Abstract
Empirical evidence suggests that the differences in rates of technical progress across sectors are time-variant, implying that the bias in technological change is not constant. In this paper, we analyze the implications of this non-constant sectoral biased technical change for structural change and we assess whether this is an important factor behind structural transformations. To this end, we develop a multi-sectoral growth model where TFP growth rates across sectors are non-constant. We calibrate our model to match the development of the U.S. economy during the twentieth century. Our findings show that, by assuming non-constant biased technical change, a purely technological approach is able to replicate the sectoral transformations in the U.S. economy not only after but also prior to World War II.
Acknowledgement
I thank my thesis advisor, Xavier Raurich, for his helpful suggestions. I thank Berthold Herrendorf for helpful comments and suggestions on an earlier version of the paper. I am grateful to Akos Valentinyi, Marc Teignier, Marti Mestieri, and Miguel Leon-Ledesma for valuable comments and suggestions. I acknowledge financial support from the Universitat de Barcelona through the grant APIF and from CONACYT grant 383793.
Appendix
A Equilibrium properties
Solution to the representative consumer optimization problem
The Hamiltonian function associated with the maximization of (15) subject to (9), (10), (11), and (12) is
where μa, μs and μm are the co-state variables corresponding to the constraints (11) and (12), respectively. The first order conditions are
and
The sectoral allocation of capital and relative prices
From combining (34) and (36), we obtain
and combining (35) and (37), we obtain
We substitute
which implies
By assuming that the manufacturing good is the numerarie and dividing equations (34) by (35), and combining (10), (39), (40) and (41), we obtain the relative prices
Note that the relative prices are the ratio between the co-state variables.
The GDP is obtained by substitution of (16) and (17) in (45). Firstly, we substitute (16) in (8) to obtain
and GDP
By combining with (17), (44) and (45), we obtain
and, given (10), we obtain that
The Euler equation
From (19), we obtain Ca and Cs as functions of Cm and the relative prices
We then substitute these equation in (14) and combining with (33), we obtain
Substituting (46) in (20) we obtain
where total expenditure is a function of the co-state variable corresponding to the constraint (12). By substituting (16) in (8), and combining with (38), we obtain the growth rate of the co-state variables μm as follows
We then log-differentiate
Proof of Proposition 4.1. If ωm > 0, then the dynamic system is
From equation
and substituting in
The steady state, it must be satisfied that
Solving the system for z and c, we obtain
If ϖm = 0, then the dynamic system at the steady state is
At the steady state, we obtain
Proof of Proposition 4.2. If ωm > 0, there are two state variables and one variable control. Using (26), (27), and (28), we obtain the following Jacobian matrix evaluated at the steady state
where
It is immediate to see that the eigenvalues are
where the solutions are
Insofar as a21 < 0 and ρ > 0, it follows that one of the roots, for example λ2 is always negative and the other one, λ3, is positive. So, λ1, λ2 < 0 and λ3 > 0. This result implies that there is a two-dimensional stable manifold in (z, c, v3) space.
On the other hand, If ωm = 0, there is one state variable and one control variable. Using (26), (27), we obtain the following Jacobian matrix evaluated at the steady state
where
As
the eigenvalues of the system are real numbers of opposite signs, and the steady state is saddle path stable.
B Estimation of the technology
Solution of differential equation
We then pose the law of motion of productivity in the i sector as follows
where we define the inverse of the distance across sectors and the frontier as follows
By taking the log-derivative of (48), we obtain that the law of motion of technological gaps is
We rewrite (49) as follows
then (50) can be integrated after a single substitution. Let
where
Substituting in (50), integrating and solving the integral equation,
we obtain
We substitute back into the mi to obtain
and substituting (51) in (48), we finally obtain
Estimation procedures: using EUKLEMS (1970–2005)
From the definition of (52), we can estimate ωi and ϕi using the data on the TFP growth rates of the agriculture, manufacturing, and services sectors from the EUKLEMS database that covers 1970–2005. To this end, we estimate the following equation which derives from (52) and our assumption that the technology frontier grows at a constant rate in equation (1). Taking logs in (52) we obtain
and normalizing the initial stock in the frontier to one, A0 = 1, we can estimate the following system of equations
where
We estimate the parameters in (53) constrained to βi = γ for all sector using non-linear squares. We report the results in Table 1 and Table 2 reports the estimated values of ωa, and ωs and the values of ϕa and ϕs, which are obtained by nonlinear combinations of the estimated parameters
References
Abramovitz, M. 1986. “Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind.” The Journal of Economic History 46 (2): 385–406.10.1017/S0022050700046209Search in Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., and V. Guerrieri. 2008. “Capital Deepening and Nonbalanced Economic Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 116: 467–498.10.1086/589523Search in Google Scholar
Alonso-Carrera, J., and X. Raurich. 2010. “Growth, Sectoral Composition, and the Evolution of Income Levels.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34 (12): 2440–2460.10.1016/j.jedc.2010.06.011Search in Google Scholar
Alvarez-Cuadrado, F., and M. Poschke. 2011. “Structural Change Out of Agriculture: Labor Push versus Labor Pull.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3 (3): 127–158.10.1257/mac.3.3.127Search in Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J. 1967. “Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomy of Urban Crisis.” The American Economic Review 57 (3): 415–426.Search in Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J., S. A. B. Blackman, and E. Wolff. 1989. Productivity and American Leadership: The Long View. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar
Bond, E., P. Wang, and C. Yip. 1996. “A General Two-Sector Modelof Endogenous Growth with Human and Physical Capital: Balanced Growth and Transitional Dynamics.” Journal of Economic Theory 68: 149–173.10.1006/jeth.1996.0008Search in Google Scholar
Boppart, T. 2014. “Structural Change and the Kaldor Facts in a Growth Model with Relative Price Effects and Non-Gorman Preferences.” Econometrica 82 (6): 2167–2196.10.3982/ECTA11354Search in Google Scholar
Buera, F., and J. P. Kaboski. 2009. “Can Traditional Theories of Structural Change Fit the Data?” Journal of the European EconomicAssociation 7 (2–3): 469–477.10.1162/JEEA.2009.7.2-3.469Search in Google Scholar
Dennis, B. N., and T. B. Iscan. 2009. “Engel Versus Baumol: Accounting for Structural Change Using Two Centuries of U.S. Data.” Explorations in Economic History 46 (2): 186–202.10.1016/j.eeh.2008.11.003Search in Google Scholar
Echevarria, C. 1997. “Changes in Sectoral Composition Associated with Economic Growth.” International Economic Review 38: 431–452.10.2307/2527382Search in Google Scholar
Foellmi, R., and J. Zweimüller. 2008. “Strucutral Change, Engel’s Consumption Cycles and Kaldor’s Facts of Economic Growth.” Journalof Monetary Economics 55: 1317–1328.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2008.09.001Search in Google Scholar
Gollin, D., D. Lagakos, and M. E. Waugh. 2014. “Agricultural Productivity Differences Across Countries.” American Economic Review 104 (5): 165–170.10.1257/aer.104.5.165Search in Google Scholar
Herrendorf, B., R. Rogerson, and Á. Valentinyi. 2014. “Growth and Structural Transformation, Chapter 6.”. In Handbook of Economic Growth, edited by A. Philippe and N. D. Steven, Vol. 2, 855–941. Amsterdam: Elsevier.10.1016/B978-0-444-53540-5.00006-9Search in Google Scholar
Herrendorf, B., R. Rogerson, and Á. Valentinyi. 2013. “Two Perspectives on Preferences and Structural Transformation.” American Economic Review 103 (7): 2752–2789.10.3386/w15416Search in Google Scholar
Joint Economic Committee. The economic report of the President: hearing before the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, One Hundred Ninth Congress, second session. 2007. February 16, 2006. Washington.Search in Google Scholar
Kongsamut, P., S. Rebelo, and D. Xie. 2001. “Beyond Balanced Growth.” Review of Economic Studies 68: 869–882.10.3386/w6159Search in Google Scholar
Meckl, J. 2002. “Structural Change and Generalized Balanced Growth.” Journal of Economics 77 (3): 241–266. DOI:10.1007/s00712-002-0542-0.Search in Google Scholar
Ngai, R., and C. Pissarides. 2004. Structural Change in a Multi-Sector Model of Growth [monograph]. IZA Discussion Paper.10.2139/ssrn.827367Search in Google Scholar
Ngai, R., and C. Pissarides. 2007. “Structural Change in a Multi-sector Model of Growth.” American Economic Review 97: 429–443.10.2139/ssrn.827367Search in Google Scholar
O’Mahony, M., and M. P. Timmer. 2009. “Output, Input and Productivity Measures at the Industry Level: The EU KLEMS Database.” Economic Journal 119 (538): F374–F403.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02280.xSearch in Google Scholar
Steger, T. M. 2006. “Heterogeneous Consumption Goods, Sectoral Change and Economic Growth.” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 10 (1):. Article 2.10.2202/1558-3708.1309Search in Google Scholar
United States Bureau of the Census. Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1970. 1975.Search in Google Scholar
Verspagen, B. 1991. “A New Empirical Approach to Catching Up or Falling Behind.” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 2 (2): 359–380.10.1016/S0954-349X(05)80008-6Search in Google Scholar
©2017 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston