Abstract
Most of the economic models on basic income account just for pecuniary forms of work, i. e. “time spent making money”, in employment. This restriction is a drawback of these analyses and of the standard economic labor supply model itself. If one wants to understand the potential effects of basic income on individual and social welfare, one should not restrict observation to the pecuniary uses of time. The objective of this contribution is to rethink the meaning of work usually applied in economic models, based on contributions of other social scientists. This reassessment is undertaken through the development of a microeconomic model, which discusses the effects of basic income on time use and interprets work not just as a source of income, but also of non-pecuniary benefits. Further, we disentangle the usual work-leisure dichotomy in two other ones (paid and unpaid time/unpaid work and leisure).
Funding statement: This work was supported by the Funder Name: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung, Funder Id: 10.13039/501100004079, Grant Number: PhD scholarship for Ana Helena Palermo Kuss.
Appendix
A Derivation of first-order conditions (FOC) for the first decision
Insert equation (8) in eq. (7), then you will get:
Then make a monotonic transformation of this equation, taking the ln and get:
To find out which level of
Solving for
Moreover, to find out under which circumstances basic income
Then reorganize it and call this level of basic income, that would lead an individual to leave the labor market,
B Derivation of first-order conditions (FOC) for the second decision
Insert eq. (14) in eq. (13), and then you will get:
Then make a monotonic transformation of (30), taking the ln and get:
To find out which level of
Then, reorganize (32) so that
To get the optimized value for
References
Aboudi, R., Thon, D., & Zheng, M. (2014). Designing a basic income system with a social welfare function. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 16, 546–568. doi:https://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12074Search in Google Scholar
Aguiar, M., & Hurst, E. (2007). Measuring trends in leisure: The allocation of time over five decades. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 969–1006. doi:https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.122.3.969Search in Google Scholar
Aguiar, M. & Hurst, E. (2016). The macroeconomics of time allocation. Taylor, John B. & Harald Uhlig (Eds.), Handbook of macroeconomics (2, pp. 203–253). Amsterdamc : Elsevier10.1016/bs.hesmac.2016.06.004Search in Google Scholar
Aguiar, M., Hurst, E., & Karabarbounis, L. (2012). Recent developments in the economics of time use. Annual Review of Economics, 4, 373–397. doi:https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-111809-125129Search in Google Scholar
Altman, M. (2001). A behavioral model of labor supply: Casting some light into the black box of income-leisure choice. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 30, 199–219. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/S1053-5357(01)00099-3Search in Google Scholar
Andreoni, J., Payne, A. A., & Smith, S. (2013). Do grants to charities crowd out other income? Evidence from the UK. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.10.3386/w18998Search in Google Scholar
Anxo, D., Mencarini, L., Pailhé, A., Solaz, A., Tanturri, M. L., & Flood, L. (2011). Gender differences in time use over the life course in France, Italy, Sweden, and the US. Feminist Economics, 17, 159–195. doi:https://doi.org/10.1080/13545701.2011.582822Search in Google Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. (1995). Public economics in action: The basic income/flat tax proposal (Reprinted in paperback). The lindahl lectures. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Search in Google Scholar
Baker, J. (2008). All things considered, should feminists embrace basic income?. Basic Income Studies, 3. doi:https://doi.org/10.2202/1932-0183.1129Search in Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time. The Economic Journal, 75, 493. doi:https://doi.org/10.2307/2228949Search in Google Scholar
Bharat, S. E. W. A. (2014). A little more, how much it is … : piloting basic income transfers in Madhya Pradesh, India. Retrieved from https://unicef.in/Uploads/Publications/Resources/pub_doc83.pdfSearch in Google Scholar
Birnbaum, S. (2012). Basic Income Reconsidered. New York: Palgrave Macmillan US.10.1057/9781137015426Search in Google Scholar
Bruni, L., & Zamagni, S. (Eds.). (2015). Handbook on the economics of reciprocity and social enterprise (paperback ed.). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Search in Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (2001). Federalism, liberty, and the law. The collected works of James M. Buchanan:; Vol. 18. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Search in Google Scholar
Chiappori, P.-A., & Lewbel, A. (2015). Gary Becker’s A theory of the allocation of time. The Economic Journal, 125, 410–442. doi:https://doi.org/10.1111/ecoj.12157Search in Google Scholar
Clavet, N.-J., Duclos, J.-Y. & Lacroix, G. (2012). Fighting poverty: Assessing the effect of a guaranteed minimum income proposal in Québec. CIRANO Scientific Series, 36, 1–28.Search in Google Scholar
Colombino, U., Locatelli, M., Narazani, E., & O’Donoghue, C. (2010). Alternative basic income mechanisms: An evaluation exercise with a microeconometric model. Basic Income Studies, 5, 586. doi:https://doi.org/10.2202/1932-0183.1162Search in Google Scholar
Colombo, G., Schnabel, R., & Schubert, S. (2008). Basic income reform in Germany: A Microsimulation-AGE analysis. Unpublished. (August). Retrieved from http://www.aiel.it/Old/bacheca/BRESCIA/papers/colombo.pdfSearch in Google Scholar
Cooter, R. (2002). The strategic constitution (2. print., 1. paperback print). Princeton paperbacks. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press.Search in Google Scholar
Drakopoulos, S. A. (1994). Hierarchical choice in economics. Journal of Economic Surveys, 8, 133–153. doi: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6419.1994.tb00097.x10.1111/j.1467-6419.1994.tb00097.xSearch in Google Scholar
Elgarte, J. M. (2008). Basic income and the gendered division of labour. Basic Income Studies, 3. doi:https://doi.org/10.2202/1932-0183.113610.2202/1932-0183.1136Search in Google Scholar
Emrich, E. & Pierdzioch, C. (2015). Public goods, private consumption, and human-capital formation: On the economics of volunteer labour supply. Working Papers of the European Institute for Socioeconomics, 14, 1–27 .Search in Google Scholar
Enríquez, C. R. (2013). Should citizen’s income become a goal for feminism in Latin America?. Lo Vuolo, R. M. (Ed.), Exploring the basic income guarantee. Citizen’s income and welfare regimes in Latin America: From cash transfers to rights (187–209). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan10.1057/9781137077547.0013Search in Google Scholar
Enste, D. H. & Schneider, R. (2016). Bedingungsloses grundeinkommen: Vision, fiktion oder illusion? IW Policy Paper, 11, 1– 34 .Search in Google Scholar
Farzin, Y. H. (2009). The effect of non-pecuniary motivations on labor supply. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 49, 1236–1259. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2009.09.001Search in Google Scholar
Fitoussi, J.-P. (2008). The end of (economic) history. In G. Piga & L. Pecchi (Eds.), Revisiting keynes: Economic possibilities for our grandchildren (pp. 151–160). Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.10.7551/mitpress/9780262162494.003.0012Search in Google Scholar
Forget, E. L. (2011). The town with no poverty: The health effects of a Canadian guaranteed annual income field experiment. Canadian Public Policy, 37, 283–305. doi:https://doi.org/10.3138/cpp.37.3.283Search in Google Scholar
Gálvez-Muñoz, L., Rodríguez-Modroño, P., & Domínguez-Serrano, M. (2011). Work and time use by gender: A new clustering of European welfare systems. Feminist Economics, 17, 125–157. doi:https://doi.org/10.1080/13545701.2011.620975Search in Google Scholar
Gamel, C., Balsan, D., & Vero, J. (2006). The impact of basic income on the propensity to work. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 35, 476–497. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2005.11.025Search in Google Scholar
Gheaus, A. (2008). Basic income, gender justice and the costs of gender-symmetrical lifestyles. Basic Income Studies, 3, 1. doi:https://doi.org/10.2202/1932-0183.1134Search in Google Scholar
Gilroy, B. M., Heimann, A., & Schopf, M. (2013). Basic income and labour supply: The German case. Basic Income Studies, 8. doi:https://doi.org/10.1515/bis-2012-0009Search in Google Scholar
Gorz, A. (1990). Quem não tiver trabalho, também terá o que comer. Estudos Avançados, 4, 211–228. doi:https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-40141990000300012Search in Google Scholar
Haagh, L. (2011a). Basic income, social democracy and control over time. Policy & Politics, 39, 43–66. doi:https://doi.org/10.1332/030557311X546316Search in Google Scholar
Haagh, L. (2011b). Working life, well-being and welfare reform: Motivation and institutions revisited. World Development, 39, 450–473. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2010.08.014Search in Google Scholar
Haigner, S., Höchtl, W., Schneider, F. G., Wakolbinger, F., & Jenewein, S. (2012). Keep on working: Unconditional basic income in the lab. Basic Income Studies, 7. doi:https://doi.org/10.1515/1932-0183.1230Search in Google Scholar
Hamermesh, D. S. (2016). WHAT’S TO KNOW ABOUT TIME USE?. Journal of Economic Surveys, 30, 198–203. doi:https://doi.org/10.1111/joes.12107Search in Google Scholar
Haushofer, J., & Shapiro, J. (2016). The short-term impact of unconditional cash transfers to the poor: Experimental evidence from Kenya. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131, 1973–2042. doi:https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjw025Search in Google Scholar
Hirway, I., & Jose, S. (2011). Understanding women’s work using time-use statistics: The case of India. Feminist Economics, 17, 67–92. doi:https://doi.org/10.1080/13545701.2011.622289Search in Google Scholar
Hochschild, A. R., & Machung, A. (2015). The second shift: Working families and the revolution at home (8[th printing], revised and with a new afterword). New York: Penguin Books.Search in Google Scholar
Hoff, K., & Stiglitz, J. E. (2015). Striving for balance in economics: Towards a theory of the social determination of behavior. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.10.3386/w21823Search in Google Scholar
Horstschräer, J., Clauss, M., & Schnabel, R. (2010). An unconditional basic income in the family context - labor supply and distributional effects. SSRN Electronic Journal. Advance online publication. doi:https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1739721Search in Google Scholar
Jager, N. E. M., De, Graafland, J. J., & Gelauff, G. M. M. (1996). A negative income tax in a mini-welfare state: A simulation exercise with mimic. Journal of Policy Modeling, 18, 223–231. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/0161-8938(95)00066-6Search in Google Scholar
Jessen, R., Rostam-Afschar, D. & Steiner, V. (2015). Getting the poor to work: Three: Welfare increasing reforms for a busy Germany. SOEPpapers on Multidisciplinary Panel Data Research at DIW Berlin, 781, 1–39 .10.2139/ssrn.2648121Search in Google Scholar
Johnson, R. D. (2010). Extracting a revised labor supply theory from Becker’s model of the household. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 39, 241–250. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2009.10.011Search in Google Scholar
Jones, D., & Marinescu, I.E. (2018). The labor market impacts of universal and permanent cash transfers: Evidence from the alaska permanent fund. SSRN Electronic Journal, Advance online publication. doi:https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3118343Search in Google Scholar
Jongen, E., de Boer, H.-W. & Dekker, P. (2014). MICSIM - A behavioural microsimulation model for the analysis of tax-benefit reform in the Netherlands. CPB Background Document, 1–94 .Search in Google Scholar
Jordan, B. (2010). Basic income and social value. Basic Income Studies, 5. doi:https://doi.org/10.2202/1932-0183.1140Search in Google Scholar
Kaufman, B. E. (1989). Models of man in industrial relations research. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 43, 72. doi:https://doi.org/10.2307/2523209Search in Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (2010). Economic possibilities for our grandchildren. In J. M. Keynes (Ed.), Essays in Persuasion (pp. 321–332). London: Palgrave Macmillan UK. doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-59072-8_25Search in Google Scholar
Mann, Stefan (2013). “Work”? On utility in the market and in the unpaid sphere. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 45, 86–91. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2013.05.001.10.1016/j.socec.2013.05.001Search in Google Scholar
Marx, A., & Peeters, H. (2008). An unconditional basic income and labor supply: Results from a pilot study of lottery winners. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 37, 1636–1659. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2007.08.007Search in Google Scholar
Mideros, A., & O’Donoghue, C. (2015). The effect of unconditional cash transfers on adult labour supply: A unitary discrete choice model for the case of ecuador. Basic Income Studies, 10, 1255. doi:https://doi.org/10.1515/bis-2014-0016Search in Google Scholar
Musick, M. A., & Wilson, J. (2010). Volunteers: A social profile. Philanthropic and nonprofit studies. Bloomington: Indiana University Press. Retrieved from http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&scope=site&db=nlebk&db=nlabk&AN=220615Search in Google Scholar
Neumärker, K. J. B. (2017). Ordnungspolitik, neuer Ordoliberalismus und Mainstream Economics. WISU. (46), 830–840.Search in Google Scholar
Neumärker, K. J. B. (2018). Bedingungsloses Grundeinkommen aus ordnungspolitischer Sicht. Wisu, 47/3, 324–334 .Search in Google Scholar
Ohanian, L. E. (2008). Back to the future with keynes. In G. Piga & L. Pecchi (Eds.), Revisiting keynes: Economic possibilities for our grandchildren (pp. 105–115). Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.10.7551/mitpress/9780262162494.003.0007Search in Google Scholar
Palm, T. (2015). Neun Thesen zum Bedingungslosen Gundeinkommen: Überlegungen zu einem unterschätzen Konzept. Lehrstuhl Für Internationale Wirtschaftsbeziehungen. Policy Paper, 1, 1–15 .Search in Google Scholar
Pasma, C. (2010). Working through the work disincentive. Basic Income Studies, 5, 442. doi:https://doi.org/10.2202/1932-0183.1169Search in Google Scholar
Paulus, A. (2016). The antipoverty performance of universal and means-tested benefits with costly take-up. ImPRovE Working Paper, 16/12, 1– 34 .Search in Google Scholar
Pech, W. J. (2010). Behavioral economics and the basic income guarantee. Basic Income Studies, 5. doi:https://doi.org/10.2202/1932-0183.1167Search in Google Scholar
Rätzel, Steffen (2012). Labour Supply, Life Satisfaction, and the (Dis)Utility of Work. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 114(4), 1160–1181. doi: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9442.2012.01717.x.10.1111/j.1467-9442.2012.01717.xSearch in Google Scholar
Robeyns, I. (2001). Will a basic income do justice to women?. Analyse & Kritik, 23(1), 88–105.10.1515/auk-2001-0108Search in Google Scholar
Robeyns, I. (2008). Introduction: Revisiting the feminism and basic income debate. Basic Income Studies, 3. doi:https://doi.org/10.2202/1932-0183.1137Search in Google Scholar
Roy, K. & Ziemek, S. (2000). On the economics of volunteering. ZEF – Discussion Papers on Development Policy, 31, 1–57 .Search in Google Scholar
Salamon, L. M., Sokolowski, S. W., Haddock, M. A., & Tice, H. S. (2012). The state of global civil society and volunteering: Latest findings from the implementation of the UN nonprofit handbook. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Center for Civil Society Studies. Working Paper. 49.Search in Google Scholar
Scutella, R. (2004). Moves to a basic income-flat tax system in Australia: Implications for the distribution of income and supply of labour. Melbourne Institute Working Paper, 5, 1–32 .Search in Google Scholar
Sherman, Arie & Shavit, Tal (2013). The immaterial sustenance of work and leisure: A new look at the work–leisure model. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 46, 10–16. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2013.06.003.10.1016/j.socec.2013.06.003Search in Google Scholar
Skidelsky, R., & Skidelsky, E. (2013). How much is enough?: Money and the good life. London: Penguin.Search in Google Scholar
Spannagel, D. (2015). Das bedingungslose Grundeinkommen: Chancen und Risiken einer Entkoppelung von Einkommen und Arbeit. Wirtschafts- Und Sozialwissenschaftliches Institut (WSI) in Der Hans-Böckler-Stiftung. (24).Search in Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. (2008). Toward a general theory of consumerism: Reflections on keynes’s economic possibilities for our grandchildren. In G. Piga & L. Pecchi (Eds.), Revisiting keynes: Economic possibilities for our grandchildren (pp. 41–85). Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar
Tondani, D. (2009). Universal basic income and negative income tax: Two different ways of thinking redistribution. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 38, 246–255. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2008.10.006Search in Google Scholar
Van Parijs, P. (1997). Real freedom for all. Oxford: Oxford University Press10.1093/0198293577.001.0001Search in Google Scholar
Van Parijs, P. (2004). A basic income for all. In L. Groot (Ed.), Basic income, unemployment and compensatory justice (pp. 11–23). Boston, MA: Springer US. doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4020-2726-0_2Search in Google Scholar
Widerquist, K. (2013). Independence, propertylessness, and basic income. New York: Palgrave Macmillan US.10.1057/9781137313096Search in Google Scholar
Yunker, J. A. (2013). The basic income guarantee: A general equilibrium evaluation. Basic Income Studies, 8. doi:https://doi.org/10.1515/bis-2013-0014Search in Google Scholar
Zelleke, A. (2008). Institutionalizing the universal caretaker through a basic income?. Basic Income Studies, 3. doi:https://doi.org/10.2202/1932-0183.1133Search in Google Scholar
Zilibotti, F. (2008). Economic possibilities ofr our grandchildren 75 year after: A global perspective. In G. Piga & L. Pecchi (Eds.), Revisiting keynes: Economic possibilities for our grandchildren (pp. 27–39). Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.10.7551/mitpress/9780262162494.003.0003Search in Google Scholar
© 2018 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston