Abstract
This paper studies how macroprudential policy tools applied to the housing market can complement the interest rate-based monetary policy in achieving one additional stabilization objective, defined as keeping either economic activity or credit at some exogenous (and possibly time-varying) levels. We show analytically in a canonical New Keynesian model with housing and collateral constraints that using the loan-to-value (LTV) ratio, tax on credit or tax on property as additional policy instruments does not resolve the inflation-output volatility tradeoff. Perfect targeting of inflation and credit with monetary and macroprudential policy is possible only if the role of housing debt in the economy is sufficiently small. The identified limits to the considered policies are related to their predominantly intertemporal impact on decisions made by financially constrained agents, making them poor complements to monetary policy, which also operates at an intertemporal margin. These limits can be overcome if macroprudential policy is instead designed such that it sufficiently redistributes income between savers and borrowers.
A.1 Model equations
In this section of the Appendix we present a full list of equations making up the benchmark NK macrofinancial model. The variables without time subscripts denote their steady state values.
Households
Euler equation for patient households
Impatient households’ budget constraint
Collateral constraint
Euler equations for impatient households
Rigid housing demand of patient households
Housing Euler equation for impatient households
Labor supply (for i = {I, P})
Labor aggregate
Firms
Marginal cost
Optimal price set by reoptimizing firms
Auxiliary functions for optimal price
Price indexes
Market Clearing
Goods market
Aggregate output
Price dispersion index
Housing market
A.2 Inflation and Output Targeting (Proof of Proposition 1)
We prove Proposition 1 by showing that stabilization of inflation and output at some exogenously moving targets using the short-term interest rate and any of the three macroprudential instruments (LTV ratio, tax on credit, and tax on new property) is inconsistent with the existence of stable rational expectations equilibrium.
Let us denote any linear function of current and past exogenous variables up to time t as exot. Formally,
First note that if output is at its target at all times, the market clearing condition (19) implies
If additionally inflation is at the target at all times, the Phillips curve implies
These two equations can be solved for
Using these results, one can show that the budget constraint of impatient households (12) can be reduced to
It is clear from this equation that credit is explosive in response to shocks if
Let us now assume instead that only transfers are used as an additional instrument to the interest rate. Then the Euler equation for impatient households (11) implies that
Plugging these results into the optimality condition for housing (14) yields
which uniquely determines a non-explosive path of credit
A.3 Inflation and Credit Targeting (Proof of Proposition 2)
We prove Proposition 2 by showing that perfect targeting of both inflation and credit using the short-term interest rate and any of the three macroprudential instruments (LTV ratio, tax on credit, and tax on new property) is consistent with the existence of stable rational expectations equilibrium only if the model parameters satisfy a certain restriction.
If inflation is at the target at all times, Eq. (20) implies
which allows us to express patient households’ consumption as a function of that of impatient ones and exogenous variables
where
Plugging this condition into the model equations and restricting credit to be at its exogenous target at all times leads to the following system of equations
where
Let us first assume that redistributive taxation is not available. Then, since both a and sc are strictly positive, equation (A.30) implies that, for a stable equilibrium to exist, we must have
Let us now work more on the formula for sc. First note that the steady state Euler equations (A.1) and (A.4), evaluated at the steady state, imply
This formula can be used to substitute for Θ in the housing Euler equation (A.6), which, after using the collateral constraint (A.3) to substitute for
Next note that the budget constraint of impatient households (A.2) evaluated at the steady state implies
Now we are ready to derive the formula for sc as a function of deep model parameters
Plugging this equation into condition
which is restriction (22) in the main text.
The condition derived above ensures that the policy rate
Finally, suppose that, instead of the three macroprudential instruments, we use redistributive taxes
where
Note that the determinant of Γ0 is
References
Alpanda, S., and S. Zubairy. 2016. “Housing and Tax Policy.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 48 (2–3): 485–512, https://doi.org/10.1111/jmcb.12307.Search in Google Scholar
Alpanda, S., and S. Zubairy. 2017. “Addressing Household Indebtedness: Monetary, Fiscal or Macroprudential Policy?.” European Economic Review 92 (C): 47–73, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2016.11.004.Search in Google Scholar
Angeloni, I., and E. Faia. 2013. “Capital Regulation and Monetary Policy with Fragile Banks.” Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (3): 311–24, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2013.01.003.Search in Google Scholar
BCBS. 2010. Guidance for National Authorities Operating The Countercyclical Capital Buffer. Technical Report. Basel: Basel Committee on Banking Supervision.Search in Google Scholar
Benigno, P., and M. Woodford. 2012. “Linear-Quadratic Approximation of Optimal Policy Problems.” Journal of Economic Theory 147 (1): 1–42, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jet.2011.10.012.Search in Google Scholar
Benigno, G., H. Chen, C. Otrok, A. Rebucci, and E. R. Young. 2013. “Financial Crises and Macro-Prudential Policies.” Journal of International Economics 89 (2): 453–70, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2012.06.002.Search in Google Scholar
Benigno, P., G. B. Eggertsson, and F. Romei. 2014. “Dynamic Debt Deleveraging and Optimal Monetary Policy.” Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. NBER Working Papers 20556.10.3386/w20556Search in Google Scholar
Bernanke, B. S., and M. Gertler. 2001. “Should Central Banks Respond to Movements in Asset Prices?.” American Economic Review 91 (2): 253–7, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.91.2.253.Search in Google Scholar
Bianchi, J., and E. G. Mendoza. 2018. “Optimal Time-Consistent Macroprudential Policy.” Journal of Political Economy 126 (2): 588–634, https://doi.org/10.1086/696280.Search in Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. J., and C. M. Kahn. 1980. “The Solution of Linear Difference Models under Rational Expectations.” Econometrica 48 (5): 1305–11, https://doi.org/10.2307/1912186.Search in Google Scholar
Bluwstein, K., M. Brzoza-Brzezina, P. Gelain, and M. Kolasa. 2020. “Multi-period loans, occasionally binding constraints and monetary policy: A quantitative evaluation.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. https://doi.org/10.1111/jmcb.12689.10.2139/ssrn.3230122Search in Google Scholar
Bodenstein, M., L. Guerrieri, and J. LaBriola. 2014. “Macroeconomic Policy Games.” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2014-87. Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.), September.10.17016/FEDS.2014.87Search in Google Scholar
Brunnermeier, M. K., and Y. Sannikov. 2014. “A Macroeconomic Model with a Financial Sector.” American Economic Review 104 (2): 379–421, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.2.379.Search in Google Scholar
Brzoza-Brzezina, M., M. Kolasa, and K. Makarski. 2015. “Macroprudential Policy and Imbalances in the Euro Area.” Journal of International Money and Finance 51: 137–54, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2014.10.004.Search in Google Scholar
Campbell, J. R., and Z. V. I. Hercowitz. 2009. “Welfare Implications of the Transition to High Household Debt.” Journal of Monetary Economics 56 (1): 1–16, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2008.09.002.Search in Google Scholar
Carlstrom, C. T., and T. Fuerst. 2007. “Asset Prices, Nominal Rigidities, and Monetary Policy.” Review of Economic Dynamics 10 (2): 256–75, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.red.2006.11.005.Search in Google Scholar
Cecchetti, S. G., and M. Kohler. 2014. “When Capital Adequacy and Interest Rate Policy Are Substitutes (And When They Are Not).” International Journal of Central Banking 10 (3): 205–31.Search in Google Scholar
Christiano, L. J., C. Ilut, R. Motto, and M. Rostagno. 2010. “Monetary policy and stock market booms.” In Proceedings – Economic Policy Symposium – Jackson Hole, 85–145. Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.10.3386/w16402Search in Google Scholar
Clement, P. 2010. The Term “Macroprudential”: Origins and Evolution. Basel: Bank for International Settlements. BIS Quarterly Review March.Search in Google Scholar
Cúrdia, V., and M. Woodford. 2009. Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Basel: Bank for International Settlements. BIS Working Papers 278 March.10.3386/w15289Search in Google Scholar
Darracq Pariés, M., C. K. Sorensen, and D. Rodriguez-Palenzuela. 2011. “Macroeconomic propagation under different regulatory regimes: Evidence from an estimated DSGE model for the euro area.” International Journal of Central Banking 7 (4): 49–113.10.2139/ssrn.1682085Search in Google Scholar
De Paoli, B., and M. Paustian. 2017. “Coordinating Monetary and Macroprudential Policies.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 49 (2–3), 319–49, https://doi.org/10.1111/jmcb.12381.Search in Google Scholar
Dixit, A., and L. Lambertini. 2003. “Interactions of Commitment and Discretion in Monetary and Fiscal Policies.” American Economic Review 93 (5): 1522–42, https://doi.org/10.1257/000282803322655428.Search in Google Scholar
Faia, E., and T. Monacelli. 2007. “Optimal interest rate rules, asset prices, and credit frictions.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 31 (10): 3228–54, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2006.11.006.Search in Google Scholar
Galati, G., and R. Moessner. 2013. “Macroprudential Policy: A Literature Review.” Journal of Economic Surveys 27 (5): 846–78.10.1111/j.1467-6419.2012.00729.xSearch in Google Scholar
Garriga, C., F. E. Kydland, and R. Sustek. 2017. “Mortgages and Monetary Policy.” Review of Financial Studies 30 (10): 3337–75, https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhx043.Search in Google Scholar
Geanakoplos, J. 2010. “The Leverage Cycle.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2009, NBER Chapters, 1–65. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.10.1086/648285Search in Google Scholar
Gertler, M., J. Gali, and R. Clarida. 1999. “The Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspective.” Journal of Economic Literature 37 (4): 1661–707.10.1257/jel.37.4.1661Search in Google Scholar
Guerrieri, L., and M. Iacoviello. 2017. “Collateral constraints and macroeconomic asymmetries.” Journal of Monetary Economics 90 (C): 28–49, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2017.06.004.Search in Google Scholar
Holbrook, R. S. 1972. “Optimal Economic Policy and the Problem of Instrument Instability.” American Economic Review 62 (1): 57–65.Search in Google Scholar
Hong Kong Monetary Authority. 2011. Loan-to-Value Ratio as a Macroprudential Tool – Hong Kong SAR’s Experience and Cross-Country Evidence. Basel: Bank for International Settlements. BIS Papers 57.10.2139/ssrn.1768546Search in Google Scholar
Iacoviello, M. 2005. “House Prices, Borrowing Constraints, and Monetary Policy in the Business Cycle.” American Economic Review 95 (3): 739–64, https://doi.org/10.1257/0002828054201477.Search in Google Scholar
IMF. 2011. Macroprudential Policy: An Organizing Framework. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Staff Background Paper.10.5089/9781498339179.007Search in Google Scholar
Jeanne, O., and A. Korinek. 2010. “Excessive Volatility in Capital Flows: A Pigouvian Taxation Approach.” American Economic Review 100 (2): 403–07, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.2.403.Search in Google Scholar
Justiniano, A., G. E. Primiceri, and A. Tambalotti. 2019. “Credit Supply and the Housing Boom.” Journal of Political Economy 127 (3): 1317–50, https://doi.org/10.1086/701440.Search in Google Scholar
Kim, C. 2014. “Macroprudential Policies in Korea: Key measures and Experiences.” In Financial Stability Review, Paris: Banque de France.Search in Google Scholar
Lambertini, L., C. Mendicino, and M. Teresa Punzi. 2013. “Leaning against boom-bust cycles in credit and housing prices.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37 (8): 1500–22, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2013.03.008.Search in Google Scholar
Lane, T. D. 1984. “Instrument Instability and Short-Term Monetary Control.” Journal of Monetary Economics 14 (2): 209–24. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(84)90060-6.Search in Google Scholar
Leduc, S., and J. M. Natal. 2018. “Monetary and Macroprudential Policies in a Leveraged Economy.” Economic Journal 128 (609): 797–826, https://doi.org/10.1111/ecoj.12452.Search in Google Scholar
Notarpietro, A., and S. Siviero. 2015. “Optimal monetary policy rules and house prices: The role of financial frictions.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 47 (1): 383–410, https://doi.org/10.1111/jmcb.12208.Search in Google Scholar
Quint, D., and P. Rabanal. 2014. “Monetary and Macroprudential Policy in an Estimated DSGE Model of the Euro Area.” International Journal of Central Banking 10 (2): 169–236.10.5089/9781484333693.001Search in Google Scholar
Rubio, M., and J. A. Carrasco-Gallego. 2016. “The new financial regulation in Basel III and monetary policy: A macroprudential approach.” Journal of Financial Stability 26 (C): 294–305, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2016.07.012.Search in Google Scholar
Schmitt-Grohe, S., and M. Uribe. 2004. “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy under Sticky Prices.” Journal of Economic Theory 114 (2): 198–230, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0022-0531(03)00111-x.Search in Google Scholar
Siu, H. E. 2004. “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy with Sticky Prices.” Journal of Monetary Economics 51 (3): 575–607, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2003.07.008.Search in Google Scholar
Woodford, M. 2003. Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400830169Search in Google Scholar
© 2020 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston