Abstract
This paper reviews rice procurement operations of Government of India from the standpoints of cost of procurement as well as effectiveness in supporting farmers’ incomes. The two channels in use for procuring rice till 2015, were custom milling of rice and levy. In the first, the government bought paddy directly from farmers at the minimum support price (MSP) and got it milled from private millers; while in the second, it purchased rice from private millers at a pre-announced levy price thus providing indirect price support to farmers. Secondary data reveal that levy, despite implying lower cost of procurement was discriminated against till about a decade back and eventually abolished in 2015 in favor of custom milling, better trusted to provide minimum price support. We analyze data from auctions of paddy from a year when levy was still important to investigate its impact on farmers’ revenues. We use semi-nonparametric estimates of millers’ values to simulate farmers’ expected revenues and find these to be rather close to the MSP; a closer analysis shows that bidder competition is critical to this result. Finally, we use our estimates to quantify the impact of change in levy price on farmers’ revenues and use this to discuss ways to revive the levy channel.
Hermite Polynomials
Hermite polynomials are a class of orthogonal polynomials that have support over the entire real line and the Gaussian function
where d
n
/dx
n
refers to the nth derivative. The nth order normalized Hermite polynomial is defined by
The first three Hermite polynomials are H
0(x) = 1, H
1(x) = x, H
2(x) = x
2−1. The first three normalized Hermite polynomials are
Since we employ as weighting function, a normal density with mean zero and standard deviation 0.4, the Hermite polynomials must also be suitably modified so that they are orthonormal with respect to the weighting function
Specifying the Joint Density of the Win Price and Winner’s Identity
The joint probability density of the win price and a specific small bidder winning is given by (Banerji and Meenakshi 2004):
The first term in this equation corresponds to the case where the large bidder’s valuation is less than the start price r. The probability that the large bidder’s valuation is less than r is F
V1(r); the probability that a specific small bidder’s valuation is more than w is
The second term consists of two possibilities, the large bidder’s valuation being between r and w, and it being exactly w. In either case, the probability that a specific small bidder’s valuation is greater than w is (1 − F
V2(w)), the realized set of non-winning active small bidders can be one of
The joint probability density of the win price and a specific large bidder winning is given by
The probability that a specific large bidder’s valuation is greater than the win price is
Estimating Farmer’s Reservation Utility for a Lot of Paddy
In the event of a lot going unsold at the formal auction, it goes back to the shop of the katcha arhtia through whom the farmer sells his grain. Typically, it gets sold to some private miller later through mutual negotiations. The private miller is free to opt out of this possibility of a purchase and not get anything; the farmer is free to opt out of the sale and take his grain to some other market to sell. Thus it is useful to think of these negotiations in terms of bilateral bargaining with outside options.
We use a stylized model here, namely the complete information bargaining model of Rubinstein (1982), augmented with outside options (see for example Muthoo 1999 for a textbook exposition). Let the miller’s (buyer’s) valuation for the lot be v. We denote by s, the seller’s (farmer’s) use value for the lot, which is the worth that the farmer attaches to a lot that does not get sold anywhere and is eventually privately used. In the absence of outside options, the subgame perfect equilibrium shares of the players in Rubinstein’s model are
We assume the buyers (millers) to have a discount rate equal to 15% per annum (which corresponds to the rate at which they could have borrowed from banks at that time), while the sellers (farmers) were able to borrow from the co-operative societies or the katcha arhtias at about 2% per month (i.e. 24% per annum). In the course of our interviews with them, farmers stated that if a lot goes unsold, then transporting it and selling it elsewhere (possibly at another market where auctions are not employed) can mean a discount of up to Rs 100 compared to the price obtainable in this market through auctions. We therefore estimate the outside option of the farmer, for each lot, as the expected second-highest valuation for that quality minus a penalty amount of Rs 100. On the other hand, if the miller opts out of the bargaining, his payoff is zero; in effect, the model then is one of alternating offers bargaining with an outside option for the seller.
The farmer’s equilibrium payoff in the bargaining model with an outside option available to him is the larger of his Rubinstein share
Derivation of Optimal Reserve Prices
Differentiating Π with respect to r
where
Thus
Since
where λ i (.) is the hazard-rate function, we have
Dividing throughout by
The above equation gives for a lot of a specific quality, the first order condition for profit maximization of the seller.
Confidence Intervals for Optimal Reserve Prices
We use the Delta method to construct confidence intervals around the optimal reserve prices.
Recall that for a lot with quality vector z, the valuation of player i of type j is given by
The first-order condition for revenue-maximization (Eq. (13) in Section 5), which gives the optimal reserve price r * can be rewritten as an implicit function of r * and the parameter vector β
where
We now obtain the asymptotic distribution of the optimal reserve price based on the semi-nonparametric estimates.
Gallant and Nychka (1987) prove the consistency of SNP estimators for multivariate data. Fenton and Gallant (1996) specialize it to the univariate case. Wong and Severini (1991) establish root-n asymptotic normality and efficiency of semi-nonparametric maximum likelihood estimators.
Consider an estimator
where V/T is the variance-covariance matrix of
Expanding
Ignoring U, as it will be negligible in the neighborhood of
Thus,
In practice, we work with approximations, so let
We use the parameter estimates (
Proof of Proposition 1
Differentiating the expected revenue (Eq. (12)) with respect to reserve price and setting N 1 = 1 and N 2 = N we get
where
Second derivative of
where
Simplifying further, we get
Evaluating this at r = r
* and using
To see how the curvature of Π(r) responds to changes in the number of bidders, we differentiate
Now
Along with
Acknowledgments
I am grateful to Abhijit Banerji and J.V. Meenakshi for their guidance and for providing paddy auctions data. I thank K.L. Krishna, Anirban Kar and seminar participants at Delhi School of Economics, Lancaster University, Indian Statistical Institute – Delhi, Indian Institutes of Technology – Bombay and Guwahati for useful comments. I gratefully acknowledge help from Ashok Sinha in acquiring some of the procurement data.
References
Arnold, B., N. Balakrishnan, and H. Nagaraja. 1992. A First Course in Order Statistics. New York: Wiley.Search in Google Scholar
Athey, S., and P. A. Haile. 2002. “Identification of Standard Auction Models.” Econometrica 70: 2107–40, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0262.2002.00435.x.Search in Google Scholar
Athey, S., and P. A. Haile. 2007. “Nonparametric Approaches to Auctions.” In Handbook of Econometrics, 1st ed., Vol. 6, Ch. 60, edited by J. J. Heckman, and E. Leamer, 3847–965. Elsevier.Search in Google Scholar
Athey, S., and J. Levin. 2001. “Information and Competition in U.S. Forest Service Timber Auctions.” Journal of Political Economy 109: 375–417, https://doi.org/10.1086/319558.Search in Google Scholar
Banerji, A., and J. V. Meenakshi. 2004. “Buyer Collusion and Efficiency of Government in Wheat Markets in Northern India: An Asymmetric Structural Auction Analysis.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86: 236–53, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0092-5853.2004.00575.x.Search in Google Scholar
Banerji, A., and J. V. Meenakshi. 2008. “Millers, Commission Agents and Collusion in Grain Markets: Evidence from Basmati Auctions in North India.” B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, Contributions 81: 4, https://doi.org/10.2202/1935-1682.1786.Search in Google Scholar
Banerji, A., N. Gupta, and J. V. Meenaksji. 2012. “Auctions in Grain Markets and Farmer Welfare.” Economic and Political Weekly XLVII (52): 64–71.Search in Google Scholar
Brendstrup, B., and H. Paarsch. 2006. “Identification and Estimation in Sequential, Asymmetric, English Auctions.” Journal of Econometrics 134: 69–94, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2005.06.017.Search in Google Scholar
Chand, R., and J. Singh. 2016. Agricultural Marketing and Farmer Friendly Reforms across Indian States and UTs. New Delhi: National Institution for Transforming India, NITI Aayog. Also available at niti.gov.in.Search in Google Scholar
Chen, X. 2007. “Large Sample Sieve Estimation of Semi-nonparametric Models.” In Handbook of Econometrics, Vol. 6, ch. 76, edited by J. J. Heckman and E. Leamer. North Holland: Elsevier.Search in Google Scholar
Fenton, V. M., and A. R. Gallant. 1996. “Convergence Rates of SNP Density Estimators.” Econometrica 64: 719–27, https://doi.org/10.2307/2171869.Search in Google Scholar
Gallant, A., and D. Nychka. 1987. “Semi-nonparametric Maximum Likelihood Estimation.” Econometrica 55: 363–90, https://doi.org/10.2307/1913241.Search in Google Scholar
Gupta, N. 2013. Government Intervention in Grain Markets in India: Rethinking the Procurement Policy. Centre for Development Economics Working Paper No. 231. Delhi School of Economics.Search in Google Scholar
Haryana Food and Supplies Department Website 2019. haryanafood.gov.in (accessed February 5, 2019).Search in Google Scholar
High Level Committee Report on Long Term Grain Policy. 2002. Department of Food and Public Distribution, Ministry of Consumer Affairs, Food and Public Distribution, Government of India.Search in Google Scholar
Kannan, K. 2018. From Mandis to Markets: Will This Round Be Any Better? Also available at www.indiatogether.org.Search in Google Scholar
Kaur, P., and N. Singla. 2018. “Can Contract Farming Double Farmers’ Income?” Economic and Political Weekly LIII: 51.Search in Google Scholar
Krishna, V. 2002. Auction Theory. San Diego: Academic Press.Search in Google Scholar
Laffont, J. J., H. Ossard, and Q. Vuong. 1995. “Econometrics of First-Price Auctions.” Econometrica 63: 953–80, https://doi.org/10.2307/2171804.Search in Google Scholar
Meenakshi, J. V., and A. Banerji. 2005. “The Unsupportable Support Price: An Analysis of Collusion and Government Intervention in Paddy Auction Markets in North India.” Journal of Development Economics 76: 377–403, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2004.02.001.Search in Google Scholar
Meilijson, I. 1981. “Estimation of the Lifetime Distribution of the Parts from the Autopsy Statistics of the Machine.” Journal of Applied Probability 18: 829–38, https://doi.org/10.2307/3213058.Search in Google Scholar
More, S. S., K. V. Deshmukh, and J. L. Katkade. 2016. “Agricultural Market Reforms in Maharashtra in Context with Model Act: Status and Issues.” Indian Journal of Agricultural Marketing 30 (3s): 74–81.Search in Google Scholar
Muthoo, A. 1999. Bargaining Theory with Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Notes prepared by Department of Food and Civil Supplies, Ministry of Food and Consumer Affairs, Government of India for the procurement arms of the Government of Haryana, various years.Search in Google Scholar
Paarsch, H. 1992. “Deciding between the Common and Private Value Paradigms in Empirical Models of Auctions.” Journal of Econometrics 51: 191–215, https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(92)90035-p.Search in Google Scholar
Paarsch, H. 1997. “Deriving an Estimate of the Optimal Reserve Price: An Application to British Columbian Timber Sales.” Journal of Econometrics 78: 333–57, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0304-4076(97)80016-4.Search in Google Scholar
Paarsch, H., and H. Hong. 2006. An Introduction to the Structural Econometrics of Auction Data. Cambridge: MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar
Palaskas, T., and B. Harriss-White. 1996. “The Identification of Market Exogeneity and Market Dominance by Tests Instead of Assumption: An Application to Indian Material.” Journal of International Development 8: 11–23, https://doi.org/10.1002/(sici)1099-1328(199601)8:1<111::aid-jid271>3.0.co;2-v.Search in Google Scholar
Ramaswami, B., and P. Balakrishnan. 2002. “Food Prices and the Efficiency of Public Intervention: The Case of Public Distribution System in India.” Food Policy 27: 419–36, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0306-9192(02)00047-7.Search in Google Scholar
Reddy, A. A. 2017. “Status of Market Reforms in India.” Indian Farming 66 (8): 33–7, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-3150-2_2.Search in Google Scholar
Rubinstein, A. 1982. “Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model.” Econometrica 50: 97–110, https://doi.org/10.2307/1912531.Search in Google Scholar
Saxena, R. 2018. Why Maharashtra Farmers Do Not Want to Sell Outside APMCs. Also available at bloombergquint.com.Search in Google Scholar
Singh, S. 2018. “Reforming Agricultural Markets in India: A Tale of Two Model Acts.” Economic and Political Weekly 53 (51): 44–9.Search in Google Scholar
Tostao, E., C. Chung, and B. Brorsen. 2006. American Agricultural Economics Association (New Name 2008: Agricultural and Applied Economics Association). 2006 Annual meeting, July 23-26, Long Beach, CA, number 21244.Search in Google Scholar
Umali-Deininger, D., and K. Deininger. 2001. “Towards Greater Food Security for India’s Poor: Balancing Government Intervention and Private Competition.” Agricultural Economics 39: 281–94, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1574-0862.2001.tb00212.x.Search in Google Scholar
Wong, W. H., and T. A. Severini. 1991. “On Maximum Likelihood Estimation in Infinite Dimensional Parameter Space.” Annals of Statistics 16: 603–32.Search in Google Scholar
© 2021 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston