Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter June 1, 2023

On the Social Desirability of Centralized Wage Setting when Firms are Run by Biased Managers

  • Nicola Meccheri EMAIL logo

Abstract

This paper compares the welfare outcomes obtained under alternative unionization regimes (decentralized vs. centralized wage setting) in a duopoly market in which shareholders delegate strategic decisions to biased (overconfident or underconfident) managers. In such a framework, the common tenet that consumer surplus and overall welfare are always higher under decentralized wage setting is completely overturned. Indeed, in the presence of centralized unionization (industry-wide union), firm shareholders always prefer to hire more aggressive or less conservative managers and, as a result, output (consumer surplus) and overall welfare are larger than in a decentralized wage setting structure.

JEL Classification: J51; L13; L22

Corresponding author: Nicola Meccheri, Department of Economics and Management, University of Pisa, Pisa, Italy, RCEA (Fellow) and GLO (Fellow), E-mail:

Acknowledgments

I am extremely grateful to the Editor Tobias Wenzel and to an anonymous referee for their comments and suggestions. I would like to thank also Cecilia Vergari, Luca Gori, participants at SIE 2022 (Torino) and seminar attendants at the University of Pisa for useful remarks. Usual disclaimers apply.

Appendix A

A.1 Common Tenet with Firms as Unit Profit-Maximising Decision Makers

This section shows that when firms are unit profit-maximising decision makers, that is, strategic decisions about output are not delegated to biased managers,[23] the common tenet holds true: on the one hand, workers are better off under centralized wage setting whilst, on the other hand, firms, consumers and the society as a whole are better off under decentralized wage setting.

In order to obtain SPNE outcomes for this (benchmark) case in the presence of decentralized wage setting, we can use Eqs. (4) and (7) with k i = k j = 1, which leads to:

w i = w j = w ̃ D = θ ( 2 γ ) 2 θ γ

q i = q j = q ̃ D = 2 ( 1 θ ) ( 2 + γ ) ( 2 θ γ )

π i = π j = π ̃ D = 4 ( 1 θ ) 2 ( 2 + γ ) 2 ( 2 θ γ ) 2

W ̃ D = 4 ( 1 θ ) ( 3 + θ θ γ θ γ 2 + γ ) ( 2 + γ ) 2 ( 2 θ γ ) 2 .

Similarly, in order to get SPNE outcomes in the presence of centralized wage setting, we can use Eqs. (4) and (14) with k i = k j = 1, which leads to:

w i = w j = w ̃ C = θ

q i = q j = q ̃ C = 1 θ 2 + γ

π i = π j = π ̃ C = ( 1 θ ) 2 ( 2 + γ ) 2

W ̃ C = ( 1 θ ) ( 3 + θ + θ γ + γ ) ( 2 + γ ) 2 .

By comparing equilibrium outcomes under decentralized and centralized wage settings, and considering that consumer surplus is proportional to output, the common tenet holds true since, for any θ, γ ∈ (0, 1), we get:

w ̃ D < w ̃ C ; q ̃ D > q ̃ C ; π ̃ D > π ̃ C ; C S ̃ D > C S ̃ C ; W ̃ D > W ̃ C .

Also notice that as far as the total wage bill is concerned, it is greater in a centralized structure unless unions are distinctly oriented towards wages, that is, for any θ < 2 4 2 γ γ .[24] For instance, when θ = 1/2, i.e. unions attach the same weight to wages and employment, the total wage bill is always (i.e. for any γ ∈ (0, 1)) larger in a centralized structure.

A.2 Oligopoly with n Firms and Quantity Competition

In the case of oligopoly with n firms competing in quantities with homogeneous product, taking inverse demand (25) into account, the first-order condition of the manager i’s choice leads to:

(A1) q i = 1 2 k i w i j i q j .

At the equilibrium, Eq. (A1) is satisfied for each of the n firms. Summing the Eq. (A1) derived for the n firms, we obtain:

(A2) i = 1 n q i = 1 2 k i w i + j i ( k j w j ) i = 1 n j i q j .

Defining with Q = i = 1 n q i total output, we have that i = 1 n j i q j = ( n 1 ) Q , and solving (A2) with respect to Q, we obtain:

(A3) Q = 1 n + 1 k i w i + j i ( k j w j ) .

By considering that j i q j = Q q i , substituting (A3) into (A1) and solving with respect to q i , we find the equilibrium quantity as a function of wages and manager types:

(A4) q i = 1 n + 1 n ( k i w i ) j i ( k j w j ) .

At the second stage, wages are set by unions. Consider first the case with decentralized wage setting, where each firm has its own union. Union i maximises V i = w i θ q i 1 θ with respect to w i . Taking (A4) into account and solving for the first-order condition, we obtain:

(A5) w i = θ n n k i j i ( k j w j ) .

At the equilibrium, Eq. (A5) is satisfied for each of the n unions. Summing the Eq. (A5) derived for the n unions, we obtain:

(A6) i = 1 n w i = θ n k i + j i k j + ( n 1 ) W

where W = i = 1 n w i . Solving (A6) with respect to W and taking into account that j i w j = W w i , we can substitute in (A5) which leads to the equilibrium wage set by union i as a function of manager types:

(A7) w i = θ n θ n + θ k i j i k j .

At the first stage, firm owners choose the type of managers to be hired. By substituting in the profit equation (with inverse demand given by Eq. (24)) for (A4) and (A7), as well as for the equilibrium values of j i q j and j i w j , and taking into account that in the symmetric equilibrium k i = k j = k, profit maximisation leads the SPNE value of the manager type. Then, by substituting back, we obtain also the SPNE values of wages, output and profits, as all reported in Section 4.2.

Consider, instead, the case with centralized wage setting (industry-wide union). At the second stage, the union sets wages to maximise V = w θ ( q i + j i q j ) 1 θ , where (by considering w i = w j = w) q i is given by (A4) and j i q j is obtained as Qq i by using (A3) and (A4). Thus, subgame equilibrium wages as a function of manager types are given by:

(A8) w = θ n k i + j i k j .

As for the decentralized wage setting case, at the first stage, firm owners choose the manager type to maximise profits. By substituting in the profit equation for equilibrium output and wages, profit maximisation (taking into account that in the symmetric equilibrium k i = k j = k) leads to the SPNE value of the manager type. By substituting back, we obtain also the SPNE values of wages, output and profits with centralized wage setting, as reported in Section 4.2.

References

Asproudis, E., and M. J. Gil-Moltó. 2015. “Green Trade Unions: Structure, Wages and Environmental Technology.” Environmental and Resource Economics 60: 165–89. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9768-x.Search in Google Scholar

Bárcena-Ruiz, J. C. 2003. “Politically Preferred Wage Bargaining Structures.” European Journal of Political Economy 19: 341–53. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0176-2680(02)00173-8.Search in Google Scholar

Bárcena-Ruiz, J. C. 2013. “Endogenous Timing of Incentive Contracts in Mixed Markets Under Bertrand Competition.” The Manchester School 81: 340–55. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9957.2011.02284.x.Search in Google Scholar

Bennet, V. M., M. Lawrence, and R. Sadun. 2017. “Are Founder CEOs Good Managers?” In Measuring Entrepreneurial Businesses, edited by J. Haltiwanger, E. Hurst, J. Miranda, and A. Schoar. NBER, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Search in Google Scholar

Berle, A. A., and G. C. Means. 1932. The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: Brace and World.Search in Google Scholar

Boeri, T., and J. van Ours. 2021. The Economics of Imperfect Labor Markets, 3rd ed. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Brander, J. A., and B. J. Spencer. 1988. “Unionized Oligopoly and International Trade Policy.” Journal of International Economics 24: 217–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-1996(88)90035-9.Search in Google Scholar

Bughin, J. 1995. “Unions and Strategic Managerial Incentives.” Economics Letters 47: 95–100. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-1765(94)00504-u.Search in Google Scholar

Bughin, J., and S. Vannini. 1995. “Strategic Direct Investment under Unionized Oligopoly.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 13: 127–45. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-7187(94)00447-a.Search in Google Scholar

Davidson, C. 1988. “Multiunit Bargaining in Oligopolistic Industries.” Journal of Labor Economics 6: 397–422. https://doi.org/10.1086/298189.Search in Google Scholar

Dhillon, A., and E. Petrakis. 2002. “A Generalised Wage Rigidity Result.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 20: 285–311. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0167-7187(00)00065-5.Search in Google Scholar

Dixit, A. K. 1979. “A Model of Duopoly Suggesting a Theory of Entry Barriers.” The Bell Journal of Economics 10: 20–32. https://doi.org/10.2307/3003317.Search in Google Scholar

Dowrick, S., and B. J. Spencer. 1994. “Union Attitudes to Labor-Saving Innovation: When Are Unions Luddites?” Journal of Labor Economics 12: 316–44. https://doi.org/10.1086/298359.Search in Google Scholar

Englmaier, F. 2010. “Managerial Optimism and Investment Choice.” Managerial and Decision Economics 31: 303–10. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.1498.Search in Google Scholar

Englmaier, F. 2011. “Commitment in R&D Tournaments via Strategic Delegation to Overoptimistic Managers.” Managerial and Decision Economics 32: 63–9. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.1518.Search in Google Scholar

Englmaier, F., and M. Reisinger. 2014. “Biased Managers as Strategic Commitment.” Managerial and Decision Economics 35: 350–6. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.2619.Search in Google Scholar

Fanti, L., and N. Meccheri. 2015. “On the Cournot-Bertrand Profit Differential and the Structure of Unionisation in a Managerial Duopoly.” Australian Economic Papers 54: 266–87. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8454.12054.Search in Google Scholar

Fanti, L., and N. Meccheri. 2017. “Unionization Regimes, Capacity Choice by Firms and Welfare Outcomes.” The Manchester School 85: 661–81. https://doi.org/10.1111/manc.12165.Search in Google Scholar

Fershtman, C., and K. L. Judd. 1987. “Equilibrium Incentives in Oligopoly.” The American Economic Review 77: 927–40.Search in Google Scholar

Galasso, A., and T. Simcoe. 2011. “CEO Overconfidence and Innovation.” Management Science 57: 1469–84. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1110.1374.Search in Google Scholar

Haucap, J., and C. Wey. 2004. “Unionisation Structures and Innovation Incentives.” Economic Journal 114: 149–65. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0013-0133.2004.00203.x.Search in Google Scholar

Horn, H., and A. Wolinsky. 1988. “Bilateral Monopolies and Incentives for Merger.” The RAND Journal of Economics 19: 408–19. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555664.Search in Google Scholar

Huffman, D., C. Raymond, and J. Shvets. 2022. “Persistent Overconfidence and Biased Memory: Evidence from Managers.” American Economic Review 112: 3141–75.10.1257/aer.20190668Search in Google Scholar

Kopel, M., and M. Pezzino. 2018. “Strategic Delegation in Oligopoly.” In Handbook of Game Theory and Industrial Organization, Vol. 2, edited by L. C. Corchón, and M. A. Marini. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Search in Google Scholar

Lambertini, L. 2017. An Economic Theory of Managerial Firms. Strategic Delegation in Oligopoly. London and New York: Routdlege.10.4324/9781315620879Search in Google Scholar

Lommerud, K. E., and O. R. Straume. 2012. “Employment Protection versus Flexicurity: On Technology Adoption in Unionised Firms.” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 114: 177–99. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9442.2011.01663.x.Search in Google Scholar

Malmendier, U., and G. Tate. 2005. “CEO Overconfidence and Corporate Investment.” The Journal of Finance 60: 2661–700. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2005.00813.x.Search in Google Scholar

Malmendier, U., and G. Tate. 2008. “Who Makes Acquisitions? CEO Overconfidence and the Market’s Reaction.” Journal of Financial Economics 89: 20–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2007.07.002.Search in Google Scholar

Malmendier, U., and G. Tate. 2015. “Behavioral CEOs: The Role of Managerial Overconfidence.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 29: 37–60. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.29.4.37.Search in Google Scholar

Meccheri, N. 2021. “Biased Managers in Vertically Related Markets.” Managerial and Decision Economics 42: 724–36. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3268.Search in Google Scholar

Meccheri, N. 2022. “The Political Economy of Managerial Delegation with Unionized Labor Markets.” In Handbook of Labor, Human Resources and Population Economics, edited by K. F. Zimmermann. Cham: Springer.10.1007/978-3-319-57365-6_232-1Search in Google Scholar

Mezzetti, C., and E. Dinopoulos. 1991. “Domestic Unionization and Import Competition.” Journal of International Economics 31: 79–100. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-1996(91)90057-d.Search in Google Scholar

Moore, D. A., and D. M. Cain. 2007. “Overconfidence and Underconfidence: When and Why People Underestimate (And Overestimate) the Competition.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 103: 197–213. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2006.09.002.Search in Google Scholar

Mukherjee, A., and E. Pennings. 2011. “Unionization Structure, Licensing and Innovation.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 29: 232–41. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2010.06.001.Search in Google Scholar

Mukherjee, A., and K. Suetrong. 2012. “Unionisation Structure and Outward Foreign Direct Investment.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 168: 266–79. https://doi.org/10.1628/093245612800933933.Search in Google Scholar

Nakamura, Y. 2014. “Biased Managers as Strategic Commitment: The Relative Profit Approach.” Research in Economics 68: 230–8. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rie.2014.01.004.Search in Google Scholar

Nakamura, Y. 2015. “Biased Managers as Strategic Commitment in a Mixed Duopoly with Relative Profit-Maximizers.” Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 15: 323–36. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-015-0198-4.Search in Google Scholar

Nakamura, Y. 2019. “The Impact of the Presence of Biased Managers as Strategic Commitment on Endogenous Market Structures.” Managerial and Decision Economics 40: 84–96. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.2983.Search in Google Scholar

OECD. 2004. OECD Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD Publishing.Search in Google Scholar

OECD. 2016. Enhancing Economic Flexibility: What is in it for Workers? OECD Economic Policy Papers, No. 19. Paris: OECD Publishing.Search in Google Scholar

Oswald, A. J. 1985. “The Economic Theory of Trade Unions: An Introductory Survey.” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 87: 160–93. https://doi.org/10.2307/3439820.Search in Google Scholar

Pasquier, N., and P. Toquebeuf. 2022. “Management Turnover, Strategic Ambiguity and Supply Incentives.” The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 23: 121–54. https://doi.org/10.1515/bejte-2021-0070.Search in Google Scholar

Pencavel, J. H. 1984. “The Tradeoff between Wages and Employment in Trade Union Objectives.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 99: 215–31. https://doi.org/10.2307/1885523.Search in Google Scholar

Pencavel, J. H. 1985. “Wages and Employment under Trade Unionism: Microeconomic Models and Macroeconomic Applications.” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 87: 197–225. https://doi.org/10.2307/3439822.Search in Google Scholar

Singh, N., and X. Vives. 1984. “Price and Quantity Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly.” The RAND Journal of Economics 15: 546–54. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555525.Search in Google Scholar

Sklivas, S. D. 1987. “The Strategic Choice of Managerial Incentives.” The RAND Journal of Economics 18: 452–8. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555609.Search in Google Scholar

Szymanski, S. 1994. “Strategic Delegation with Endogenous Costs. A Duopoly with Wage Bargaining.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 12: 105–16. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-7187(94)90030-2.Search in Google Scholar

Vickers, J. 1985. “Delegation and the Theory of the Firm.” Economic Journal 95: 138–47. https://doi.org/10.2307/2232877.Search in Google Scholar

Williamson, O. E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.Search in Google Scholar

Yu, C.-F. 2014. “CEO Overconfidence and Overinvestment under Product Market Competition.” Managerial and Decision Economics 35: 574–9. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.2662.Search in Google Scholar

Zhao, L. 2001. “Unionization, Vertical Markets, and the Outsourcing of Multinationals.” Journal of International Economics 55: 187–202. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0022-1996(01)00090-3.Search in Google Scholar


Supplementary Material

This article contains supplementary material (https://doi.org/10.1515/bejeap-2022-0321).


Received: 2022-08-23
Accepted: 2023-05-21
Published Online: 2023-06-01

© 2023 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 6.12.2023 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2022-0321/html
Scroll to top button