Skip to content
Publicly Available Published by De Gruyter May 27, 2016

University Competition and Transnational Education: The Choice of Branch Campus

  • Joanna Poyago-Theotoky and Alessandro Tampieri EMAIL logo

Abstract

We present a theoretical framework in which an elitist and a non-elitist university in a developed country compete by choosing admission standards and deciding whether or not to open a branch campus in a developing country. Students from a developing country attend university if either a branch campus is opened or, they can afford to move to the developed country. We find that the elitist university is more likely to open a branch campus. This result is reversed if the gain, in terms of prestige, to attend the home campus of the elitist university more than offsets a student’s mobility costs. A rise in the graduate wage increases the incentive for opening a branch campus, although this incentive is stronger for the elitist university.

JEL: I23; L13; F23

1 Introduction

A rapidly growing number of universities across the world are engaging in transnational education activities by establishing branch campuses in other countries. Transnational education is defined as arrangements in which courses or degree programmes offered by an institution in one country are delivered to students located in a different country (Ziguras 2003).

The evidence shows that the international branch campus market has become more competitive. Higher education institutions from 22 countries have established branch campuses abroad compared with 17 countries in 2006. Most of these campuses (111 out of 162) were established by institutions in the Anglophone nations, the US continuing to overshadow all others with its 78 offshore bases accounting for 48 % of the total. The US is followed by Australia with 14 campuses, 9 % of the total number, the UK with 13 or 8 % of the total, and France and India each with 11. Several other countries, including Mexico with seven small campuses, the Netherlands with five, Malaysia with four and Canada and Ireland with three each, operate multiple branches abroad. Since 2006, institutions from five new source countries have established at least one overseas campus: these are Lebanon, Malaysia, South Korea, Sri Lanka and Switzerland (Becker 2009).

In the higher education economics literature, contributions on the effects of branch campuses are scarce, with few but notable exceptions. Lien (2006) analyses a university market in a developing country, with a domestic university and the branch campus of a foreign university. The domestic university provides education in both global knowledge (commonly accepted and being helpful for developing countries probably in the future) and local knowledge (being directly helpful for developing countries), whereas the branch campus specializes in global knowledge education only. Students have different learning ability in global knowledge (but not in local knowledge) and they choose which university to attend based upon the expected wages. If graduates from the branch campus have opportunities to work abroad and earn higher incomes, then an increase in the wage in the foreign country will lead to a reduction in local knowledge production. Lien (2008) extends Lien (2006) by considering different qualities of the branch campus. Finally, Lien and Wang (2010) examine student decisions in a developing country about whether to attend the local university or study abroad. All these papers focus on the effects of a branch campus on the question of brain drain on the developing country and treat the decision to open a branch campus as exogenous and not determined in equilibrium. Further, there is no university competition, in the sense that universities do not act strategically.

The growing importance of transnational education activities, such as the establishment of branch campuses, and its role in competition among universities appears not to have been investigated thoroughly in the literature. This is the main objective of the present paper. The paper is also related to the literature on spatial competition among universities (Del Rey 2001; De Fraja and Iossa 2002; Cesri and Paolini 2013; Carroni, Cesi and Paolini 2015). In particular, the modelling framework borrows some elements from the analysis of university competition of De Fraja and Iossa (2002). [1]

To the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper to analyse the decision of investing in a branch campus within a competitive environment. In a simple stylised model, two universities operating in a developed country compete by choosing their admission standards and deciding whether or not to open a branch campus in a developing country. We show that one of the two universities is “elitist”, in the sense that it sets its admission standard higher than its competitor. A student who is admitted to university will graduate with certainty and will obtain a higher income in the job market. Students from a developing country can attend university if a branch campus is opened or if they are “privileged”, i. e. they can borrow money (from the family or the financial sector) to move to the developed country. So students decisions’ depend on travel costs and their borrowing constraints while university decisions depend on the fixed investment costs of opening the branch campus and their revenues.

We investigate the relationship between investment costs and graduate wages. Very high investment costs discourage the opening of a branch campus. An increase in the graduate wage increases the incentive for opening a branch campus, although the incentive is stronger for the elitist than the non-elitist university. This is due to the fact that students prefer to attend the elitist university, so that the demand for higher education is filled from the elitist university and the non-elitist university covers the remainder. Therefore three possible equilibria emerge: (i) no branch campus is established, (ii) one branch campus is opened by the elitist university only and (iii) each university opens a branch campus. Surprisingly, an increase in the proportion of privileged students increases the chance of an equilibrium of type (ii) to the detriment of equilibrium (i). Indeed, the presence of more privileged students entails that opening a branch campus is less profitable (in the limit case where all students are privileged, there is no incentive at all since all students are able to move to the main campus), so one would expect that the university who gains the most from opening a branch campus will do it with lower probability. The intuition is the following: an increase in privileged students reduces the demand for university from students who stay in the developing country. The non-elitist university suffers from the fall in the demand relatively more than the elitist university, given the higher benefit from the latter from opening a branch campus.

We also examine the case where a “top university” competes with a non-elitist university. The top university sets a higher admission standard than the non-elitist university. In addition, the gain in terms of prestige and reputation in attending the home campus of a top university more than offsets mobility costs – this is the defining characteristic for a top university in this context. This of course affects the demand for attending the home campus of the top university, which remains high even if a branch campus is opened. In other words, if a student from a developing country can afford it, she will attend the home campus of a top university irrespective of the university choice of branch campus. The strict preference towards the home campus of top universities is in line with empirical evidence showing a large number of international students attending prestigious American and British Universities, even when these insitutions open a branch campus. In this case, the results strictly depend on the proportion of privileged students. For a low proportion, the results are qualitatively similar to the baseline case. However, when the proportion of privileged students is high, the market configuration in equilibrium exhibits the opening of a branch campus by the non-elitist university only.

The remainder of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 presents the modelling framework and provides the equilibrium analysis for the baseline case (Sections 2.12.5). Section 2.6 considers a market with a top university and a non-elitist university. Section 3 provides some brief concluding remarks.

2 The Model

Consider a large population of potential students that is evenly distributed in two countries, 1 and 2. In each country the number of students is normalised to one. Country 1 can be thought of as a “developed” country. In Country 1 two universities, denoted by A and B, are established. Country 2 can be thought as a “developing” country, and we assume that there are no local universities. [2] However, university A and B may decide to open a branch campus (from now on, BC) in Country 2. The timing of the interaction between students and universities is modelled as a two-stage game where in stage 1 universities decide whether to open a branch campus and in stage 2 universities set admission standards while students choose which university/campus to enrol in. [3]

2.1 Universities

Following De Fraja and Iossa (2002), the objective function of a university, i,i=A,B, is written as:

[1]Wni,Ri,ΘiΦi,

where W captures the three elements that a university bureaucracy [4] cares about:

  1. the number of enrolling students ni, where

    ni={ni1+ni2ifaBCisopenedni1ifnoBCisopened

  1. the quality of the student body Θi (i. e. average ability of students attending i), and

  2. the expenditure on research Ri,

while

Φi={FifaBCisopened0ifnoBCisopened

are the fixed costs associated with opening a branch campus. The first partial derivatives of W in eq. [1] are all positive, and Wnn,WRR,WΘΘ<0, and that the second cross derivatives are sufficiently small so that the relevant second-order conditions are satisfied. This implies that W is approximately separable.

Each university has a budget determined by the amount of tuition fees collected from the enrolled students, fni, where f>0 represents the fees per student. Tuition fees f are set exogenously: universities are not free to choose what students are charged in fees. [5] Therefore, each university:

  1. decides whether or not to open a BC in Country 2 at a fixed cost F>0; and

  2. chooses the required standard necessary to admit a student in each location/campus. We denote this by xijx_ij,1,i=A,B,j=1,2, where x_ij>0 is the lowest possible admission standard. This implies that only students who reach at least standard xij are accepted at institution i with campus in Country j.

Further, suppose that teaching ni students carries a cost of

Cni={cn1+cn2ifaBCisopenedcn1ifnoBCisopened,

with c'(nj)>0, c''(nj)0,j1,2 and limn1c'(nj)=+. Thus the teaching cost is considered separately for each university site. This assumption represents better a university technology in the real world: the costs are increasing and convex within each campus, due to the number of staff, classroom size, equipment, laboratories, and so on.

2.2 Students

Students differ in ability, denoted by θ0,1. In each country, students’ distribution by ability is Gθ, with G0=0,G1=1 and density g(θ)=G'(θ). The admission standard set by a university, xij, is in the same support as ability, so that xij0,1 and xij=θij where θij is the lowest ability student that can be accepted by university i in Country j. [6] If a student attends university, she graduates with certainty at the end of the university period. Still with certainty, in the labour market she will receive a wage surplus for being a graduate (“graduate wage”) Sxij, depending on the university admission threshold xij. Effectively the wage surplus captures the peer effects at university: the higher the admission standard, the smarter the people a student interacts with Del Rey (2001), De Fraja and Iossa (2002) and Cesi and Paolini (2014). To put it simply, being with smart people makes you smarter.

A student’s payoff function (if attending university) depends on her ability θ, the admission standard, xij, the tuition fee, f and the mobility cost T:

Sxij+θfT,

where Uxij,θ=Sxij+θ is a student’s utility with S'(xij)>0, and

T={tifastudentmovestoattenduniversity0ifastudentdoesnotmove.

For the sake of simplicity, we assume Sx_ij>f. In other words, the lowest possible graduate wage is higher than tuition fees. This ensures that every student is willing to attend university irrespective of f. A possible interpretation is that a government agency designs tuition fees in order to give incentives to the largest number of students to attend university. This assumption simplifies the analysis as f does not play any role in determining the demand function of students, but only determines a university’s budget.

To simplify the analysis, all students from Country 1 attend university in Country 1, even if at least one BC is present in Country 2. [7] On the other hand, in Country 2 there is an exogenous number of students β0,1, denoted as “privileged” who can borrow, either from their family or the banking system, the amount of money to cover the mobility costs t. β is independent of a student’s level of ability.

A student who does not attend university has a reservation utility of U0,0<Uxij,θ, for all xijx_ij,1, so that a student from the developed country would surely attend university if admitted. A student from the developing country would surely attend university if admitted and either

  1. there is a BC, or

  2. there is no BC but she belongs to the group of privileged students and Uxij,θft.

The next definition is convenient.

Definition 1:

Lettdenote the cost of moving to Country 1 such that

UxA1,θt=UxB2,θ.

2.3 Students’ Admission and University Attendance

In this section we establish university attendance which depends on the admission standard/threshold set by each university. Using [1] we rewrite the payoff functions of the two universities as

[2]πi(xAj,xBj)=WnixAj,xBj,fnixAj,xBjcnixAj,xBj,ΘixAj,xBjΦi,

where nixAj,xBj and ΘixAj,xBj are the number of students admitted and the average quality of students at university i,i=A,B, respectively, given the admission standards xAj,xBj for locations j=1,2. Notice that we have replaced research expenditure Ri with Ri=fnixAj,xBjcnixAj,xBj, i. e. the difference between total revenue from tuition fees and teaching costs.

It is clear that Θi/xij>0: an increase in a university’s admission standard increases the average ability of that university’s students. According to the timing of the game, universities set their admission standards following their decision on the opening (or not) of a branch campus. Therefore there are four distinct possibilities, depending on the first-stage subgames:

  1. Neither university opens a branch campus, hence the relevant standards to set are xA1 and xB1.

  2. University A opens a branch campus; the standards to be set are xA1, xA2 and xB1.

  3. University B opens a branch campus; the standards to be set are xA1, xB1 and xB2.

  4. Both universities open a branch campus; the relevant standards are xA1, xA2, xB1 and xB2.

A natural question arising here is whether the standards chosen will be symmetric, meaning that the universities set the same admission standards, or asymmetric, where universities choose different admission standards. A preliminary result is the following.

Lemma 1:

Symmetric standards cannot be part of an equilibrium with positive student demand.

Proof

See Appendix A.1. ■

Lemma 1 establishes that an equilibrium requires setting different admission standards.

In relation to subgame 4 (see above) we clarify that one can distinguish the following possibilities: (a) University A sets a higher standard in both countries, (b) University B sets a higher standard in both countries, (c) University A sets a higher standard in country 1, (d) University A sets a higher standard in Country 2. Cases (a) and (b) and cases (c) and (d) are clearly specular. In what follows, we focus on equilibria where university A sets the higher standard in every country in which it operates, and we call university A “elitist”. [8] We therefore state,

Assumption 1:

xAj>xBj.

The following propositions describe university attendance of students from Country 1 and 2, respectively.

Proposition 1:

Consider students living in Country 1. Let universityiA,Bset standardxi1, and Assumption 1 hold. A student attends universityAifθxA1,1and universityBifθxB1,xA1.

Proof

See the Appendix A.2. ■

The next proposition establishes university attendance of students from Country 2. For these students, university attendance depends on (i) whether or not one or two branch campuses are opened, and (ii), in the case where only university B opens a branch campus, whether t is greater or not than t (see Definition 1). Indeed, a student with high ability may be admitted to university A, but the mobility costs are high so that the student may prefer to attend the branch campus of university B. The equivalent of Proposition 1 for students of Country 2 follows.

Proposition 2:

Consider students living in Country 2. Let universityiA,Bset standardxijin their site in CountryjwithxAj>xBj(assumption 1).

  1. No BC: a student attends university if she is privileged: in particular, university A if θxA1,1 and university B if θxB1,xA1.

  2. UniversityAoperates BC: a student attends university A if θxA2,1 and university B if privileged and θxB1,xA1.

  3. UniversitiesAandBoperate BC: a student attends university A if θxA2,1 and university B if θxB2,xA2.

  4. UniversityBoperates BC, andtt: a student attends university A if privileged and θxA1,1 and university B either if non-privileged and θxA1,1 or, if not privileged and θxB2,xA1.

  5. UniversityBoperates BC, andt>t: a student never attends university A, and attends university B if θxB2,1.

Propositions 1 and 2 allow us to simplify the interaction between universities and students so that, in the first stage, the strategy space is binary, and consists of the decision of whether to open (or not) a branch campus in country 2 and in the second stage, the strategy space is given by the admission standards, xAj,xBj[0,1]. The equilibrium concept is subgame perfect equilibrium by backward induction. Figure 1 depicts the timing of the game.

Figure 1: The simplified game.
Figure 1:

The simplified game.

To make further progress and obtain explicit closed-form solutions for the remainder of the paper we specify the functional relationships as follows:

[3]U(xij,θ)=wxij+θ,
[4]Wni,Ri,Θi=jnijwxij+fcnij,
[5]cnij=cjnij2,
[6]G(θ)=θ,

where Sxij=wxij,w>0 is a graduate’s wage. The specifications chosen (eqs [3], [4], [5] and [6]) respect the properties of the associated general functions. In particular, note that the average ability of students increases with xij. Finally, assuming a uniform distribution for ability is standard in the literature of university competition (Del Rey, 2001; De Fraja and Iossa, 2002; Cesi and Paolini, 2013 and Carroni, Cesi and Paolini 2015).

2.4 Admission Standards

The following Lemma 2 shows the number of admitted students and is a direct consequence of Propositions 1 and 2.

Lemma 2:

Let Assumption 1 hold. Then the number of students being admitted to each university is:

nA={1+β1xA1noBC1xA1+1xA2ABC1+β1xA1BBC,AnoBCfortt1xA1BBC,AnoBCfort>t1xA1+1xA2B,A,BC,nB={1+βxA1xB1noBCxA1xB1+βxA12xB1ABCj1,2xAjxBjAandB,BC1+βxA1xB1+1β1xB2BBC,AnoBCandttxA1xB1+1xB2BBC,AnoBCandt>t.

Thus a university’s problem in the second stage is given by

maxxijjnijwxij+fcnijΦi.

where j=1 if a university does not open a BC and j=1,2, if a BC is opened. Thus the admission standard in equilibrium is denoted by xij=argmaxπixij. The four possible solutions (according to which university opens the BC) are xANN;xBNN,xAFN;xBFN,xANF;xBNF and xANN;xBNN is given by eqs [12], [14], [18] and [16], respectively, in Appendix A.1. Superscript NN indicates that none of the universities opens a BC, superscript FN denotes that university A opens a BC and university B does not. Conversely, superscript NF says that university A does not open a BC but university B does. Finally, superscript FF indicates that both universities open a BC.

Based on these results for the case where University B opens a BC and University A does not, Lemma 3 below provides the critical value for mobility cost t that determines whether a student from country 2 will attend country 1 or not (see Definition 1).

Lemma 3:

Suppose that UniversityBopens a BC while UniversityAdoes not. Then, a student from Country2with ability at leastθA=xAwould either attend universityAin Country1for alltt, or attend the BC of universityBfor allt>t,where

twcβw+f2w+cw+c1+β.
Proof

See Appendix A.4. ■

Notice that university A (B) prefers wxAt>wxB, as shown by:

πA1NFπA2NF=βww+f4w+cw+c1+β>0,

and

πB1NFπB2NF=βw2w+fw24β+2wc5+β+c26+4β16w+c2w+2c<0.

2.5 Investment in BC

In the first stage, each university decides whether to open a BC according to the competitor’s strategy. For brevity, we focus on the case where tt. [9] The following table shows the payoff matrix according to whether university A and B decide to invest in a BC.

University B
BCN
University ABCπAFF;πBFFπAFN;πBFN
NπANF;πBNFπANN;πBNN

The full derivation of πANN;πBNN,πAFN;πBFN,πANF;πBNF and πANN;πBNN is given by eqs [13], [15], [19] and [17], respectively, in Appendix A.1. This allows us to compare profits in every scenario and to find the equilibria in the decision of opening a BC. The subgame perfect equilibrium is therefore determined as the Nash equilibrium of the 2×2 payoff matrix above, according to values of the establishment (fixed) costs of opening a BC, F.

Begin by examining the strategy of university A according to university B decisions. If university B plays BC, university A would do the same for πA1FF>πA1NF, whereas if university B plays N, university A would play BC for πA1FN>πA1NN. Both these inequalities hold for all:

F<FAw+f2w1β+c1+β4w+cw+c1+β,

so that A has a dominant strategy: for F<FA it plays BC and for F>FA it plays N. Invoking dominance, we now turn to the behaviour of university B. For F<FA university A plays BC so that university B would also play BC when πB1FF>πB1FN, which occurs for all:

F<FˆBw+f2w+2c2w1β+c1+β16w+c3w+c1+β,

and would play N if F>FˆB. For F>FA university A plays N so that university B would play BC for πB1NF>πB1NN, which occurs for:

F<FBw34β1β+cw212β211βw+f216w+cw+c1+β3+4wc232β21+β2+4c31+β3w+f216w+cw+c1+β3

and would play N for F>FB.

Notice that the chain of inequalities for the threshold levels is FA>FB>FˆB. Therefore, in conjunction with the preceding discussion, we establish the following proposition, which is one of the main results of this paper. [10]

Proposition 3:

Letwxij>tfor alliA,B,j1,2andtt. For all:

  1. F>FA, neither university opens a BC, the equilibrium is [N;N] (type 1);

  2. FA>F>FˆB, universityAopens aBCand universityBdoes not, the equilibrium is [BC;N] (type 2);

  3. F<FˆB,both universities open a BC, the equilibrium is [BC;BC] (type 3).

Figure 2 illustrates these equilibria for combination between the investment cost F and the graduate wage w, for given β and c. Also, notice that

|FAw=0=|FˆBw=0=f24c

university A gains more from the students’ qualification x than university B. Hence, the number of students n has relatively more importance in determining B’s profits. Students prefer to attend university A, so that the demand for higher education is filled from that institution, whereas university B serves only the remainder of the demand for higher education. Therefore university A has more incentives in investing in BC, given the same cost F.

Consider next how a variation in the share of privileged students may affect the equilibrium. Differentiating FAFˆB with respect to β yields:

βFAFˆB=w2w+f23w+4c16w+c2w+c1+β>0.
Corollary 1:

An increase in the number of privileged students increases the probability that universityAopens aBCwhile universityBdoes not (equilibrium [2]).

The result described in Corollary 1 can be explained as follows. A raise in the number of privileged students reduces the demand for university from students in the developing country. The non-elitist university is more affected by the fall in the demand relatively more than the elitist university, given the higher benefit from the latter from opening a branch campus.

Figure 2: Illustration of proposition 3.
Figure 2:

Illustration of proposition 3.

2.6 “Top” University

The analysis carried out so far aimed at stressing the importance of mobility costs in university interaction. This approach is relevant in many situations in which students’ decisions strongly depend on these costs. However, to highlight the role of mobility costs necessarily sets aside the role played by the prestige of attending the home campus of a top university. Indeed, there is substantial evidence suggesting that many students prefer to attend a top university even if the same institution opened a branch campus (for example, consider the proportion of Asian students in top American universities). In our framework, this corresponds to setting t<0 when attending university A. In words, the gain (in terms of reputation, extra salary independent of ability, and the like) for attending the home campus of a top university more than offsets the mobility costs for doing so. This section is devoted to explore this case.

Let us re-label University A as “top university”. As in the previous analysis, University A sets higher admission standards than University B. Moreover, denote tA<0 as the difference between mobility costs and the benefit of attending a top university. Nothing changes for University B, so that a student from the developing country who attends the home campus of University B still bears a cost of t>0. Lemma 2 changes as follows.

Lemma 4:

Let Assumption 1 hold, andtA<0. Then the number of students being admitted to each university is:

nA={1+β1xA1noBC1xA11+β+1xA21βABC1+β1xA1BBC1xA11+β+1xA21βB,A,BC,nB={1+βxA1xB1noBC1+βxA1xB1ABCxA1xB1+xA1xB1+1xA11βBBCxA1xB1+xA1xB1B,A,BC,

We solve the game following the previous structure. Equations [13], [20], [22] and [21] in Appendix A.2 are the equilibrium payoffs according to the decisions of opening a BC in the first stage. Using these results, we examine the investment decisions in BC in the first stage. We start by examining the strategy of university A according to university B decisions. If university B plays BC, university A would do the same for πA1FF>πA1NF, whereas if university B plays N, university A would play BC for πA1FN>πA1NN. Both inequalities hold for all:

F<FATop(1β)(f+w)24(c+w)4βc.

Consider next the strategy of university B. If university A plays BC, university B would do the same for πB1FF>πB1FN, which occurs for all:

F<FˆBTop(f+w)216(c+w)(c+wβc)2(βc+c+w)3×[4(β1)2(β+1)3c5+4β5+2β46β2+β+4c4w+(β+1)((β2)β(4β+17)+25)c3w2](β(β(3β11)15)+19)c2w3+(7β(2β+7))cw4(β1)w5.

If university A plays N, university B would play BC the same for πB1NF>πB1NN, which takes place for:

F<FBTop(f+w)24(β+1)3c34(β+1)2(2β3)c2w+(β11)β2+12cw2+(β4)(β1)w316(c+w)(βc+c+w)3

For the sake of tractability, we set w=c. The results depend on the proportion of privileged students, as summarised in the following lemma.

Lemma 5:

Let Assumption 1 hold, tA<0and denoteβˆ0.454andβ0.985. For

  1. β<βˆ, the chain of inequalities is FATop>FBTop>FˆBTop;

  2. βˆ<β<β, the chain of inequalities is FBTop>FATop>FˆBTop;

  3. β>β, the chain of inequalities is FBTop>FˆBTop>FATop.

Case [1] of Lemma 1 is qualitatively similar to the baseline model. When the proportion of privileged students is low, the top university has the same strategic behaviour of the elitist university. This is intuitive. Since a low proportion of students can afford to move to the developed country in order to attend the top university, the top university has an incentive in opening a BC.

The result changes for Cases [2] and [3] as follows.

Proposition 4:

Let Assumption 1 hold, tA<0andβˆ<β. For all:

  1. F>FBTop, neither university opens a BC, the equilibrium is [N;N];

  2. FBTop>F>FATop, university B opens a BC and university A does not, the equilibrium is [N;BC];

  3. F<FATop, both universities open a BC, the equilibrium is [BC;BC].

Proposition 4 identifies a case ([2]) where it is the non-elitist University B that opens a BC while the top university does not. This is in contrast to the baseline case of Proposition 3. This result is due to the large proportion of privileged students, who can afford to move to the developed country. In this case University A has little incentive in opening a BC.

3 Concluding Remarks

We have analysed competition among universities and its effect in opening a branch campus. Competition among universities from a developed country takes place by both setting admission standards and deciding whether or not to open a branch campus in a developing country. Students living in the developing country can attend university only if a branch campus is opened or if they can afford to move to the developed country. An increase in the graduate wage increases the incentives for opening a branch campus, although the incentive is stronger for the elitist than the non-elitist university. Three possible equilibria emerge: (i) no branch campus, when the investment costs are too high, (ii) a branch campus is opened by the elitist university only and (iii) two branch campuses. An increase in the proportion of privileged students increases the chance of an equilibrium of type (ii) to the detriment of equilibrium (i). By contrast, in the case of a “Top” university the branch campus is opened only by the non-elitist university; this latter result is driven by the proportion of “privileged” students.

The paper could be further enriched by considering different tuition fees between universities in the developing and developed country. Tuition fees are usually lower in the branch rather than the main campus. However, this extension would have complicated the analysis by not adding so much. Indeed, the difference in tuition fees can be captured by the mobility costs, so in effect is already captured by the analysis.

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Gianni De Fraja, Elena Del Rey, Simona Fabrizi, Francisco Martinez-Mora, Lynne Pepall, Pierre Picard, Sergey Popov, Dan Richards, the Editor Burkhard C. Schipper, two anonymous referees and seminar audiences at AMES 2014 (Taipei), EARIE 2014 (Milan), CNR 2015 (Rome) and PET 2015 (Luxembrourg) for helpful comments.

Appendix

A.1 A.1 Proof of Lemma 1

Begin by noting that, given the additive and separable nature of a university’s objective function (see expressions [7] and [8]), each admission standard is determined for each country separately, depending exclusively on the competitor’s response within that country. This allows us to focus on setting the admission standard in a single country.

Prior to doing this, we consider a useful benchmark case where there is only one university operating in country 1, say A. This monopolistic university could either operate a branch campus or not. In the absence of a BC, it sets standard x and for T=0 will admit nA1=2(1G(x)) students while for T=t it will admit nA1=(1+β)(1G(x)). The associated first-order conditions are:

[7]2(Wn()+fWR()WRc'())g(x)=WΘ()θx()
[8](1+β)(Wn()+fWR()WRc'())g(x)=WΘ()θx().

Denote the solutions to [7] and [8] as xm and xmT respectively. [11] With a BC, only the case T=t is relevant, the standards are x1 and x2, one for each campus location and the students admitted are nA1+nA2=(1G(x1))+(1G(x2)). The solutions to the relevant first-order conditions (not shown) yield standards xM1=xM2.

We now return to the question of symmetric standards and consider the case (1) in the main text (where no university opens a BC), in more detail. Suppose A and B choose symmetric standards, xA=xB=xm, in equilibrium and split evenly students’ demand; [12] any value of common admission standard different from xm necessarily violates the first-order condition (1) as A and B share the market and effectively act as a local monopoly. [13] We now show that one university, say B, has an incentive to deviate from the symmetric equilibrium. Suppose B sets xB=xmε, with ε>0 small. This deviation leads to a change in B’s payoff approximated by:

[9]ε×((Wn()+fWR()WR()c'())nB(xm,xm)xB|xB<xm+WΘ()θx())

where

nB(xm,xm)xB|xB<xm=limh0nB(xm,xm+h)nB(xm,xm)h

is the left partial derivative of nB(xm,xm). For xB<xm, nB(xm,xB)=2(G(xm)G(xB)), so that

nB(xm,xm)xB|xB<xm=limh02(G(xm)G(xm+h))h=2g(xm)

and [9] becomes

ε×(2(Wn()+fWR()WR()c'()g(xm)+WΘ()θx())

and using [7]:

εWΘ()θx()>0.

A small reduction in the standard increases B’s payoff, hence symmetric standards cannot be an equilibrium. This type of argument can also apply to the remaining cases (2), (3) and (4), noting that in the case where only one university opens a BC in country 2 it behaves as a local monopoly in the setting of the standard, while it still competes in country 1.

Finally, notice that there is an alternative possibility with B raising its standard by ε or more. If both universities keep raising their standards, they eventually reach a configuration where xA=xB=1, and no student is admitted. This outcome maximises the average quality of students, but minimises the total number of admitted students. Hence there is an incentive to deviate by lowering the standard to raise the number of admissions.

A.2 Proof of Proposition 1

The proposition follows directly from S'(xij)>0 and the discussion in the preceding section. The following lemma gives university attendance according to a student’s ability.

Lemma 6

Consider students living in Country 1. UniversityiA,Bsets standardxi1, andxA1>xB1.

  1. Let student with ability θA1 attend university A. Then all students with ability θ>θA1 also attend university A.

  2. Let student with ability θB1 attend university B. Then all students with ability θB1<θ<θA1 also attend university B.

This follows from the fact that a student with higher ability gains more from attendance at a university with a stricter admission test (Epple and Romano 1998; De Fraja and Iossa 2002). Proposition 1 is an immediate consequence of Lemma 6 and the characterization of a student’s ability.

A.3 Proof of Proposition 2

The following lemma is the equivalent of Lemma 6 for students of Country 2.

Lemma 7

Consider students living in Country 2. Let universityiA,Bset standardxijfor their site in CountryjwithxAj>xBj(assumption 1).

  1. No BC:

    1. Let a privileged student with ability θA1 attend university A. Then β students with ability θ>θA1 also attend university A.

    2. Let a privileged student with ability θB1 attend university B. Then β students with ability θB1<θ<θA1 also attend university B.

  2. UniversityAoperates BC:

    1. Let a student with ability θA2 attend university A. Then all students with ability θ>θA2 also attend university A.

    2. Let a privileged student with ability θB1 attend university B. Then β students with ability θB1<θ<θA1 also attend university B.

  3. UniversitiesAandBoperate BC:

    1. Let a student with ability θA2 attend university A. Then all students with ability θ>θA2 also attend university A.

    2. Let a student with ability θB2 attend university B. Then all students with ability θB2<θ<θA2 also attend university B.

  4. UniversityBoperates BC, andtt:

    1. Let a privileged student with ability θA1 attend university A. Then β students with ability θ>θA1 also attend university A.

    2. Let a student with ability θB2 attend university B. Then all students with ability θB2<θ<θA1 and 1β students with ability θ>θA1 also attend university B.

  5. UniversityBoperates BC, andt>t:

    1. No students from Country 2 attend university A.

    2. Let a student with ability θB2 attend university B. Then all students with ability θ>θB2 also attend university B.

Notice that, in the case in which university B is the only university to open a BC and tt (part 4 in proposition 2 above), students with ability at least θA1 attend university A only if they are privileged. If they are not, they will attend the BC of university B. Conversely, in the case in which university B operates a BC only and t>t, then none of the students of ability at least θA1 from Country 2 will attend university A, since the increase in utility from attending university A is more than offset by the mobility costs.

A.4 Proof of Lemma 3

Proof

A student in Country 2 with ability equal or greater than θA is indifferent between moving to Country 1 to attend university A and attending the BC of university B if

wxA1NFttt=wxB2NFt>t,

which occurs for

t=wcβw+f2w+cw+c1+β.

Finally, it is necessary to verify that indeed below t the condition

[10]wxA1NFttt>wxB2NFtt

holds and, accordingly, above t the condition

[11]wxA1NFt>tt<wxB2NFt>t

holds. Inequality [10] holds for all

t<t˜wβw+fw+4c4w+cw+c1+β,

whereas inequality [11] holds for all

t>tˆ0.

Finally, notice that tˆ<t<t˜, thus the threshold t satisfies the conditions [10] and [11] along the entire parameter range. ■

A.5 Calculations for Section 2.5 – Admission Standards and Payoffs

No BC: in the case where neither university A nor B open a BC, the first order conditions with respect to xA,xB are:

πAxA1=1+βw12xA1+21+βc1xA1=0,πBxB1=1+βwxA12xB1+21+βcxA1xB1=0.

Solving yields the admission thresholds in equilibrium:

[12]xA1NN=w+2c1+βf2w+c1+β,xB1NN=ww3f+4c21+β2+4cwf1+β4w+c1+β2,

and the universities payoffs are:

[13]πANN=(w+f)2(1+β)4[w+c(1+β)],πBNN=(w+f)2[w+2c(1+β)]2(1+β)16[w+c(1+β)]3.

Notice that

xA1NNxB1NN=w+fwf+2c1+β4w+c1+β2>0.

UniversityABC: if university A opens a BC but not university B, the first order conditions with respect to xA,xB yield:

πAxA1=w+2c1xA1wxA1f=0,πAxA2=w+2c1xA2wxA2f=0,πBxB1=1+βw+2c1+βxA1xB1wxB1f=0.

The admission threshold in equilibrium is then:

[14]xA1FN=xA2FN=w+2cf2(w+c),xB1FN=w(w3f)+4c2(1+β)+2c(wf)(2+β)4[w+c(1+β)]2.

Thus the universities profits are:

[15]πAFN=(w+f)22(w+c)F,πBFN=(w+f)2(w+2c)2(1+β)16(w+c)2[w+c(1+β)].

Notice that

xA1FNxB1FN=w+fw+2c4w+cw+c1+β>0.

UniversityAandBBC: if both universities open a BC, the first order conditions with respect to xA,xB are:

πAxA1=w+2c1xA1wxA1f=0,πAxA2=w+2c1xA2wxA2f=0,πBxB1=w+2cxA1xB1wxB1f=0.πBxB2=w+2cxA2xB2wxB2f=0.

The admission threshold in equilibrium is:

[16]xA1FF=xA2FF=w+2cf2(w+2c),xB1FF=xB2FF=(w+2c)2f(3w+4c)4(w+c)2,

where the superscript indicates that both universities invest in BC. Therefore the universities payoffs are:

[17]πAFF=(w+f)22(w+c)F,πBFF=(w+2c)2(w+f)28(w+2c)3F.

Notice that

xA1FFxB1FF=w+fw+2c4w+c2>0.

UniversityBBC: as previously stated, in the case in which university B is the only one who opens a BC, then there are two possibilities according to whether tt. First we consider the case when tt, so that wxAtwxB (see Definition 1). According to Lemma 2 demands for university A and B are:

nA=1+β1xA1,nB=xA1xB1+1xA11β+xA1xB2.

The first order conditions with respect to xA1,xB1 and xB2 are:

πAxA1=1+βw+2c1+β1xA1wxA1f=0,πBxB1=w+2cxA1xB1wxB1f=0,πBxB2=w2c1β1xA1xB2wxB2f=0.

The admission thresholds in equilibrium are:

[18]xA1NF(tt)=w+2c(1+β)f2[w+c(1+β)],xB1NF(tt)=w(w3f)+4c2(1+β)+2c(wf)(2+β)4(w+c)[w+c(1+β)],xB2NF(tt)=4c2(1+β)w[f(2+β)w(2β)]+2c[3wf(1+2β)]4(w+c)[w+c(1+β)]

where the superscript indicates that university A did not invest in BC (N) and university B did (F). Therefore the universities payoffs are:

[19].9!πA1NF(tt)=(w+f)2(1+β)4[w+c(1+β)],πB1NF(tt)=(w+f)2[8c2(1+β)2+4wc(3β)(1+β)+w2(5β(4β))]16(w+c)[w+c(1+β)]F.

We then consider the case when wxA1t<wxB2 (i. e., t>t). In this case, the demands for university A and B are:

nA=1xA1,nB=xA1xB1+1xB1.

The first order conditions are:

πAxA1=w+2c1xA1wxA1f=0,πBxB1=w+2cxA1xB1wxB1f=0,πBxB2=w+2c1xB2wxB2f=0.

The admission thresholds in equilibrium are:

xA1NF(t>t)=w+2cf2(w+c),xB1NF(t>t)=(w+2c)f(3w+4c)8(w2+3wc+2c2),xB2NF(t>t)=w+2cf2(w+c),

and universities payoffs are:

πA2NF(t>t)=(w+f)4(w+c),πB2NF(t>t)=(w+f)2(5w2+12wc+8c2)16(w+c)3F

A.6 Calculations for Section 2.6 – “Top” University, Admission Standards and Payoffs

For brevity, we omit the derivation of the first order conditions. The case No BC is identical to the baseline case in Section 2.5, see expressions [12] and [13].

UniversityABC: if university A opens a BC but not university B, the admission threshold in equilibrium is:

xA1FN=w+2(β+1)cf2[w+c(1+β)]xA2FN=w+2(1β)cf2[w+c(1β)],xB1FN=4(1+β)2c2+4(β+1)c(wf)+w(w3f)4[w+c(1+β)]2.

Notice that

xA1FNxB1FN=(f+w)(2(β+1)c+w)4(βc+c+w)2>0,

and

xA1FNxA2FN=cβw+fw+c1+βw+c1β>0.

Unlike the baseline case, the admission requirements for the top university in the developed country are higher than in the developing country. The universities payoffs are:

[20]πAFN=[(w+2)w+1](c+w)β2c(1+w)22[(c+w)2β2c2]F,πBFN=(β+1)(f+w)2[2(β+1)c+w]216[w+c(1+β)]3.

UniversityAandBBC: if both universities open a BC, the admission thresholds in equilibrium are:

xA1FF=w+2(1+β)cf2[w+c(1+β)],xA2FF=w+2(1β)cf2[w+c(1β)],xB1FF=2(2+β)c(wf)+4(1+β)c2+w(w3f)4(c+w)[w+c(1+β)],xB2FF=2(2β)c(wf)+4(1β)c2+w(w3f)4(c+w)[w+c(1β)].

Notice that

xA1FFxB1FF=(w+1)w+2(1+β)c4(c+w)w+c1+β>0,xA2FFxB2FF=(w+1)w+2(1β)c4(c+w)w+c1β>0.

The universities payoffs are:

[21]πAFF=(f+w)2(w+cβ2c)2(c+w)22β2c2F,πBFF=(f+w)2[(c+w)2(2c+w)2+4β4c4β2c2(8c2+12cw+3w2)]8(c+w)[(c+w)2β2c2]2F.
UniversityBBC: The admission threshold in equilibrium is:
xA1NF=w+2(1+β)cf2[w+c(1+β)],xB1NF=2(β+2)c(wf)+4c2(1+β)+w(w3f)4(c+w)[w+c(1+β)],xB2NF=w[(2β)w(β+2)f]+4c2(1+β)+2c(3w2βff)4(c+w)[w+c(1+β)].

Notice that

xA1NFxB1NF=(w+f)w+2(β+1)c4w+cw+c1+β>0,

and

xB1NFxB2NF=(1β)(w+2c)(w+f)4w+cw+c1+β>0,

saying that University B sets higher admission standard in the home campus. Finally, the universities payoffs are:

[22]πA1NF=(1+β)(f+w)24[w+c(1+β)],πB1NF=(f+w)2[8(1+β)2c2+4(3β)(1+β)cw+(5(4β)β)w2]16(c+w)[w+c(1+β)]2F

References

Becker, R. 2009. “International Branch Campuses: Markets and Strategies”. Report of the Observatory on Borderless Higher Education.Search in Google Scholar

Carroni, E., B. Cesi, and D. Paolini. 2015. “Peer Group, Distance and Tuition Fees: When Widening University Participation is Still Better.” CRENOS working paper 06.Search in Google Scholar

Cesi, B., and D. Paolini. 2014. Peer Group and Distance: When Widening University Participation Is Better. University of Manchester: The Manchester School, 82:110–32.10.1111/manc.12049Search in Google Scholar

De Fraja, G., and E. Iossa. 2002. “Competition among Universities and the Emergence of the Elite Institution.” Bulletin of Economic Research 54:275–93.10.1111/1467-8586.00153Search in Google Scholar

Del Rey, E. 2001. “Teaching Versus Research: A Model of State University Competition.” Journal of Urban Economics 49:356–73.10.1006/juec.2000.2193Search in Google Scholar

Epple, D., and R. E. Romano. 1998. “Competition between Private and Public Schools, Vouchers and Peer-Group Effects.” American Economic Review 88:33–62.Search in Google Scholar

Lien, D. 2006. “Borderless Education and Domestic Program.” Education Economics 14:297–308.10.1080/09645290600777519Search in Google Scholar

Lien, D. 2008. “Economic Analysis of Transnational Education.” Education Economics 16:149–66.10.1080/09645290701273475Search in Google Scholar

Lien, D., and Y. Wang. 2010. “The Effects of a Branch Campus.” Education Economics 20:1–16.10.1080/09645292.2010.488488Search in Google Scholar

Pepall, L., and D. Richard. 2014. “Competition, Selectivity and Innovation in the Higher Educational Market,” Discussion Papers Series, Department of Economics, Tufts University 0782, Department of Economics, Tufts University.Search in Google Scholar

Ziguras, C. 2003. The Impact of the GATS on Transnational Tertiary Education: Comparing Experiences of New Zealand, Australia, Singapore and Malaysia. Australian Education Researcher 30:89–109.10.1007/BF03216799Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2016-5-27
Published in Print: 2016-6-1

©2016 by De Gruyter

Downloaded on 1.12.2023 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2015-0052/html
Scroll to top button