Married | 0.571 | 0.495 | 0 | 1 | ||
Variation in children(nt+1) | mlogit | 21,060 | ||||
No change | 0.788 | 0.408 | 0 | 1 | ||
Decrease | 0.184 | 0.387 | 0 | 1 | ||
Increase | 0.028 | 0.165 | 0 | 1 | ||
Medical consumption (kt+1) | Ols | 21,438 | ||||
Number of medical visits | 6.697 | 12.639 | 0 | 240 | ||
Health status (Ht+1) | mlogit | 14,336 | ||||
Very good | 0.147 | 0.354 | 0 | 1 | ||
Good | 0.519 | 0.500 | 0 | 1 | ||
Regular | 0.266 | 0.442 | 0 | 1 | ||
Poor | 0.068 | 0.252 | 0 | 1 |
Summary statistics of explanatory variables entering period t for research sample.
Variable | Mean | Std. Dev. | Min. | Max. |
---|---|---|---|---|
Work experience (years) | 15.646 | 8.111 | 0 | 30 |
Employment status in period t | ||||
Full-time worker | 0.691 | 0.462 | 0 | 1 |
Part-time worker | 0.032 | 0.177 | 0 | 1 |
Not employed | 0.277 | 0.447 | 0 | 1 |
Occupation category in period t | ||||
Elementary occupations | 0.117 | 0.322 | 0 | 1 |
Legis., Prof., Tech., other | 0.099 | 0.298 | 0 | 1 |
Clerical support workers | 0.057 | 0.232 | 0 | 1 |
Service and sales workers | 0.078 | 0.269 | 0 | 1 |
Agricultural, craft and trade, other | 0.030 | 0.172 | 0 | 1 |
Operators and assemblers | 0.153 | 0.360 | 0 | 1 |
Lagged investment decision | ||||
Account A (riskiest) | 0.059 | 0.235 | 0 | 1 |
Account B | 0.135 | 0.341 | 0 | 1 |
Account C | 0.495 | 0.500 | 0 | 1 |
Account D | 0.095 | 0.293 | 0 | 1 |
Account E (safest) | 0.021 | 0.144 | 0 | 1 |
Value of assets | 5.906 | 12.487 | 0 | 241 |
Any optional savings | 0.218 | 0.413 | 0 | 1 |
Married | 0.569 | 0.495 | 0 | 1 |
Duration of marriage (years) | 11.444 | 12.626 | 0 | 56 |
Number of children | 1.009 | 1.083 | 0 | 8 |
Number of medical visits in period t | 5.007 | 11.31 | 0 | 240 |
Health status | ||||
Very good | 0.139 | 0.346 | 0 | 1 |
Good | 0.536 | 0.499 | 0 | 1 |
Fair | 0.266 | 0.442 | 0 | 1 |
Poor | 0.059 | 0.236 | 0 | 1 |
Age | 43.965 | 9.628 | 25 | 66 |
Female | 0.462 | 0.499 | 0 | 1 |
Education category | ||||
Less than high school | 0.536 | 0.499 | 0 | 1 |
High school | 0.334 | 0.472 | 0 | 1 |
Technical college | 0.097 | 0.296 | 0 | 1 |
College and post-graduate | 0.025 | 0.156 | 0 | 1 |
Exclusion restrictions | ||||
Unemployment rate | 9.226 | 2.261 | 4.200 | 15 |
Number of hospital beds (# per 1000 population) | 2.345 | 0.373 | 1.300 | 3.900 |
Number of doctors (# per 1000 population) | 0.978 | 0.220 | 0.580 | 1.870 |
Number of marriages (# year per 1000 population) | 3.486 | 0.437 | 2.500 | 5.100 |
Inches of rainfall (thousand inches per year) | 17.501 | 13.705 | 0.000 | 65.450 |
College tuition (thousand dollars) | 3.240 | 0.641 | 0.000 | 4.300 |
Missing indicators | ||||
Missing: number of children | 0.021 | 0.142 | 0 | 1 |
Missing: education | 0.007 | 0.082 | 0 | 1 |
Missing: occupation | 0.261 | 0.439 | 0 | 1 |
Missing: marriage duration | 0.005 | 0.069 | 0 | 1 |
Missing: number of medical visits | 0.252 | 0.434 | 0 | 1 |
Appendix C: Estimation Results (Preferred Model)
C.1 Likelihood Function
The likelihood function conditional and unconditional to the unobserved heterogeneity is given by Eqs. (12) and (13), respectively.
where
where PW μq is the probability of observing q mass points for the permanent component μ, and PW νr is the probability of observing r mass points for the time-varying component ν t . These approximate the true distributions of μ and ν t .
C.2 Empirical Specification and Identification
Specification of set of equations in preferred empirical model.
Equation | Explanatory variables | ||
---|---|---|---|
Predetermined | Exogenous | Unobserved | |
variables | variables | heterogeneity | |
Employment (e t ) | it−1, st−1,
|
X
t
,
|
μ
E
,
|
Occupation (o t ) | it−1, st−1,
|
X
t
,
|
μ
O
,
|
Savings (s t ) | it−1,
|
X
t
,
|
μ
S
,
|
Investment in A
|
it−1, st−1,
|
X
t
,
|
|
Investment in B
|
it−1, st−1,
|
X
t
,
|
|
Investment in C
|
it−1, st−1,
|
X
t
,
|
|
Investment in D
|
it−1, st−1,
|
X
t
,
|
|
Investment in E
|
it−1, st−1,
|
X
t
,
|
|
Duration of life
|
it−1, st−1,
|
X
t
,
|
|
Elicited risk aversion (r t ) | it−1, st−1,
|
X
t
,
|
μ
R
,
|
Log wage (w t |e t , o t ) | E t , H t | X
t
,
|
μ
W
,
|
Medical consumption (k t ) | H t | X
t
,
|
μ
K
,
|
Marital status (mt+1) | e t , M t , N t | X
t
,
|
μ
M
,
|
Change in children (nt+1) | e t , M t , N t | X
t
,
|
μ
N
,
|
Health status (Ht+1) | e t , o t , k t , E t , H t | X
t
,
|
μ
H
,
|
Initial conditions | |||
Employment (e1) | X1,
|
|
|
Work experience (E1) | X1,
|
|
|
Occupation (o1) | X1,
|
|
|
Savings (s1) | X1,
|
|
|
Marital status (m1) | X1,
|
|
|
Number of children (n1) | X1,
|
|
|
Health status (H1) | X1,
|
|
Joint significance test for all market-level exogenous characteristics.
Equation | Market-level characteristics | |
---|---|---|
Employment at t | c | p-value = 0.000 |
Occupation at t | c | p-value = 0.000 |
Investment in A at t | c | p-value = 0.000 |
Investment in B at t | p-value = 0.120 | |
Investment in C at t | c | p-value = 0.000 |
Investment in D at t | a | p-value = 0.054 |
Investment in E at t | c | p-value = 0.000 |
Savings at t | c | p-value = 0.000 |
Duration of Life at t | c | p-value = 0.000 |
Elicited risk aversion at t | c | p-value = 0.000 |
-
a, b, csignificant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels.
Significance test for lagged market-level exogenous characteristics.
Behavior at t | Lagged market-level characteristics (at t − 1) | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Unemployment | Hospital | Number of | Number of | Rainfall | College | |
rate | beds | doctors | marriages | tuition | ||
Employment | b | Not sig | c | c | a | Not sig |
Occupation | c | Not sig | c | c | c | c |
Investment in A | Not sig | Not sig | b | c | c | Not sig |
Investment in B | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig | c |
Investment in C | Not sig | Not sig | b | c | c | Not sig |
Investment in D | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig |
Investment in E | Not sig | Not sig | c | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig |
Savings at t | b | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig | c |
Duration of Life | b | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig | Not sig |
Elicited risk aversion | b | b | c | b | Not sig | b |
-
a, b, csignificant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels.
C.3 Parameter Estimates
Multinomial logit on employment status (relative to working full-time).
Variable | Part-time | Not working | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Coeff. | St.Er. | Coeff. | St.Er. | |
Work experience | −0.065 | 0.021c | −0.078 | 0.011c |
Experience squared | 0.001 | 0.001 | −0.001 | 0.000c |
Lagged investment in A | −0.164 | 0.340 | −0.077 | 0.098 |
Lagged investment in B | −0.089 | 0.293 | −0.100 | 0.081 |
Lagged investment in C | −0.093 | 0.311 | −0.100 | 0.079 |
Lagged investment in D | −0.043 | 0.325 | 0.051 | 0.094 |
Lagged investment in E | 0.265 | 0.483 | −0.047 | 0.139 |
Lagged assets | −0.042 | 0.006c | −0.002 | 0.002 |
Lagged optional savings | −0.148 | 0.097 | −0.143 | 0.049c |
Lagged marital status | −0.399 | 0.138c | −0.249 | 0.069c |
Number of children | −0.052 | 0.075 | −0.078 | 0.035b |
Interaction Female-married | 0.519 | 0.174c | 0.698 | 0.092c |
Interaction Female-children | 0.140 | 0.085a | 0.233 | 0.043c |
Health: Very good | −0.007 | 0.126 | 0.003 | 0.066 |
Health: Fair | 0.083 | 0.099 | 0.328 | 0.050c |
Health: Poor | 0.455 | 0.172c | 1.005 | 0.088c |
Age | 0.126 | 0.064b | 0.162 | 0.029c |
Age squared | −0.044 | 0.033 | −0.072 | 0.015c |
Age cubic | 0.006 | 0.005 | 0.014 | 0.002c |
Female | 0.619 | 0.147c | 0.602 | 0.077c |
High school | −0.276 | 0.107c | −0.486 | 0.052c |
Technical college | −0.221 | 0.168 | −1.031 | 0.093c |
College | −0.106 | 0.849 | −1.581 | 0.347c |
Unemployment rate | −0.017 | 0.025 | 0.033 | 0.012c |
Number of hospital beds | 0.201 | 0.201 | −0.087 | 0.092 |
Number of doctors | 1.174 | 0.512b | 0.191 | 0.213 |
Number of marriages | 0.166 | 0.212 | 0.272 | 0.082c |
Inches of rainfall | 0.010 | 0.004b | 0.006 | 0.002c |
College tuition | 0.093 | 0.091 | −0.063 | 0.045 |
Missing: number of children | 0.189 | 0.871 | −0.317 | 0.194 |
Missing: education | −0.261 | 0.785 | −0.176 | 0.317 |
Time trend | 0.086 | 0.066 | 0.065 | 0.019c |
Constant | −6.321 | 0.916c | −2.654 | 0.406c |
Permanent Unob. Het. | −0.543 | 0.258b | −1.229 | 0.124c |
Permanent Unob. Het. | 0.395 | 0.154b | 0.883 | 0.091c |
Permanent Unob. Het. | −0.499 | 0.176c | −1.399 | 0.120c |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | 0.297 | 0.140b | 0.028 | 0.064 |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | 0.678 | 0.310b | 1.637 | 0.409c |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | 0.312 | 0.177a | −0.146 | 0.095 |
-
a, b, csignificant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level.
Multinomial logit on occupation category (relative to elementary occupation).
Variable | Prof and tech | Clerical support | Service and sales | Agricul and craft | Plant and machine | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Coeff. | St.Er. | Coeff. | St.Er. | Coeff. | St.Er. | Coeff. | St.Er. | Coeff. | St.Er. | |
Work experience | −0.072 | 0.029b | −0.013 | 0.031 | −0.058 | 0.024b | −0.003 | 0.029 | −0.014 | 0.029 |
Experience squared | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.000 | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001a | 0.002 | 0.001b | 0.000 | 0.001 |
Lagged investment in A | −0.108 | 0.205 | −0.078 | 0.200 | 0.000 | 0.209 | −0.134 | 0.251 | −0.161 | 0.191 |
Lagged investment in B | −0.118 | 0.157 | 0.174 | 0.155 | 0.334 | 0.156b | −0.001 | 0.204 | −0.083 | 0.150 |
Lagged investment in C | −0.401 | 0.160b | −0.016 | 0.157 | 0.063 | 0.158 | −0.347 | 0.206a | −0.245 | 0.147a |
Lagged investment in D | −0.241 | 0.220 | −0.124 | 0.218 | −0.149 | 0.215 | −0.026 | 0.232 | −0.196 | 0.196 |
Lagged investment in E | −0.568 | 0.373 | −0.310 | 0.386 | 0.348 | 0.316 | −0.404 | 0.379 | −0.237 | 0.275 |
Lagged assets | 0.051 | 0.004c | 0.054 | 0.004c | 0.041 | 0.004c | −0.004 | 0.006 | 0.028 | 0.004c |
Lagged optional savings | 0.317 | 0.085c | 0.135 | 0.089 | −0.007 | 0.089 | 0.118 | 0.104 | −0.191 | 0.085b |
Lagged marital status | 0.401 | 0.174b | 0.591 | 0.171c | 0.137 | 0.177 | 0.068 | 0.120 | 0.192 | 0.133 |
Number of children | −0.077 | 0.063 | −0.162 | 0.068b | 0.012 | 0.065 | −0.111 | 0.053b | 0.104 | 0.049b |
Interaction Female-married | 0.134 | 0.259 | −0.390 | 0.245 | 0.098 | 0.258 | 0.471 | 0.249a | −0.210 | 0.243 |
Interaction Female-children | −0.030 | 0.086 | 0.083 | 0.089 | −0.133 | 0.088 | 0.226 | 0.102b | −0.239 | 0.089c |
Health: Very good | 0.236 | 0.115b | 0.042 | 0.119 | 0.121 | 0.119 | 0.077 | 0.135 | −0.092 | 0.111 |
Health: Fair | −0.265 | 0.115b | −0.072 | 0.114 | −0.078 | 0.110 | 0.079 | 0.102 | −0.067 | 0.098 |
Health: Poor | −0.151 | 0.446 | 0.042 | 0.406 | 0.121 | 0.372 | 0.076 | 0.227 | −0.171 | 0.305 |
Age | 0.010 | 0.025 | −0.080 | 0.026c | −0.054 | 0.023b | −0.046 | 0.026a | 0.013 | 0.025 |
Age squared | 0.002 | 0.006 | 0.010 | 0.006 | 0.011 | 0.005b | 0.006 | 0.006 | −0.003 | 0.006 |
Female | −0.227 | 0.180 | 0.324 | 0.174a | 0.752 | 0.184c | −1.039 | 0.202c | −2.275 | 0.175c |
High school | 2.656 | 0.115c | 2.778 | 0.118c | 1.558 | 0.109c | −0.503 | 0.121c | 1.075 | 0.105c |
Technical college | 6.471 | 0.275c | 4.494 | 0.291c | 2.771 | 0.269c | −0.271 | 0.477 | 1.523 | 0.285c |
College | 8.027 | 0.602c | 5.560 | 0.710c | 3.578 | 0.732c | 1.209 | 1.048 | 1.302 | 0.867 |
Unemployment rate | 0.027 | 0.025 | 0.021 | 0.027 | −0.025 | 0.024 | 0.018 | 0.026 | 0.061 | 0.025b |
Number of hospital beds | −0.136 | 0.206 | −0.199 | 0.223 | −0.275 | 0.202 | −0.217 | 0.212 | −0.058 | 0.195 |
Number of doctors | 0.743 | 0.392a | 0.446 | 0.467 | 1.156 | 0.412c | −1.558 | 0.536c | 0.418 | 0.417 |
Number of marriages | 0.063 | 0.173 | 0.423 | 0.183b | 0.323 | 0.164b | −0.620 | 0.195c | 0.253 | 0.161 |
Inches of rainfall | 0.001 | 0.005 | 0.004 | 0.005 | −0.003 | 0.004 | 0.027 | 0.005c | 0.005 | 0.004 |
College tuition | 0.204 | 0.089b | 0.439 | 0.094c | 0.006 | 0.089 | −0.765 | 0.102c | 0.164 | 0.090a |
Missing: number of children | −0.084 | 0.308 | −0.235 | 0.356 | −0.586 | 0.356a | 0.081 | 0.523 | 0.181 | 0.332 |
Missing: education | 4.686 | 0.538c | 3.454 | 0.633c | 2.151 | 0.613c | −11.427 | 1.186c | 1.692 | 0.642c |
Time trend | 0.023 | 0.038 | −0.041 | 0.038 | −0.026 | 0.037 | −0.006 | 0.048 | 0.038 | 0.035 |
Constant | −2.650 | 0.696c | −5.162 | 0.770c | −2.541 | 0.696c | 4.692 | 0.814c | 0.597 | 0.660 |
Permanent Unob. Het. | −1.440 | 0.193c | 1.370 | 0.232c | −1.106 | 0.222c | −1.406 | 0.339c | −4.461 | 0.168c |
Permanent Unob. Het. | −3.777 | 0.259c | −1.824 | 0.269c | −0.729 | 0.209c | 0.755 | 0.248c | −4.240 | 0.144c |
Permanent Unob. Het. | 1.585 | 0.228c | 1.103 | 0.307c | 3.710 | 0.217c | −1.595 | 0.547c | −3.281 | 0.253c |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | 0.005 | 0.117 | −0.037 | 0.118 | −0.034 | 0.117 | −0.004 | 0.131 | −0.163 | 0.109 |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | 1.171 | 0.330c | 0.358 | 0.361 | 0.887 | 0.344c | 0.453 | 0.501 | 0.311 | 0.327 |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | 0.709 | 0.176c | 0.477 | 0.180c | 0.211 | 0.183 | −0.294 | 0.227 | −0.068 | 0.175 |
-
a, b, cSignificant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level.
Wage equation.
Variable | Wage (log) | |
---|---|---|
Coeff. | St.Er. | |
Work experience | 0.006 | 0.003a |
Experience squared | 0.000 | 0.000 |
Legislators | 0.561 | 0.022c |
Clerical | 0.339 | 0.022c |
Service and sales | 0.118 | 0.023c |
Agricultural | −0.079 | 0.023c |
Plant operators | −0.042 | 0.021b |
Health: very good | 0.060 | 0.013c |
Health: fair | −0.107 | 0.013c |
Health: poor | −0.196 | 0.026c |
Number of children | 0.003 | 0.007 |
Lagged marital status | 0.092 | 0.011c |
Age | 0.001 | 0.001 |
Female | −0.196 | 0.013c |
High school | 0.257 | 0.012c |
Technical college | 0.686 | 0.021c |
College | 0.875 | 0.040c |
Missing: occupation | 0.139 | 0.044c |
Unemployment rate | −0.003 | 0.003 |
Missing: education | 0.365 | 0.059c |
Missing: number of children | 0.000 | 0.031 |
Constant | 0.572 | 0.039c |
Permanent Unob. Het. | −0.263 | 0.028c |
Permanent Unob. Het. | −0.411 | 0.024c |
Permanent Unob. Het. | −0.314 | 0.029c |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | 0.039 | 0.014c |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | −10.294 | 0.039c |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | 0.180 | 0.019c |
-
a, b, csignificant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels.
Estimation results: marital status and variation in number of children.
Variable | Marital status | Children variation | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(relative to married) | (relative to no change) | |||||
Decrease | Increase | |||||
Coeff. | St.Er. | Coeff. | St.Er. | Coeff. | St.Er. | |
Duration of marriage | −0.025 | 0.004c | 0.066 | 0.004c | −0.098 | 0.014c |
Lagged marital status | −4.382 | 0.106c | −1.133 | 0.115c | 0.798 | 0.195c |
Number of children | −0.258 | 0.035c | 1.161 | 0.032c | 0.691 | 0.065c |
Interaction Female-married | −0.097 | 0.106 | −0.316 | 0.095c | −0.076 | 0.213 |
Interaction Female-children | 0.100 | 0.048b | 0.177 | 0.041c | −0.035 | 0.098 |
Full-time employed | −0.047 | 0.071 | 0.297 | 0.060c | 0.554 | 0.194c |
Part-time employed | −0.029 | 0.153 | 0.254 | 0.127b | 0.148 | 0.463 |
Age | 0.063 | 0.028b | 0.515 | 0.017c | −0.153 | 0.025c |
Age squared | −0.037 | 0.017b | −0.113 | 0.004c | 0.006 | 0.009 |
Age cubic | 0.006 | 0.003b | ||||
Female | 0.357 | 0.090c | 0.263 | 0.098c | 0.005 | 0.211 |
High school | 0.016 | 0.060 | −0.078 | 0.049 | 0.202 | 0.118a |
Technical college | −0.079 | 0.092 | −0.131 | 0.080a | 0.068 | 0.187 |
College | −0.452 | 0.159c | −0.075 | 0.127 | 0.037 | 0.583 |
Number of marriages | −0.317 | 0.085c | ||||
College tuition | −0.001 | 0.039 | −0.217 | 0.087c | ||
Missing: Marriage Duration | −0.082 | 0.441 | 1.595 | 0.443c | −0.026 | 0.988 |
Missing: Number of children | −0.641 | 0.158c | ||||
Missing: Education | −0.374 | 0.553 | 0.114 | 0.426 | 0.941 | 0.893 |
Constant | 3.257 | 0.388c | −8.618 | 0.261c | −2.371 | 0.463c |
Permanent Unob. Het. | 0.184 | 0.093b | −0.107 | 0.079 | −0.053 | 0.200 |
Permanent Unob. Het. | 0.016 | 0.078 | 0.041 | 0.064 | −0.112 | 0.206 |
Permanent Unob. Het. | 0.045 | 0.093 | −0.099 | 0.076 | −0.183 | 0.198 |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | 0.015 | 0.089 | −0.011 | 0.079 | −0.199 | 0.212 |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | −1.795 | 0.352c | 0.866 | 0.319c | 3.972 | 0.439c |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | −0.043 | 0.130 | 0.254 | 0.105b | −0.072 | 0.271 |
-
a, b, cSignificant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels.
Health status and medical care consumption.
Variable | Health status | Medical | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(relative to very good) | Consumption | |||||||
Good | Regular | Poor | ||||||
Coeff. | St.Er. | Coeff. | St.Er. | Coeff. | St.Er. | Coeff. | St.Er. | |
Health: Very good | −0.528 | 0.060c | −0.789 | 0.084c | −0.889 | 0.203c | −1.047 | 0.246c |
Health: Fair | 0.289 | 0.081c | 1.526 | 0.084c | 1.845 | 0.122c | 4.887 | 0.207c |
Health: Poor | 0.678 | 0.329b | 2.353 | 0.322c | 4.108 | 0.333c | 15.679 | 0.424c |
Number of medical visits | 0.010 | 0.003c | 0.022 | 0.004c | 0.027 | 0.004c | ||
Work experience | 0.003 | 0.005 | −0.004 | 0.006 | −0.005 | 0.008 | ||
Legislators | −0.296 | 0.142b | −0.442 | 0.175b | −0.288 | 0.330 | ||
Clerical | −0.025 | 0.143 | 0.007 | 0.172 | 0.282 | 0.352 | ||
Service and sales | 0.011 | 0.156 | −0.090 | 0.187 | 0.084 | 0.322 | ||
Agricultural | −0.165 | 0.178 | −0.244 | 0.204 | −0.191 | 0.342 | ||
Plant operators | 0.062 | 0.141 | −0.018 | 0.163 | 0.208 | 0.264 | ||
Age | 0.034 | 0.014b | 0.084 | 0.017c | 0.163 | 0.032c | −0.048 | 0.040 |
Age squared | −0.004 | 0.003 | −0.009 | 0.004b | −0.021 | 0.007c | 0.019 | 0.009b |
Female | 0.170 | 0.064c | 0.379 | 0.075c | 0.618 | 0.115c | 4.149 | 0.177c |
High school | −0.098 | 0.066 | −0.537 | 0.077c | −0.693 | 0.121c | 1.370 | 0.198c |
Technical college | −0.214 | 0.105b | −0.924 | 0.139c | −1.301 | 0.274c | 2.881 | 0.378c |
College | −0.489 | 0.253a | −1.445 | 0.520c | −1.873 | 0.826b | 3.974 | 0.943c |
Inches of rainfall | 0.001 | 0.002 | 0.006 | 0.002b | 0.003 | 0.004 | ||
Number of hospital beds | −0.038 | 0.299 | ||||||
Number of doctors | 0.550 | 0.671 | ||||||
Missing: Occupation | −0.096 | 0.327 | −0.341 | 0.438 | −0.405 | 0.691 | ||
Missing: Education | −0.201 | 0.492 | −0.657 | 0.712 | −0.766 | 0.922 | 2.248 | 1.000b |
Not employed | 0.123 | 0.333 | 0.254 | 0.448 | 0.713 | 0.686 | ||
Constant | 0.869 | 0.200c | −0.946 | 0.244c | −4.435 | 0.508c | 1.537 | 0.882a |
Permanent Unob. Het. | −0.079 | 0.139 | −0.130 | 0.168 | −0.220 | 0.294 | −0.302 | 0.413 |
Permanent Unob. Het. | 0.072 | 0.118 | 0.409 | 0.136c | 0.749 | 0.206c | −0.201 | 0.480 |
Permanent Unob. Het. | 0.075 | 0.137 | 0.093 | 0.169 | 0.296 | 0.288 | −0.657 | 0.434 |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | −0.068 | 0.075 | −0.055 | 0.090 | 0.009 | 0.150 | 0.215 | 0.340 |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | 1.084 | 1.442 | 1.105 | 1.442 | 1.624 | 1.670 | −1.633 | 0.699b |
Time-varying Unob. Het. | −0.095 | 0.103 | −0.273 | 0.126b | −0.325 | 0.210 | 0.947 | 0.598 |
-
a, b, cSignificant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level.
Pearson’s correlation coefficient for unobserved heterogeneity between subjective assessments and outcomes.
Outcome | Risk aversion | Expected | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Intermediate | Least | Duration of life | ||||
Perm. | Time-var. | Perm. | Time-var. | Perm. | Time-var. | |
Employment (relative to full-time worker) | ||||||
Part-time worker | −0.021 | 0.681 | −0.558 | −0.014 | −0.689 | 0.765 |
Not working | −0.092 | −0.236 | −0.597 | 0.027 | −0.643 | 0.867 |
Occupation (relative to elementary occupation) | ||||||
Legis., prof., tech., other | 0.626 | 0.435 | 0.967 | 0.794 | 0.022 | 0.815 |
Clerical support workers | 0.058 | 0.527 | 0.623 | 0.948 | 0.626 | 0.543 |
Service and sales workers | 0.842 | 0.081 | 0.829 | 0.587 | −0.244 | 0.903 |
Agricultural, craft and trade | −0.069 | −0.638 | −0.558 | −0.505 | −0.664 | 0.425 |
Operators and assemblers | 0.506 | −0.589 | 0.612 | 0.479 | −0.474 | 0.339 |
Investment decision | ||||||
Account A (riskier) | 0.114 | 0.917 | 0.682 | 0.680 | 0.526 | 0.407 |
Account B | −0.389 | 0.610 | 0.225 | −0.465 | 0.728 | 0.321 |
Account C | 0.343 | −0.984 | −0.210 | −0.465 | −0.909 | −0.399 |
Account D | 0.269 | −0.067 | −0.285 | −0.912 | −0.492 | 0.069 |
Account E (safest) | −0.238 | 0.838 | −0.749 | −0.169 | −0.279 | 0.351 |
Saving outcomes | ||||||
Optional savings | 0.222 | 0.884 | 0.726 | 0.432 | 0.255 | −0.151 |
Elicited Risk Aversion (relative to most risk averse) | ||||||
Intermediate risk-averse | 1.000 | 1.000 | 0.804 | 0.342 | −0.699 | 0.268 |
Least risk-averse | 0.804 | 0.342 | 1.000 | 1.000 | −0.213 | 0.300 |
Marital status | ||||||
Married | −0.675 | 0.134 | −0.209 | −0.254 | 0.997 | −0.915 |
Variation in number of children (relative to no change) | ||||||
Decrease | 0.038 | 0.177 | −0.467 | 0.609 | −0.740 | 0.920 |
Increase | −0.263 | −0.240 | 0.012 | 0.268 | 0.041 | 0.859 |
Health status (relative to very good) | ||||||
Good | 0.587 | −0.336 | 0.013 | 0.188 | −0.762 | 0.812 |
Regular | 0.071 | −0.478 | −0.529 | −0.064 | −0.564 | 0.713 |
Poor | 0.139 | −0.369 | −0.459 | −0.111 | −0.561 | 0.776 |
Expected duration of life | −0.699 | 0.268 | −0.213 | 0.300 | 1.000 | 1.000 |
Log wage | 0.270 | 0.179 | 0.573 | −0.181 | −0.146 | −0.899 |
Medical consumption | −0.236 | 0.729 | −0.277 | 0.278 | −0.314 | −0.440 |
-
(a) Permanent unobserved heterogeneity also enters the initial condition equations.
Appendix D: Simulation Results
[Preferred model] share of individuals that stay in the default at the end of each period (%) – all individuals are treated.
Period | Baseline | Default + 1 | Riskier default | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Total | Women | Men | Total | Women | Men | Total | Women | Men | |
All individuals are treated | |||||||||
t = 3 | 72.99c | 72.02c | 73.84c | 37.33c | 37.24c | 37.42c | 35.15c | 32.83b | 37.18c |
(6.02) | (6.00) | (6.07) | (8.96) | (8.67) | (9.28) | (13.24) | (13.12) | (13.45) | |
t = 4 | 66.72c | 65.24c | 68.01c | 27.64c | 28.21c | 27.15c | 24.90b | 22.55a | 26.95b |
(5.87) | (5.75) | (6.06) | (9.38) | (8.80) | (9.98) | (12.18) | (11.90) | (12.55) | |
t = 5 | 63.86c | 61.90c | 65.59c | 23.86c | 24.79c | 23.05b | 21.55b | 19.38a | 23.44b |
(5.66) | (5.42) | (6.02) | (8.92) | (8.27) | (9.59) | (10.68) | (10.36) | (11.07) | |
t = 6 | 63.15c | 60.89c | 65.13c | 21.67b | 23.17b | 20.36b | 20.53b | 18.54b | 22.28b |
(5.63) | (5.31) | (6.14) | (8.50) | (7.77) | (9.24) | (9.43) | (9.10) | (9.81) | |
t = 7 | 63.09c | 60.57c | 65.31c | 19.31b | 21.11b | 17.73b | 20.37b | 18.61b | 21.92b |
(5.63) | (5.30) | (6.26) | (8.05) | (7.40) | (8.73) | (8.30) | (7.96) | (8.68) | |
t = 8 | 64.86c | 62.03c | 67.34c | 18.00b | 20.27b | 16.01b | 20.42c | 18.57c | 22.04c |
(5.68) | (5.47) | (6.25) | (7.44) | (6.86) | (8.06) | (7.04) | (6.69) | (7.43) |
-
(a) Individuals start period t = 1 with their observed initial conditions. Individuals observed to be in the default in period t = 2 are treated. After the treatment, the simulated outcomes are used to update the next period’s endogenous explanatory variables. (b) Baseline simulation corresponds to the evolution of the model without policy intervention. (c) Bootstrapped standard errors are in parentheses using 100 draws.
[Preferred model] crowding-out effect of increasing contribution rates of 5 and 10 percent (% change).
Period | Investment | Savings | Employment | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
A | B | C | D | E | Full-time | Part-time | Not Emp | ||
Contribution rate = 15% | |||||||||
t = 3 | 0.18c | 0.11c | 0.01 | −0.06c | 0.10 | 0.10c | 0.03 | −0.89c | 0.00 |
(0.05) | (0.04) | (0.01) | (0.02) | (0.07) | (0.04) | (0.12) | (0.25) | (0.09) | |
t = 4 | 0.38c | 0.28c | 0.01 | −0.14c | 0.32b | 0.23c | 0.06 | −1.58c | 0.00 |
(0.11) | (0.10) | (0.02) | (0.04) | (0.14) | (0.08) | (0.27) | (0.57) | (0.20) | |
t = 5 | 0.60c | 0.56c | 0.01 | −0.22c | 0.50b | 0.38c | 0.10 | −2.46c | 0.01 |
(0.18) | (0.17) | (0.03) | (0.06) | (0.21) | (0.13) | (0.43) | (0.82) | (0.33) | |
t = 6 | 0.82c | 0.80c | 0.00 | −0.27c | 0.74b | 0.54c | 0.15 | −3.38c | 0.00 |
(0.26) | (0.27) | (0.05) | (0.07) | (0.31) | (0.18) | (0.62) | (1.03) | (0.46) | |
t = 7 | 1.08c | 1.27c | 0.02 | −0.32c | 0.99b | 0.73c | 0.20 | −4.28c | 0.01 |
(0.35) | (0.40) | (0.06) | (0.09) | (0.41) | (0.24) | (0.84) | (1.37) | (0.61) | |
t = 8 | 1.25c | 1.78c | 0.02 | −0.38c | 1.37b | 0.93c | 0.24 | −5.29c | 0.01 |
(0.44) | (0.53) | (0.07) | (0.10) | (0.52) | (0.30) | (1.04) | (1.76) | (0.76) | |
Contribution rate = 20% | |||||||||
t = 3 | 0.35c | 0.23c | 0.02 | −0.13c | 0.21 | 0.20c | 0.07 | −1.72c | 0.00 |
(0.09) | (0.08) | (0.02) | (0.04) | (0.13) | (0.07) | (0.25) | (0.46) | (0.19) | |
t = 4 | 0.78c | 0.57c | 0.02 | −0.27c | 0.68b | 0.49c | 0.12 | −3.10c | 0.00 |
(0.22) | (0.19) | (0.04) | (0.07) | (0.27) | (0.16) | (0.53) | (1.01) | (0.40) | |
t = 5 | 1.20c | 1.08c | 0.01 | −0.41c | 0.96b | 0.75c | 0.20 | −4.89c | 0.02 |
(0.37) | (0.34) | (0.07) | (0.11) | (0.44) | (0.26) | (0.86) | (1.46) | (0.65) | |
t = 6 | 1.66c | 1.69c | 0.02 | −0.52c | 1.36b | 1.09 | 0.30 | −6.49 | −0.01 |
(0.53) | (0.55) | (0.09) | (0.14) | (0.65) | (0.36) | (1.25) | (1.97) | (0.92) | |
t = 7 | 2.19c | 2.56c | 0.04 | −0.66c | 1.96b | 1.46c | 0.41 | −8.39c | 0.01 |
(0.72) | (0.80) | (0.12) | (0.17) | (0.83) | (0.48) | (1.68) | (2.48) | (1.22) | |
t = 8 | 2.50c | 3.58c | 0.04 | −0.81c | 2.65b | 1.85c | 0.47 | −10.27c | 0.01 |
(0.91) | (1.09) | (0.15) | (0.19) | (1.06) | (0.62) | (2.07) | (3.20) | (1.54) |
-
(a) Percentage change in accumulated assets with respect to the baseline simulation (α = 0.1) (b) Individuals start period t = 1 with their observed initial conditions. All individuals are treated in period t = 2. (c) Bootstrapped standard errors are in parentheses using 100 draws. a, b, cSignificant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels.
[Alternative specifications] percentage change in accumulated assets at the end of seven years for different mandatory contribution rates under alternative specifications of the model.
Alternative a) | Alternative b) | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
No subjective assessments – no CUH | Exogenous subjective assessments – CUH | |||||||
α = 11% | α = 13% | α = 15% | α = 20% | α = 11% | α = 13% | α = 15% | α = 20% | |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | |
Mean | 4.54 | 13.63 | 22.76 | 45.77 | 4.32a | 13.00a | 21.71a | 43.64a |
(2.87) | (8.66) | (14.52) | (29.36) | (2.34) | (7.09) | (11.94) | (24.49) | |
Percentile | ||||||||
1% | 6.17b | 18.07b | 29.50b | 54.38b | 5.06a | 15.32a | 25.43a | 46.02 |
(2.46) | (7.56) | (12.78) | (26.31) | (2.95) | (8.97) | (15.09) | (30.57) | |
5% | 7.23c | 20.73c | 33.43c | 63.93c | 6.45c | 19.06c | 31.07b | 58.56b |
(1.78) | (5.49) | (9.35) | (19.79) | (2.37) | (7.23) | (12.18) | (24.93) | |
10% | 7.48c | 21.93c | 35.98c | 69.68c | 7.06c | 20.65c | 33.70c | 64.96c |
(1.46) | (4.56) | (7.89) | (16.91) | (2.07) | (6.27) | (10.64) | (21.99) | |
25% | 7.04c | 20.95c | 34.41c | 67.20c | 6.97c | 20.43c | 33.47c | 64.86c |
(1.50) | (4.65) | (8.01) | (17.24) | (1.63) | (4.93) | (8.29) | (16.97) | |
50% | 5.83b | 17.28b | 28.45b | 55.77b | 5.67c | 16.69c | 27.58c | 53.83c |
(2.36) | (7.15) | (12.05) | (24.69) | (1.63) | (4.91) | (8.20) | (16.52) | |
75% | 4.71a | 14.18a | 23.56a | 46.72a | 4.62b | 13.75b | 22.83b | 45.25b |
(2.77) | (8.33) | (13.97) | (28.32) | (1.98) | (5.97) | (10.02) | (20.41) | |
90% | 3.99 | 12.23 | 20.55 | 41.58 | 3.83 | 11.74 | 19.69 | 39.81 |
(3.03) | (9.15) | (15.33) | (30.94) | (2.47) | (7.48) | (12.66) | (26.22) | |
95% | 3.58 | 10.71 | 18.11 | 37.65 | 3.32 | 10.22 | 17.34 | 36.10 |
(3.16) | (9.54) | (15.99) | (32.31) | (2.73) | (8.36) | (14.16) | (29.45) | |
99% | 3.29 | 9.80 | 16.67 | 35.89 | 2.77 | 8.70 | 14.90 | 32.71 |
(3.39) | (10.27) | (17.24) | (34.85) | (3.13) | (9.55) | (16.10) | (33.08) |
-
(a) Alternative a) without subjective assessments or correlated unobserved heterogeneity. Alternative b) Model with subjective assessments as exogenous explanatory variables and no correlated unobserved heterogeneity. (b) Percentage change in accumulated assets with respect to the baseline simulation (α = 10%). (c) Bootstrapped standard errors are in parentheses using 100 draws. a, b, cSignificant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels.
[Alternative specifications] percentage change in accumulated assets at the end of seven years for alternative default schemes under alternative specifications of the model.
Investment paths | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Alternative a) | Alternative b) | |||||||||
No subjective assessments – no CUH | Exogenous subjective assessments – CUH | |||||||||
Predicted | Riskier | Riskier | All C | All E | Predicted | Riskier | Riskier | All C | All E | |
by model | default | gender-equated | by model | default | gender-equated | |||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | |
Mean | −2.05 | 7.92c | 8.60c | 0.82 | −12.71c | −2.10 | 8.04b | 8.72c | 0.85 | −12.81a |
(7.17) | (2.25) | (2.27) | (0.81) | (3.21) | (7.19) | (3.17) | (3.10) | (1.31) | (7.40) | |
Percentile | ||||||||||
1% | −0.90 | 13.66 | 16.60 | 4.54 | −8.87 | −2.46 | 11.89 | 13.73 | 4.28 | −9.61 |
(12.05) | (13.09) | (13.58) | (10.16) | (23.25) | (18.09) | (17.65) | (16.02) | (14.25) | (38.60) | |
5% | −2.74 | 10.32 | 12.32 | 1.99 | −12.29 | −2.77 | 11.07 | 13.62 | 2.18 | −12.08 |
(8.68) | (8.25) | (9.11) | (5.39) | (12.71) | (12.67) | (12.55) | (12.14) | (7.89) | (25.09) | |
10% | −2.97 | 8.94 | 10.93 | 1.13 | −12.45 | −2.93 | 9.37 | 11.27 | 1.35 | −12.42 |
(7.36) | (6.59) | (7.20) | (4.02) | (9.33) | (10.28) | (9.74) | (9.47) | (5.61) | (19.49) | |
25% | −3.20 | 7.70a | 9.20a | −0.08 | −12.79b | −3.29 | 7.95 | 9.53 | −0.14 | −12.91 |
(6.80) | (4.52) | (4.72) | (2.45) | (6.22) | (8.08) | (6.30) | (6.37) | (3.62) | (13.92) | |
50% | −3.23 | 7.85b | 9.27c | −0.57 | −13.37c | −3.32 | 7.99a | 9.50b | −0.57 | −13.46 |
(7.13) | (3.15) | (3.20) | (1.47) | (4.48) | (7.40) | (4.39) | (4.75) | (2.29) | (10.63) | |
75% | −2.84 | 7.97c | 9.24c | 0.04 | −13.19c | −2.83 | 8.09b | 9.36b | 0.10 | −13.25 |
(7.11) | (2.57) | (2.81) | (0.89) | (3.57) | (7.36) | (3.54) | (3.75) | (1.44) | (8.69) | |
90% | −2.21 | 7.89c | 8.49c | 1.17 | −12.60c | −2.39 | 7.97b | 8.69c | 1.11 | −12.80a |
(7.14) | (2.16) | (2.30) | (0.72) | (3.02) | (7.42) | (3.11) | (3.03) | (1.06) | (7.41) | |
95% | −2.25 | 7.77c | 7.68c | 1.83b | −12.29c | −2.10 | 7.89c | 7.88c | 1.93b | −12.37a |
(7.48) | (2.02) | (2.07) | (0.88) | (2.80) | (7.51) | (2.91) | (2.72) | (0.98) | (6.54) | |
99% | −0.11 | 7.65c | 7.23c | 2.83b | −11.62c | −0.20 | 8.04c | 7.18c | 3.03b | −11.70b |
(7.89 | (2.09) | (1.86) | (1.25) | (2.71) | (7.44) | (2.56) | (2.30) | (1.24) | (5.13) |
-
(a) Alternative a) without subjective assessments nor correlated unobserved heterogeneity. Alternative b) model with subjective assessments as exogenous explanatory variables and no correlated unobserved heterogeneity. (b) Percentage change in accumulated assets with respect to default investment path. (c) Bootstrapped standard errors are in parentheses using 100 draws. a, b, cSignificant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels.
References
Albert, S. M., and J. Duffy. 2012. “Differences in Risk Aversion between Young and Older Adults.” Neuroscience and Neuroeconomics 2012 (1). https://doi.org/10.2147/NAN.S27184.Search in Google Scholar
Arano, K., C. Parker, and R. Terry. 2010. “Gender-based Risk Aversion and Retirement Asset allocation.” Economic Inquiry 48 (1): 147–55. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7295.2008.00201.x.Search in Google Scholar
Arellano, M., and S. Bond. 1991. “Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations.” The Review of Economic Studies 58 (2): 277–97. https://doi.org/10.2307/2297968.Search in Google Scholar
Attanasio, O. P., and A. Brugiavini. 2003. “Social Security and Households’ Saving,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (3): 1075–119. https://doi.org/10.1162/00335530360698504.Search in Google Scholar
Attanasio, O. P., and S. Rohwedder. 2003. “Pension Wealth and Household Saving: Evidence from Pension Reforms in the United Kingdom.” The American Economic Review 93 (5): 1499–521. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282803322655419.Search in Google Scholar
Barsky, R. B., F. T. Juster, M. S. Kimball, and M. D. Shapiro. 1997. “Preference Parameters and Behavioral Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement Study.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (2): 537–79. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355397555280.Search in Google Scholar
Behrman, J., M. C. Calderon, O.S. Mitchell, J. Vasquez, and D. Bravo. 2011. “First-Round Impacts of the 2008 Chilean Pension System Reform.” In Michigan Retirement Research Center Research Paper No. WP, 245.10.2139/ssrn.1960582Search in Google Scholar
Bernartzi, S., and R. Thaler. 2004. “Save More Tomorrow: Using Behavioral Economics to Increase Employee Savings.” Journal of Political Economy 112 (1): 164–87.10.1086/380085Search in Google Scholar
Benartzi, S., and R. H. Thaler. 2013. “Behavioral Economics and the Retirement Savings Crisis.” Science 339 (6124): 1152–3. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1231320.Search in Google Scholar
Bernasek, A., and S. Shwiff. 2001. “Gender, Risk, and Retirement.” Journal of Economic Issues: 345–56. https://doi.org/10.1080/00213624.2001.11506368.Search in Google Scholar
Berstein, S., ed. 2010 The Chilean Pension System: Superintendence of Pensions. Chile.Search in Google Scholar
Berstein, S., O. Fuentes, and F. Villatoro. 2013. “Default Investment Strategies in a Defined Contribution Pension System: a Pension Risk Model Application for the Chilean Case.” Journal of Pension Economics and Finance 12 (4): 379–414. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1474747213000073.Search in Google Scholar
Beshears, J., J. J. Choi, D. Laibson, and B. C. Madrian. 2012. “Default Stickiness among Long-Income Individuals.” In RAND Working Paper WR-926-SSA.Search in Google Scholar
Bhargava, A. 1991. “Identification and Panel Data Models with Endogenous Regressors.” The Review of Economic Studies 58 (1): 129–40. https://doi.org/10.2307/2298050.Search in Google Scholar
Blau, D. M. 2016. “Pensions, Household Saving, and Welfare: A Dynamic Analysis of Crowd Out.” Quantitative Economics 7 (1): 193–224. https://doi.org/10.3982/qe349.Search in Google Scholar
Bommier, A. 2013. “Life-cycle Preferences Revisited.” Journal of the European Economic Association 11 (6): 1290–319. https://doi.org/10.1111/jeea.12056.Search in Google Scholar
Bommier, A., and J.-C. Rochet. 2006. “Risk Aversion and Planning Horizons.” Journal of the European Economic Association 4 (4): 708–34. https://doi.org/10.1162/jeea.2006.4.4.708.Search in Google Scholar
Bonin, H., T. Dohmen, A. Falk, D. Huffman, and U. Sunde. 2007. “Cross-sectional Earnings Risk and Occupational Sorting: The Role of Risk Attitudes.” Labour Economics 14 (6): 926–37. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.labeco.2007.06.007.Search in Google Scholar
Brunnermeier, M. K., and S. Nagel. 2008. “Do Wealth Fluctuations Generate Time-Varying Risk Aversion? Micro-evidence on Individuals’ Asset allocation (Digest Summary).” The American Economic Review 98 (3): 713–36. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.98.3.713.Search in Google Scholar
Byrne, A., D. Blake, A. Cairns, and K. Dowd. 2007. “Default Funds in UK Defined-Contribution Plans (Corrected).” Financial Analysts Journal 63 (4): 40–51. https://doi.org/10.2469/faj.v63.n4.4748.Search in Google Scholar
Card, D., and M. Ransom. 2011. “Pension Plan Characteristics and Framing Effects in Employee Savings Behavior.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 93 (1): 228–43. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00051.Search in Google Scholar
Carroll, G. D., J. J. Choi, D. Laibson, B. C. Madrian, and A. Metrick. 2009. “Optimal Defaults and Active Decisions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (4): 1639–74. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2009.124.4.1639.Search in Google Scholar
Chetty, R., J. N. Friedman, S. Leth-Petersen, T. Heien Nielsen, and T. Olsen. 2014. “Active vs. Passive Decisions and Crowd-Out in Retirement Savings Accounts: Evidence from Denmark.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (3): 1141–219. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qju013.Search in Google Scholar
Chiappori, P.-A., and M. Paiella. 2011. “Relative Risk Aversion Is Constant: Evidence from Panel Data.” Journal of the European Economic Association 9 (6): 1021–52. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1542-4774.2011.01046.x.Search in Google Scholar
Choi, J. J., D. Laibson, B. C. Madrian, and A. Metrick. 2002. “Defined Contribution Pensions: Plan Rules, Participant Choices, and the Path of Least Resistance.” Tax Policy and the Economy 16: 67–113. https://doi.org/10.1086/654750.Search in Google Scholar
Choi, J. J., D. Laibson, B. C. Madrian, and A. Metrick. 2004. “For Better or for Worse: Default Effects and 401 (K) Savings Behavior.” In Perspectives on the Economics of Aging, 81–126. Chicago, IL, USA: University of Chicago Press.10.3386/w8651Search in Google Scholar
Choi, J. J., J. Beshears, D. Laibson, and B. C. Madrian. 2012. “Default Stickiness Among Low-Income Individuals.” In Technical Report RAND Working Paper WR-926-SSA. Rand Corporation.Search in Google Scholar
Da, Z., B. Larrain, C. Sialm, and J. Tessada. 2018. “Destabilizing Financial Advice: Evidence from Pension Fund Reallocations.” Review of Financial Studies 31 (10): 3720–55. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhy011.Search in Google Scholar
Decker, S., and H. Schmitz. 2016. “Health Shocks and Risk Aversion.” Journal of Health Economics 50: 156–70. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2016.09.006.Search in Google Scholar
DeLeire, T., and H. G. Levy. 2001. “Gender, Occupation Choice and the Risk of Death at Work,” In NBER Working Paper Series No. W8574 (November). Cambridge, MA, USA.10.3386/w8574Search in Google Scholar
Dohmen, T., A. Falk, D. Huffman, U. Sunde, J. Schupp, and G. G. Wagner. 2005. “Individual Risk Attitudes: New Evidence from a Large, Representative, Experimentally Validated Survey.” In IZA Discussion Paper No. 1730.10.2139/ssrn.807408Search in Google Scholar
Dohmen, T., A. Falk, D. Huffman, U. Sunde, J. Schupp, and G. G. Wagner. 2011. “Individual Risk Attitudes: Measurement, Determinants, and Behavioral Consequences.” Journal of the European Economic Association 9 (3): 522–50. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1542-4774.2011.01015.x.Search in Google Scholar
Dohmen, T., H. Lehmann, and N. Pignatti. 2016. “Time-varying Individual Risk Attitudes over the Great Recession: A Comparison of Germany and Ukraine.” Journal of Comparative Economics 44 (1): 182–200. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2015.10.002.Search in Google Scholar
Dolls, M., P. Doerrenberg, A. Peichl, and H. Stichnoth. 2018. “Do retirement Savings Increase in Response to Information about Retirement and Expected Pensions?” Journal of Public Economics 158: 168–79. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2017.12.014.Search in Google Scholar
Duque, D., D. P. Morton, and B. K. Pagnoncelli. 2021. “How Good Are Default Investment Policies in Defined Contribution Pension Plans?” Journal of Pension Economics and Finance 20 (2): 252–72. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1474747220000153.Search in Google Scholar
Eisenhauer, J. G., and L. Ventura. 2003. “Survey Measures of Risk Aversion and Prudence.” Applied Economics 35 (13): 1477–84. https://doi.org/10.1080/0003684032000151287.Search in Google Scholar
Engelhardt, G. V., and A. Kumar. 2007. “Employer Matching and 401 (K) Saving: Evidence from the Health and Retirement Study.” Journal of Public Economics 91 (10): 1920–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.02.009.Search in Google Scholar
Flanders, S., M. Nungsari, and M. Parada-Contzen. 2020. “Pricing Schemes and Market Efficiency in Private Retirement Systems.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 22 (4): 1041–68. https://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12419.Search in Google Scholar
Fout, B. T., and D. B. Gilleskie. 2015. “Does Health Insurance Encourage or Crowd Out Beneficial Nonmedical Care? a Dynamic Analysis of Insurance, Health Inputs, and Health Production.” American Journal of Health Economics 1 (2): 125–64.10.1162/AJHE_a_00010Search in Google Scholar
Gardner, L., and D. B. Gilleskie. 2012. “The Effects of State Medicaid Policies on the Dynamic Savings Patterns and Medicaid Enrollment of the Elderly.” Journal of Human Resources 47 (4): 1082–127. https://doi.org/10.1353/jhr.2012.0030.Search in Google Scholar
Gelber, A. M. 2011. “How Do 401 (K) S Affect Saving? Evidence from Changes in 401 (K) Eligibility.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 3 (4): 103–22. https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.3.4.103.Search in Google Scholar
Gilleskie, D. B. 2021. “In Sickness and in Health, until Death Do Us Part: A Case for Theory.” Southern Economic Journal 87 (3): 753–68. https://doi.org/10.1002/soej.12474.Search in Google Scholar
Gilleskie, D., and D. Hoffman. 2014. “The Impact of Human and Health Capital on Wages: An Examination of Occupation, Employer, and Disability Transitions.” Journal of Human Capital 8 (3): 235–379. https://doi.org/10.1086/677855.Search in Google Scholar
Gilleskie, D. B., E. Han, and E. C. Norton. 2017. “Disentangling the Contemporaneous and Dynamic Effects of Human and Health Capital on Wages over the Life Cycle.” Review of Economic Dynamics 25: 350–83. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.red.2017.02.012.Search in Google Scholar
Goldin, J., T. Homonoff, R. Patterson, and W. Skimmyhorn. 2020. “How Much to Save? Decision Costs and Retirement Plan Participation.” Journal of Public Economics 191: 104247. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2020.104247.Search in Google Scholar
Goodman, L. 2020. “Catching up or Crowding Out? the Crowd-Out Effects of Catch-Up Retirement Contributions on Non-retirement Saving.” Journal of Public Economics 188: 104221. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2020.104221.Search in Google Scholar
Grable, J. E. 2000. “Financial Risk Tolerance and Additional Factors that Affect Risk Taking in Everyday Money Matters.” Journal of Business and Psychology 14 (4): 625–30. https://doi.org/10.1023/a:1022994314982.10.1023/A:1022994314982Search in Google Scholar
Grazier, S., and P. J. Sloane. 2008. “Accident Risk, Gender, Family Status and Occupational Choice in the UK.” Labour Economics 15 (5): 938–57. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.labeco.2007.07.007.Search in Google Scholar
Grossman, M. 1972. “Front Matter, the Demand for Health: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation.” In The Demand for Health: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation: NBER, 20.Search in Google Scholar
Guilkey, D. K., and P. M. Lance. 2014. “Program Impact Estimation with Binary Outcome Variables: Monte Carlo Results for Alternative Estimators and Empirical Examples.” In Festschrift in Honor of Peter, 5–46. Schmidt: Springer.10.1007/978-1-4899-8008-3_2Search in Google Scholar
Guiso, L., S. Paola, and L. Zingales. 2013. “Time Varying Risk Aversion.” In Technical Report. National Bureau of Economic Research.10.3386/w19284Search in Google Scholar
Gustman, A. L., and T. L. Steinmeier. 2015. “Effects of Social Security Policies on Benefit Claiming, Retirement and Saving.” Journal of Public Economics 129: 51–62. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2015.07.005.Search in Google Scholar
Halek, M., and J. G. Eisenhauer. 2001. “Demography of Risk Aversion.” Journal of Risk & Insurance: 1–24. https://doi.org/10.2307/2678130.Search in Google Scholar
Harrison, G. W., M. I. Lau, and E. E. Rutström. 2007. “Estimating Risk Attitudes in denmark: A Field Experiment*.” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 109 (2): 341–68. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9442.2007.00496.x.Search in Google Scholar
Hastings, J. S., A. Hortaçsu, and C. Syverson. 2013. “Advertising and Competition in Privatized Social Security: The Case of Mexico.” In NBER Working Paper Series, p. 18881.Search in Google Scholar
Heckman, J., and B. Singer. 1984. “A Method for Minimizing the Impact of Distributional Assumptions in Econometric Models for Duration Data.” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society: 271–320. https://doi.org/10.2307/1911491.Search in Google Scholar
Illanes, G. 2016. “Switching Costs in Pension Plan Choice.” In Working Paper.Search in Google Scholar
Joubert, C. 2015. “Pension Design with a Large Informal Labor Market: Evidence from Chile.” International Economic Review 56 (2): 673–94. https://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12118.Search in Google Scholar
Krasnokutskaya, E., Y. Li, and P. E. Todd. 2018. “Product Choice under Government Regulation: The Case of Chile’s Privatized Pension System.” International Economic Review 59 (4): 1747–83. https://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12319.Search in Google Scholar
Kristjanpoller, W. D., and J. E. Olson. 2015a. “Choice of Retirement Funds in Chile: Are Chilean Women More Risk Averse Than Men?” Sex Roles 72 (1–2): 50–67. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11199-014-0439-8.Search in Google Scholar
Kristjanpoller, W. D., and J. E. Olson. 2015b. “The Effect of Financial Knowledge and Demographic Variables on Passive and Active Investment in Chile’s Pension Plan.” Journal of Pension Economics and Finance 14 (3): 293–314. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1474747214000213.Search in Google Scholar
Le, A. T., P. W. Miller, W. S. Slutske, and N. G. Martin. 2011. “Attitudes towards Economic Risk and the Gender Pay Gap.” Labour Economics 18 (4): 555–61. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.labeco.2010.12.007.Search in Google Scholar
Li, C., and D. B. Gilleskie. 2021. “The Influence of Endogenous Behaviors Among Social Pairs: Social Interaction Effects of Smoking.” Journal of Health Economics 80: 102547. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2021.102547.Search in Google Scholar
Light, A., and T. Ahn. 2010. “Divorce as Risky Behavior.” Demography 47 (4): 895–921. https://doi.org/10.1007/bf03213732.Search in Google Scholar
Lindeboom, M., and R. Montizaan. 2020. “Disentangling Retirement and Savings Responses.” Journal of Public Economics 192: 104297. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2020.104297.Search in Google Scholar
López, F., and E. Walker. 2021. “Investment Performance, Regulation and Incentives: The Case of Chilean Pension Funds.” Journal of Pension Economics and Finance 20 (1): 125–50. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1474747219000350.Search in Google Scholar
Luco, F. 2019. “Switching Costs and Competition in Retirement Investment.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 11 (2): 26–54. https://doi.org/10.1257/mic.20160332.Search in Google Scholar
Madeira, C. 2021. “The Long Term Impact of Chilean Policy Reforms on Savings and Pensions.” The Journal of the Economics of Ageing 19: 100326. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeoa.2021.100326.Search in Google Scholar
Madrian, B. C., and D. F. Shea. 2001. “The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401 (K) Participation and Savings Behavior.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (4): 1149–87. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355301753265543.Search in Google Scholar
Malmendier, U., and S. Nagel. 2011. “Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk Taking?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (1): 373–416. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjq004.Search in Google Scholar
McKiernan, K. 2021. “Social Security Reform in the Presence of Informality.” Review of Economic Dynamics 40: 228–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.red.2020.10.001.Search in Google Scholar
Mitchell, O. S., P. Todd, and D. Bravo. 2008. “Learning from the Chilean Experience: The Determinants of Pension Switching.” In Overcoming the Saving Slump: Making Financial Education and Saving Programs More Effective, edited by A. Lusardi, 301–23. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.10.7208/chicago/9780226497105.003.0012Search in Google Scholar
Morales, L. F., P. Gordon-Larsen, and D. Guilkey. 2016. “Obesity and Health-Related Decisions: An Empirical Model of the Determinants of Weight Status across the Transition from Adolescence to Young Adulthood.” Economics and Human Biology 23: 46–62. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ehb.2016.06.003.Search in Google Scholar
Mroz, T. A. 1999. “Discrete Factor Approximations in Simultaneous Equation Models: Estimating the Impact of a Dummy Endogenous Variable on a Continuous Outcome.” Journal of Econometrics 92 (2): 233–74. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0304-4076(98)00091-8.Search in Google Scholar
Mroz, T. A., and D. K. Guilkey. 1992. Discrete Factor Approximation for Use in Simultaneous Equation Models with Both Continuous and Discrete Endogenous Variables. Chapel Hill: Carolina Population Center, University of North Carolina.Search in Google Scholar
Necker, S., and M. Ziegelmeyer. 2016. “Household Risk Taking after the Financial Crisis.” The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 59: 141–60. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2015.03.006.Search in Google Scholar
Neelakantan, U. 2010. “Estimation and Impact of Gender Differences in Risk Tolerance.” Economic Inquiry 48 (1): 228–33. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7295.2009.00251.x.Search in Google Scholar
Parada-Contzen, M. 2020. “Crowding-out in Savings Decisions, Portfolio Default Adoption and Home Ownership: Evidence from the Chilean Retirement System.” Review of Economics of the Household 18 (2): 543–69. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-020-09479-x.Search in Google Scholar
Parada-Contzen, M. 2022. “Gender, Family Status, and Health Characteristics: Understanding Retirement Inequalities in the Chilean Pension Model.” International Labour Review, https://doi.org/10.1111/ilr.12365.Search in Google Scholar
Pollmann, D., T. Dohmen, and F. Palm. 2020. “Robust Estimation of Wage Dispersion with Censored Data: An Application to Occupational Earnings Risk and Risk Attitudes.” De Economist 168 (4): 519–40.10.1007/s10645-020-09374-xSearch in Google Scholar
Sahm, C. R. 2012. “How Much Does Risk Tolerance Change?” Quarterly Journal of Forestry 2 (04). https://doi.org/10.1142/S2010139212500206.Search in Google Scholar
Schmidt, L. 2008. “Risk Preferences and the Timing of Marriage and Childbearing.” Demography 45 (2): 439–60. https://doi.org/10.1353/dem.0.0005.Search in Google Scholar
Sethi-Iyengar, S., G. Huberman, and W. Jiang. 2004. “How Much Choice Is Too Much? Contributions to 401 (K) Retirement Plans.” Pension Design and Atructure: New Lessons from Behavioral Finance 83: 84–7.10.1093/0199273391.003.0005Search in Google Scholar
Spivey, C. 2010. “Desperation or Desire? the Role of Risk Aversion in Marriage.” Economic Inquiry 48 (2): 499–516. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7295.2008.00181.x.Search in Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. 2016. “Behavioral Economics: Past, Present and Future.” In Present and Future. (May 27, 2016).10.2139/ssrn.2790606Search in Google Scholar
Yang, Z., D. B. Gilleskie, and E. C. Norton. 2009. “Health Insurance, Medical Care, and Health Outcomes a Model of Elderly Health Dynamics.” Journal of Human Resources 44 (1): 47–114. https://doi.org/10.1353/jhr.2009.0022.Search in Google Scholar
© 2022 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston