Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter July 4, 2017

Structural change and non-constant biased technical change

  • Edgar Cruz EMAIL logo

Abstract

Empirical evidence suggests that the differences in rates of technical progress across sectors are time-variant, implying that the bias in technological change is not constant. In this paper, we analyze the implications of this non-constant sectoral biased technical change for structural change and we assess whether this is an important factor behind structural transformations. To this end, we develop a multi-sectoral growth model where TFP growth rates across sectors are non-constant. We calibrate our model to match the development of the U.S. economy during the twentieth century. Our findings show that, by assuming non-constant biased technical change, a purely technological approach is able to replicate the sectoral transformations in the U.S. economy not only after but also prior to World War II.

JEL Classification: O41; O47

Acknowledgement

I thank my thesis advisor, Xavier Raurich, for his helpful suggestions. I thank Berthold Herrendorf for helpful comments and suggestions on an earlier version of the paper. I am grateful to Akos Valentinyi, Marc Teignier, Marti Mestieri, and Miguel Leon-Ledesma for valuable comments and suggestions. I acknowledge financial support from the Universitat de Barcelona through the grant APIF and from CONACYT grant 383793.

Appendix

A Equilibrium properties

Solution to the representative consumer optimization problem

The Hamiltonian function associated with the maximization of (15) subject to (9), (10), (11), and (12) is

H=lnC~+i=a,sμi(YiCi)+μm(YmδKCm),

where μa, μs and μm are the co-state variables corresponding to the constraints (11) and (12), respectively. The first order conditions are

(31)ηaC~1ϵϵCa1ϵ=μa,
(32)η2C~1ϵϵCs1ϵ=μs,
(33)η3C~1ϵϵCm1ϵ=μm,
(34)(1α)μaYala=(1α)μmYmlm,
(35)(1α)μsYsls=(1α)μmYmlm,
(36)αμaYaυa=αμmYmυm,
(37)αμsYsυs=αμmYmυm,

and

(38)μ˙m+μmρ=μaαYaK+μsαYsK+μm(αYmKδ).

The sectoral allocation of capital and relative prices

From combining (34) and (36), we obtain

υa=υmlalm,

and combining (35) and (37), we obtain

υs=υmlslm.

We substitute υa and υs in (9), and taking into account (10), the optimal capital share in the manufacturing sector is

(39)υm=lm,

which implies

(40)υa=la,
(41)υs=ls.

By assuming that the manufacturing good is the numerarie and dividing equations (34) by (35), and combining (10), (39), (40) and (41), we obtain the relative prices

(42)paμaμm=YmlaYalm=AmAa,
(43)psμsμm=YmlsYslm=AmAs.

Note that the relative prices are the ratio between the co-state variables.

The GDP is obtained by substitution of (16) and (17) in (45). Firstly, we substitute (16) in (8) to obtain

(44)Yi=AiKαli,

and GDP

(45)Y=paYa+psYs+Ym.

By combining with (17), (44) and (45), we obtain

Y=AmKα(la+lm+lm),

and, given (10), we obtain that

Y=AmKα.

The Euler equation

From (19), we obtain Ca and Cs as functions of Cm and the relative prices

Ci=(ηiηm)ϵpiϵCm for i=a,s.

We then substitute these equation in (14) and combining with (33), we obtain

(46)(1+xa+xs)Cm=μm1.

Substituting (46) in (20) we obtain

C=μm1,

where total expenditure is a function of the co-state variable corresponding to the constraint (12). By substituting (16) in (8), and combining with (38), we obtain the growth rate of the co-state variables μm as follows

(47)μ^m=αAmKα1(ρ+δ).

We then log-differentiate C=μm1 and combine with (47), we obtain (24).

Proof of Proposition 4.1. If ωm > 0, then the dynamic system is

z^=zα1czδγϕmωmlnvm(1α),c^=αzα1(ρ+δ)γϕmωmlnvm(1α),v^m=ϕmγωmlnvm,

From equation v^m, it follows that there is a unique steady value such that

vm=exp(ϕmγωm),

and substituting in z^ and ĉ, we obtain

z^=zα1czδγ(1α),c^=αzα1(ρ+δ)γ(1α).

The steady state, it must be satisfied that z^ = ĉ = 0, implying that

0=zα1czδγ(1α),0=αzα1(ρ+δ)γ(1α).

Solving the system for z and c, we obtain

z=(α(1α)γ+(1α)(ρ+δ))11α,c=(γ+ρ+(1α)δ)α(α(1α)γ+(1α)(δ+ρ))11α.

If ϖm = 0, then the dynamic system at the steady state is

z^=zα1czδϕm(1α),c^=αzα1(ρ+δ)ϕm(1α).

At the steady state, we obtain

z=(α(1α)ϕmγ+(1α)(ρ+δ))11α,c=(ϕmγ+ρ+(1α)δα)(α(1α)ϕmγ+(1α)(δ+ρ))11α.

Proof of Proposition 4.2. If ωm > 0, there are two state variables and one variable control. Using (26), (27), and (28), we obtain the following Jacobian matrix evaluated at the steady state

J=(a11a12a13a21a22a2300a33),

where

a11z^z=ρ,a12z^c=1,a13z^vm=ωm1αzvm,a21c^z=α(α1)zα2c,a23ωm1αcvm,a33v^mvm=ωm.

It is immediate to see that the eigenvalues are λ1=ωm, and the two roots λ2 and λ3 are the solution of the following equation

Q(λ)=λ2λ(ρ)+a21=0,

where the solutions are

λ2,λ3=ρ±ρ24a212.

Insofar as a21 < 0 and ρ > 0, it follows that one of the roots, for example λ2 is always negative and the other one, λ3, is positive. So, λ1, λ2 < 0 and λ3 > 0. This result implies that there is a two-dimensional stable manifold in (z, c, v3) space.

On the other hand, If ωm = 0, there is one state variable and one control variable. Using (26), (27), we obtain the following Jacobian matrix evaluated at the steady state

J=(b11b12b21b22),

where

b11z^z=ρ,b12z^c=1,b21c^z=α(α1)zα2c,b22c^c=0.

As

detJ=λ1λ2=(b21)(b12)<0,

the eigenvalues of the system are real numbers of opposite signs, and the steady state is saddle path stable.

B Estimation of the technology

Solution of differential equation

We then pose the law of motion of productivity in the i sector as follows

A˙iAi=ϕi+ωiln(1vi),

where we define the inverse of the distance across sectors and the frontier as follows

(48)vi=AiA.

By taking the log-derivative of (48), we obtain that the law of motion of technological gaps is

(49)v˙i=(ϕiγ)viωiln(vi)vi.

We rewrite (49) as follows

(50)dvi(ϕiγ)viωiln(vi)vi=dt,

then (50) can be integrated after a single substitution. Let

m=ϕiγωiln(vi),

where

dmdvi=ωividvivi=dmωi.

Substituting in (50), integrating and solving the integral equation,

1ωi1midmi=dt,

we obtain

mi=eωi(t+c),

We substitute back into the mi to obtain

(51)vi=exp(ϕiγωi+eωi(ct)),

and substituting (51) in (48), we finally obtain

(52)Ai=exp(ϕiγωi+eωi(ct))A.

Estimation procedures: using EUKLEMS (1970–2005)

From the definition of (52), we can estimate ωi and ϕi using the data on the TFP growth rates of the agriculture, manufacturing, and services sectors from the EUKLEMS database that covers 1970–2005. To this end, we estimate the following equation which derives from (52) and our assumption that the technology frontier grows at a constant rate in equation (1). Taking logs in (52) we obtain

lnAi=ϕiγωi+lnA0+eωi(ct)+γt,

and normalizing the initial stock in the frontier to one, A0 = 1, we can estimate the following system of equations

(53)lnAa=αa+βat+eδa(tca),lnAm=αm+βmt+eδm(tcm),lnAs=αs+βst+eδs(tcs),

where

αi=ϕiγωi;βi=γ; and δi=ωi.

We estimate the parameters in (53) constrained to βi = γ for all sector using non-linear squares. We report the results in Table 1 and Table 2 reports the estimated values of ωa, and ωs and the values of ϕa and ϕs, which are obtained by nonlinear combinations of the estimated parameters α^i and β^i using nlcom (nonlinear combination) command in STATA.

References

Abramovitz, M. 1986. “Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind.” The Journal of Economic History 46 (2): 385–406.10.1017/S0022050700046209Search in Google Scholar

Acemoglu, D., and V. Guerrieri. 2008. “Capital Deepening and Nonbalanced Economic Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 116: 467–498.10.1086/589523Search in Google Scholar

Alonso-Carrera, J., and X. Raurich. 2010. “Growth, Sectoral Composition, and the Evolution of Income Levels.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34 (12): 2440–2460.10.1016/j.jedc.2010.06.011Search in Google Scholar

Alvarez-Cuadrado, F., and M. Poschke. 2011. “Structural Change Out of Agriculture: Labor Push versus Labor Pull.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3 (3): 127–158.10.1257/mac.3.3.127Search in Google Scholar

Baumol, W. J. 1967. “Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomy of Urban Crisis.” The American Economic Review 57 (3): 415–426.Search in Google Scholar

Baumol, W. J., S. A. B. Blackman, and E. Wolff. 1989. Productivity and American Leadership: The Long View. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar

Bond, E., P. Wang, and C. Yip. 1996. “A General Two-Sector Modelof Endogenous Growth with Human and Physical Capital: Balanced Growth and Transitional Dynamics.” Journal of Economic Theory 68: 149–173.10.1006/jeth.1996.0008Search in Google Scholar

Boppart, T. 2014. “Structural Change and the Kaldor Facts in a Growth Model with Relative Price Effects and Non-Gorman Preferences.” Econometrica 82 (6): 2167–2196.10.3982/ECTA11354Search in Google Scholar

Buera, F., and J. P. Kaboski. 2009. “Can Traditional Theories of Structural Change Fit the Data?” Journal of the European EconomicAssociation 7 (2–3): 469–477.10.1162/JEEA.2009.7.2-3.469Search in Google Scholar

Dennis, B. N., and T. B. Iscan. 2009. “Engel Versus Baumol: Accounting for Structural Change Using Two Centuries of U.S. Data.” Explorations in Economic History 46 (2): 186–202.10.1016/j.eeh.2008.11.003Search in Google Scholar

Echevarria, C. 1997. “Changes in Sectoral Composition Associated with Economic Growth.” International Economic Review 38: 431–452.10.2307/2527382Search in Google Scholar

Foellmi, R., and J. Zweimüller. 2008. “Strucutral Change, Engel’s Consumption Cycles and Kaldor’s Facts of Economic Growth.” Journalof Monetary Economics 55: 1317–1328.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2008.09.001Search in Google Scholar

Gollin, D., D. Lagakos, and M. E. Waugh. 2014. “Agricultural Productivity Differences Across Countries.” American Economic Review 104 (5): 165–170.10.1257/aer.104.5.165Search in Google Scholar

Herrendorf, B., R. Rogerson, and Á. Valentinyi. 2014. “Growth and Structural Transformation, Chapter 6.”. In Handbook of Economic Growth, edited by A. Philippe and N. D. Steven, Vol. 2, 855–941. Amsterdam: Elsevier.10.1016/B978-0-444-53540-5.00006-9Search in Google Scholar

Herrendorf, B., R. Rogerson, and Á. Valentinyi. 2013. “Two Perspectives on Preferences and Structural Transformation.” American Economic Review 103 (7): 2752–2789.10.3386/w15416Search in Google Scholar

Joint Economic Committee. The economic report of the President: hearing before the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, One Hundred Ninth Congress, second session. 2007. February 16, 2006. Washington.Search in Google Scholar

Kongsamut, P., S. Rebelo, and D. Xie. 2001. “Beyond Balanced Growth.” Review of Economic Studies 68: 869–882.10.3386/w6159Search in Google Scholar

Meckl, J. 2002. “Structural Change and Generalized Balanced Growth.” Journal of Economics 77 (3): 241–266. DOI:10.1007/s00712-002-0542-0.Search in Google Scholar

Ngai, R., and C. Pissarides. 2004. Structural Change in a Multi-Sector Model of Growth [monograph]. IZA Discussion Paper.10.2139/ssrn.827367Search in Google Scholar

Ngai, R., and C. Pissarides. 2007. “Structural Change in a Multi-sector Model of Growth.” American Economic Review 97: 429–443.10.2139/ssrn.827367Search in Google Scholar

O’Mahony, M., and M. P. Timmer. 2009. “Output, Input and Productivity Measures at the Industry Level: The EU KLEMS Database.” Economic Journal 119 (538): F374–F403.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02280.xSearch in Google Scholar

Steger, T. M. 2006. “Heterogeneous Consumption Goods, Sectoral Change and Economic Growth.” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 10 (1):. Article 2.10.2202/1558-3708.1309Search in Google Scholar

United States Bureau of the Census. Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1970. 1975.Search in Google Scholar

Verspagen, B. 1991. “A New Empirical Approach to Catching Up or Falling Behind.” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 2 (2): 359–380.10.1016/S0954-349X(05)80008-6Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2017-7-4

©2017 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 5.6.2023 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejm-2015-0046/html
Scroll to top button