Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter December 14, 2017

A Re-Examination of Multistage Economies in Hog Farming

  • Joshua D. Parcel , John R. Schroeter and Azzeddine M Azzam EMAIL logo

Abstract

Current trends in the structure of hog production in the U.S. are toward facilities that are not only larger, but also more likely to be specialized, carrying out only some of the vertically linked phases of production in the same facility. This paper investigates the cost efficiency incentives for these changes by estimating a multistage cost function for hog production. Data are from the Hog Production Practices and Costs portion of the USDA’s 2004 Agricultural Resource Management Survey.


Notes

This project received financial support from the National Research Initiative Competitive Grants Program (Markets and Trade area), CSREES/USDA, proposal No. 2007-04495. The opinions expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of CSREES or USDA. The authors gratefully acknowledge helpful communications with Robert Dubman, Nigel Key, and William McBride.


Funding statement: National Research Initiative Competitive Grants Program (Markets and Trade area), CSREES/USDA., (Grant / Award Number: ‘2007-04495’).

Appendix: The Measurement of Stage-Specific Output

The stage one and stage two output measures used in the multistage cost function are hundred weight gain in the farrow-to-feeder (FAR) and the feeder-to-finish stages (FIN) during calendar year 2004, the period to which the ARMS Phase III survey applied. Since output at the farrow-to-feeder stage includes, for some farms, feeder pigs that are then transferred internally, and since the number of these internal transfers must be inferred from stocks and flows at the second stage, we start by considering output at the feeder-to-finish stage.

Output Measure: Stage 2

FIN, the hundred weight gain at the feeder-to-finish stage, was calculated as the weight of market hogs sold/removed, plus the change in the weight of the inventory of hogs in the feeder-to-finish stage, minus the weight of feeder pigs supplied as inputs to the stage. Firms can acquire feeder pigs for input into their second stage production by transferring them internally or purchasing/placing them. No feeder pigs are produced under completely specialized feeder-to-finish operations so all must be acquired through purchase/placement, and the number of feeder pigs purchased or placed is reported in the survey. For all other firms, however, the number of head of feeder pigs entering the feeder-to-finish stage (HDFPIn) is not directly reported in the survey but can be determined by adding the outflow of market hogs exiting the stage due to sale (HDMHSold) or death loss (FeedFinDL) to the net change in market hog inventory (HDFeedFinΔInv):

HDFPIn=HDFPPurch,forcompletelyspecializedfeedertofinishHDMHSold+FeedFinDL+HDFeedFinΔInv,otherwise

where HDFPPurch is the number of head of feeder pigs purchased/placed.[23] Given the number of feeder pigs used as a second stage input, the total weight is calculated by multiplying by the average weight of feeder pigs in hundred-weight (AvgCwtFP). For farms that purchased/placed or sold/removed feeder pigs, AvgCwtFP was set equal to the reported average weight of pigs involved in these transactions and was thus a measure specific to the farm. Fully-integrated farrow-to-feeder operations do not have external transactions in feeder pigs so, for these farms, AvgCwtFP was set equal to the sample average weight of feeder pigs purchase/placed or sold/removed by all farms, approximately 47 pounds. The hundred weight of feeder pig input to the second stage is then calculated as

CwtFPIn=AvgCwtFPxHDFPIn.

Beginning-of-year and end-of-year head count inventories were reported separately in the survey for four size categories: 0–59 pounds, 60–119 pounds, 120–179 pounds, and 180 pounds and over. Hogs in the last three categories, and some of the hogs in the first category, are attributed to the feeder-to-finish stage. As the average weight of feeder pigs observed is less than 60 pounds, the inventory of hogs in the 0–59 pound category must be allocated between the farrow-to-feeder and feeder-to-finish stages. The allocation was based on the assumption that the pigs in this size category were uniformly distributed over weights of 0 to 60 pounds. This also implies that the average weight of the pigs in excess of 47 pounds is the average of 47 and 60, the category’s upper bound weight. Thus the hundred weight change in feeder-to-finish inventory of pigs weighing 47 to 60 pounds (CwtFeedFinΔInv4759) is calculated as

CwtFeedFinΔInv4759=0.6+0.472604760HDEndInv059HDBegInv059,

where HDBegInv059 and HDEndInv059 are beginning and ending inventories of pigs under 60 pounds.

The representative weights of the other three categories, 100 pounds, 150 pounds, and 200 pounds, are the category weights implicit in the ERS/NASS calculations of the hundred-weight inventory variables from the reported head-count inventories. Thus, the hundred weight inventory changes in the remaining categories are constructed as:

CwtFeedFinΔInv60119=1.0HDEndInv60119HDBegInv60119
CwtFeedFinΔInv120179=1.5HDEndInv120179HDBegInv120179
CwtFeedFinΔInv180+=2.0HDEndInv180+HDBegInv180+,

where the new notation is defined in the obvious way. Summing these, we have the hundred weight change in feeder-to-finish inventory

CwtFeedFinΔInv=CwtFeedFinΔInv4759+CwtFeedFinΔInv60119+CwtFeedFinΔInv120179+CwtFeedFinΔInv180+.

Since both head of market hogs sold/removed (HDMHSold) and the average weight of market hogs sold/removed (AvgWtMH) were reported, the hundred weight of market hogs sold can be calculated as

CwtMHOut=AvgWtMHxHDMHSold/100.

Finally, the stage two output is

FIN=CwtMHOut+CwtFeedFinΔInvCwtFPIn.

Output Measure: Stage 1

At the first stage, no output is produced by completely specialized feeder-to-finish operations. Since there is no intermediate input required for the farrow-to-feeder stage, the process of calculating hundred-weight gain is divided into only two parts: feeder pigs exiting the stage and change in inventory.

As previously mentioned, the survey reports head counts of pigs under 60 pounds in beginning-of-year (HDBegInv059) and end-of-year inventory (HDEndInv059). Just as before, we allocate these inventory totals between the farrow-to-feeder and feeder-to-finish stages based on the assumption of a uniform distribution of weights within the 0 – 60 pound category. With 47 pounds taken to be the top weight of the farrow-to-feeder stage, we have the following beginning- and end-of-year inventory head counts:

HDFarFeedBegInv=4760HDBegInv059

and

HDFarFeedEndInv=4760HDEndInv059.

Assuming the average weight of feeder pigs in these beginning and ending inventories is half the average feeder pig weight, the hundred weight change in the pig inventory is

CwtFarFeedΔInv=0.472HDFarFeedEndInvHDFarFeedBegInv.

The outflow of feeder pigs from the first stage to the second (HDFPOut) occurs through either internal transfer or sale on the market. Thus, the number of feeder pigs exiting the farrow-to-feeder stage is

HDFPOut=HDFPSold+HDFPInHDFPPurch,

where HDFPSold, the number of feeder pigs sold/removed, is reported in the survey. The hundred-weight of feeder pigs exiting the farrow-to-feeder stage is then

CwtFPOut=AvgCwtFPxHDFPOut.

From this, stage one output is given by

FAR=CwtFPOut+CwtFarFeedΔInv.

Death Loss Allocation

To determine the head count flows we require a measure of death loss at the feeder-to-finish stage. However, death losses were instead reported for pre-wean and post-wean periods – with weaning, of course, occurring during the farrow-to-feeder stage – so an allocation of the reported post-wean death losses (PstwDL) between the two stages was required for farms that operate at both stages. To achieve this, we calculated post-wean death loss ratios for completely specialized farrow-to-feeder and completely specialized feeder-to-finish operations as the number of weaned pigs that died before reaching market weight per feeder pig or per market hog sold/removed, respectively. These two producer types were selected as they operate exclusively on one stage or the other, and so reported death losses can be attributed entirely to a single stage of production. Sample averages of the post-wean death loss ratios were then generated for these two producer types. By dividing the average post-wean death loss ratio for feeder-to-finish operations by the sum of the average post-wean death loss ratios for both types of specialized operations, we obtained a rough estimate of the proportion of post-wean death losses that occur in the second stage of production (PstwPstfDLprop). This figure was then assumed to be applicable to all farms operating at both stages.

Completely specialized farrow-to-feeder farms have no second stage production so no death loss is allocated to the feeder-to-finish stage. Similarly, completely specialized feeder-to-finish farms operate exclusively on the second stage so all post-wean death loss is allocated to the feeder-to-finish stage. Since fully-integrated feeder-to-finish, partially-integrated backward, and partially-integrated forward firms operate on both stages, a portion of post-wean death loss is allocated to each stage. For these farms, farm-specific death loss at the feeder-to-finish stage (FeedFinDL) was calculated by multiplying the industry-wide proportion of post-wean death loss attributable to the second stage, PstwPstfDLprop, by the farm’s reported number of post-wean deaths:

FeedFinDL=PstwPstfDLpropxPstwDL.

References

Azzam, A., and C.S. Skinner. 2007. “Vertical Economies and the Structure of U.S. Hog Farms.” Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 55:349–364.10.1111/j.1744-7976.2007.00096.xSearch in Google Scholar

Bailey, E.E., and A.F. Friedlaender. 1982. “Market Structure and Multiproduct Industries.” Journal of Economic Literature 20:1024–1048.Search in Google Scholar

Baumol, W.J. 1977. “On the Proper Cost Tests for Natural Monopoly in a Multiproduct Industry.” American Economic Review 67 (5):809–822.Search in Google Scholar

Carrington, W.J., J.L. Eltinge, and K. McCue. 2000. An Economist’s Primer on Survey Samples. Discussion Paper CES 00-15, Center for Economic Studies, Bureau of the Census.Search in Google Scholar

Dubman, R.W. 2001. Variance Estimation with USDA’s Farm Costs and Returns Surveys and Agricultural Resource Management Study Surveys. ERS Staff Paper AGES 00-01. USDA-ERS.Search in Google Scholar

DuMouchel, W.H., and G.J. Duncan. 1983. “Using Sample Survey Weights in Multiple Regression Analyses of Stratified Samples.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 78 (383):535–543.10.1080/01621459.1983.10478006Search in Google Scholar

Kaserman, D.L., and J.W. Mayo. 1991. “The Measurement of Vertical Economies and the Efficient Structure of the Electric Utility Industry.” Journal of Industrial Economics 39 (5):483–502.10.2307/2098457Search in Google Scholar

Key, N., and W. McBride. 2007. The Changing Economics of U.S. Hog Production. Economic Research Report No. 52. USDA-ERS.10.2139/ssrn.1084881Search in Google Scholar

Kott, P.S. 2001. Using the Delete-a-Group Jackknife Variance Estimator in Nass Surveys. NASS Research Report 98-01 (revised 2001). Available at: http://www.nass.usda.gov/research/reports/RRGJ7.pdfSearch in Google Scholar

Kott, P.S. 2008. Building a Better Delete-A-Group Jackknife for a Calibration Estimator (Like that Based on Data from the ARMS III). Extension of paper presented at the Workshop on Calibration and Estimation in Surveys, Ottawa, Ontario, October/November 2007.Search in Google Scholar

Kwoka, J.E. 2002. “Vertical Economies in Electric Power: Evidence on Integration and Its Alternatives.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 20:653–671.10.1016/S0167-7187(00)00114-4Search in Google Scholar

Little, R.J. 2004. “To Model or Not to Model? Competing Modes of Inference for Finite Population Sampling.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 99:546–556.10.1198/016214504000000467Search in Google Scholar

MacDonald, J., J. Perry, M. Ahearn, D. Banker, W. Chambers, C. Dimitri, N. Key, K. Nelson, and L. Southard. 2004. Contracts, Markets, and Prices: Organizing the Production and Use of Agricultural Commodities. Agricultural Economics Report No. 837. USDA-ERS.10.2139/ssrn.754986Search in Google Scholar

Mayen, C.D., J.V. Balagtas, and C.E. Alexander. 2009. “Vertical Economies of Scope in Dairy Farming.” Journal of Agricultural and Food Industrial Organization 7:article 8.10.2202/1542-0485.1281Search in Google Scholar

National Research Council. 2007. “Methods for Analysis of Complex Surveys. Chapter 7.” In Understanding American Agriculture: Challenges for the Agricultural Resource Management Survey. Washington, DC: National Academy of Sciences. Available at http://www.nap.edu/catalog/11990.html.Search in Google Scholar

Panzar, J.C., and R.D. Willig. 1975. Economies of Scale and Economies of Scope in Multi-Output Production. Economics Discussion Paper 33. Bell Labs.Search in Google Scholar

Panzar, J.C., and R.D. Willig. 1977. “Economies of Scale in Multi-Output Production.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 91 (3):431–493.10.2307/1885979Search in Google Scholar

Panzar, J.C., and R.D. Willig. 1981. “Economies of Scope.” American Economic Review 71 (2):268–272.Search in Google Scholar

U. S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service. 2009. ARMS Global Documentation. Available at: http://www.ers.usda.gov/Data/ARMS/GlobalDocumentation.htmSearch in Google Scholar

Wooldridge, J.M. 1999. “Asymptotic Properties of Weighted M-Estimators for Variable Probability Samples.” Econometrica 67 (6):1385–1406.10.1111/1468-0262.00083Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2017-12-14

© 2018 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 5.12.2023 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/jafio-2017-0033/html
Scroll to top button