Abstract
The empirical evidence on the causal relationship between international trade and economic growth is inconclusive. While some studies show that trade leads to growth, others have pointed to a reverse causation. In this paper, we develop a model of international trade and productivity growth in the presence of a misallocation of resources. Misallocation in a country arises as a result of lobbying by firms to establish barriers to the competitive allocation of labor. Misallocation prevents the country from exploiting its technological comparative advantage and leads to a reduction in the volume of trade in the absence of any explicit trade barriers. In the model, whether barriers diminish or worsen with productivity growth depends on the extent of the initial resource misallocation. If the initial resource misallocation is not severe, then productivity growth leads to diminishing barriers and vice versa. In either case, productivity growth strengthens the comparative advantage over time and therefore increases the volume of trade.
Acknowledgement
We would like to thank the associate editor and two anonymous referees for their comments.
Appendix
Proof of Proposition 1: As is clear from Equation (11), the optimal contribution of type B firms in the interval [0, θρ) is β* = 0. On the interval [θρ, ∞), the payoff πB has a derivative equal to (θρhB/β2 − 1) which is greater than, equal to, or less than 0 as θρhB is greater than, equal to, or less than β2. It follows also that if this derivative is less than zero at θρ, then it is less than zero on the entire interval [θρ, ∞). Therefore, if the derivative is negative at θρ, then the optimal value for β on [θρ, ∞) is β = θρ. In this case, the globally optimal β, as established above, is β = 0.
If the derivative at β = θρ is positive, that is, if ρ < hB/θ, then the optimal β on [θρ, ∞) is
However, this value of β is globally optimal if and only if the payoff at β = (θρhB)1/2 is greater than the payoff obtained when β = 0. This requires
This establishes that the optimal value for β, β*, is
Given the values for β* in Equation (33), we can now determine the optimal allocation for the type R leader. As is clear from Equation (33), the optimal value for ρ lies in the interval [0,
Let f(ρ) ≡ (θρ)1/2hR/hB1/2 − ρ and note that f′(ρ) >, <, or = 0, as ρ <, >, or = ρ* ≡ (θ
Suppose θ < (hB/hR) and thus ρ* is less than
Note that when ρ = ρ* ≡ (θ
The quadratic function g(θ) has zeros at θ = (hB/hR)(2 −
References
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2001. “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.” American Economic Review 91 (5): 1369–1401.10.3386/w7771Search in Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2002. “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4): 1231–1294.10.3386/w8460Search in Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and James A. Robinson. 2006. “Economic Backwardness in Political Perspective.” American Political Science Review 100 (1): 115–131.10.3386/w8831Search in Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and James A. Robinson. 2012. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty., Vol. 1, 1st ed. 115–131. New York: Crown.Search in Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Philippe Aghion, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2006. “Distance to Frontier, Selection, and Economic Growth.” Journal of the European Economic Association 4 (1): 37–74.10.3386/w9066Search in Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Dani Rodrik. 1994. “Distributive Politics and Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (2): 465–490.10.3386/w3668Search in Google Scholar
Anderson, Lill, and Ronald Babula. 2008. “The link between openness and long-run economic growth.” Journal of International Commerce and Economics 2: 31–50.Search in Google Scholar
Baik, Kyung H., and Jason F. Shogren. 1992. “Strategic Behavior in Contests: Comment.” The American Economic Review 82 (1): 359–362.10.1007/978-3-540-79182-9_31Search in Google Scholar
Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Benjamin Moll. 2010. “Why Does Misallocation Persist?” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (1): 189–206.10.1257/mac.2.1.189Search in Google Scholar
Bartelsman, Eric, John Haltiwanger, and Stefano Scarpetta. 2013. “Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection.” American Economic Review 103 (1): 305–334.10.3386/w15490Search in Google Scholar
Buera, Francisco J., Joseph P. Kaboski, and Yongseok Shin. 2011. “Finance and Development: A Tale of Two Sectors.” American Economic Review 101 (5): 1964–2002.10.3386/w14914Search in Google Scholar
Campante, Filipe R., and Francisco H. G. Ferreira. 2007. “Inefficient Lobbying, Populism and Oligarchy.” Journal of Public Economics 91 (5): 993–1021.10.1596/1813-9450-3240Search in Google Scholar
Dollar, David 1992. “Outward-oriented Developing Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 40 (3): 523–544.10.1086/451959Search in Google Scholar
Edwards, Sebastian 1998. “Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do We Really Know?” Economic Journal 108 (447): 383–398.10.3386/w5978Search in Google Scholar
Fischer, Stanley (2000). Lunch address given at the conference on “Promoting Dialogue: Global Challenges and Global Institutions.”. Washington: American University.Search in Google Scholar
Glazer, Amihai, and Refael Hassin. 2000. “Sequential Rent Seeking.” Public Choice 102 (3–4): 219–228.10.1023/A:1005011008448Search in Google Scholar
Jeong, Hyeok, and Robert M. Townsend. 2007. “Sources of TFP Growth: Occupational Choice and Financial Deepening.” Economic Theory 32 (1): 179–221.10.1007/s00199-006-0201-8Search in Google Scholar
Hseih, Chang-Tai, and Peter J. Klenow. 2009. “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (4): 1403–1448.10.3386/w13290Search in Google Scholar
Le Breton, Michel, Peter Sudhölter, and Vera Zaporozhets. 2012. “Sequential Legislative Lobbying.” Social Choice and Welfare 39 (2–3): 491–520.10.1007/s00355-012-0660-8Search in Google Scholar
Leininger, Wolfgang 1993. “More Efficient Rent-seeking a Münchhausen Solution.” Public Choice 75 (1): 43–62.10.1007/978-1-4757-5055-3_19Search in Google Scholar
Linster, Bruce G 1993. “Stackelberg Rent-seeking.” Public Choice 77 (2): 307–321.10.1007/BF01047872Search in Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert E 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics 22 (1): 3–42.10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7Search in Google Scholar
Mohtadi, Hamid, and Terry Roe. 1998. “Growth, Lobbying and Public Goods.” European Journal of Political Economy 14 (3): 453–473.10.1016/S0176-2680(98)00017-2Search in Google Scholar
Mork, Knut Anton 1993. “Living with Lobbying: A Growth Policy Co-opted by Lobbyists Can Be Better than No Growth Policy at All.” The Scandinavian Journal of Econoics 95 (4): 597–605.10.2307/3440913Search in Google Scholar
Ray, Debraj 2010. “Uneven Growth: A Framework for Research in Development Economics.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 24 (3): 45–60.10.1257/jep.24.3.45Search in Google Scholar
Restuccia, Diego, and Richard Rogerson. 2008. “Policy Distortions and Aggregate Productivity with Heterogeneous Establishments.” Review of Economic Dynamics 11 (4): 707–720.10.1016/j.red.2008.05.002Search in Google Scholar
Rodriguez, Fransico, and Dani Rodrik. (2001)."Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic’s Guide to the Cross-National Evidence," NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000. Cambridge: MIT Press 261–338.Search in Google Scholar
Sachs, Jeffrey, and Andrew Warner. 1995. “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 1–118.10.2307/2534573Search in Google Scholar
©2017 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston