Skip to content
BY 4.0 license Open Access Published by De Gruyter Oldenbourg September 9, 2022

A Model United Nations Experiment on Climate Negotiations

  • Elisa Hofmann ORCID logo , Lucas Kyriacou ORCID logo and Klaus M. Schmidt ORCID logo EMAIL logo

Abstract

Weitzman, M.L. (2014. Can negotiating a uniform carbon price help to internalize the global warming externality? J. Assoc. Environ. Resour. Econ. 1: 29–49) proposed that focusing international climate negotiations on a uniform common commitment (such as a uniform carbon price) is more effective than negotiations on individual commitments (as in the Paris agreement) in achieving ambitious climate action. We put this hypothesis to an experimental test by simulating international negotiations on climate change in collaboration with Model United Nations associations. This novel experimental format combines some of the advantages of lab and field experiments. Our results offer support for Weitzman’s hypothesis and indicate that negotiating a common commitment on a uniform carbon price may yield higher emission reductions in the long run and more participation than individual commitments à la Paris.

JEL Classification: C81; C93; F51; H87; Q54

1 Introduction

Mitigating CO2 emissions is a global public good problem. To solve it, effective international cooperation is required that needs to be negotiated by sovereign countries. The success of these negotiations depends on how they are structured. In the negotiations on the Paris agreement, countries negotiated a common, nonbinding goal by how much to limit global warming. This goal is to be implemented by “nationally determined contributions”, i.e. individual commitments by the participating countries of how much to contribute to the common good. This negotiation design was very successful in achieving maximum participation (all 197 member nations of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) signed the agreement) and an ambitious common goal (limit global warming to less than 2 °C), but it did not induce the parties to engage in sufficient climate action to achieve this goal. Because each country has to bear the full cost of its mitigation efforts alone while the benefits are distributed across all nations, it is widely feared that the Paris agreement will fail to sufficiently limit global warming.[1]

There is a new proposal, advocated by Weitzman (2014, 2017a), Nordhaus (2015, 2019, MacKay et al. (2015), and others, to structure climate negotiations in a radically different way. They argue that negotiations should focus on a uniform price for carbon emissions. This negotiation design strives for a uniform common commitment that builds on reciprocity. If a country pushes for a higher carbon price, it knows that this higher price will apply uniformly to all countries. Thus, both the benefits and the costs of this action are borne by all nations. This induces each country to strive for a carbon price that it believes is optimal for the world as a whole, rather than some climate action that it believes is optimal for itself given the mitigation efforts taken by the rest of the world. However, a possible drawback of this design is that some countries may prefer to stay out of the agreement and not to impose any carbon price at all.

Is this new approach, focusing on a uniform common commitment, likely to be more successful than negotiating individual commitments, as in the Paris approach? In this paper we report on the results of a novel type of field experiment that sheds light on this question. We collaborated with “Model United Nations” (MUN) associations in Germany and Switzerland and simulated “Conferences of the Parties” (COPs) of the United Nations (UN) with student delegates. The conferences followed the actual COP rules of the United Nations. Student delegates were supposed to represent the position of the country they were assigned to, they were provided with detailed information, they had to carefully prepare for the event, and they wrote a position paper for their country before the conference started. At each location we held two simultaneous COP conferences on climate action with ten countries each, representing all major regions and the main conflicting interests. Student delegates were assigned randomly to the two COPs and to the countries they represented.

Both COPs had to pass resolutions specifying the reductions of carbon emissions in the years 2030, 2040, and 2050. In committee C1, these reductions were achieved by binding individual commitments to emission reductions of the participating countries in these years, combined with a nonbinding common goal on how much to reduce worldwide emissions. In committee C2, the parties that passed the resolution agreed to a binding commitment on a uniform carbon price for each of these years. Thus, C1 negotiated individual commitments (as in Paris), while C2 focused the negotiations on a uniform common commitment (a uniform carbon price).

Our study has four main results: First, we find that countries achieve significantly and substantially higher reductions of carbon emissions in 2050 in C2 where they negotiate a uniform carbon price. Second, in C1 countries are equally ambitious in their nonbinding common goals as in C2 (no significant difference), but the actual individual commitments in C1 do not live up to these goals. Third, to our surprise, significantly more countries participate in the resolution if a uniform common commitment is negotiated than if negotiations are focused on individual commitments. This is partly due to the behavior of countries like Russia and Saudi Arabia. They are opposed to a carbon price not because they suffer a lot if a high carbon price is introduced in their countries, but rather if other countries introduce a high carbon price which reduces demand for their fossil fuel exports. Thus, these countries try to convince other countries to keep the carbon price low in exchange for their participation in the overall agreement. Finally, there are substantial and significant differences in the reduction of emissions between the different countries in C1, while countries contribute more equally to the common good in C2. This is partly due to the uniformity of the carbon price, and partly due to the fact that in C2 more countries participate in the resolution.

Our paper is closely related and complementary to Schmidt and Ockenfels (2021) who conducted a laboratory experiment comparing the negotiation designs of Paris, Kyoto, and the new approach striving for a uniform carbon price. In the lab experiment, four subjects faced an asymmetric public good problem and negotiated a binding contract on their contributions to the public good. Negotiations took place through a computer network without personal interaction, the problem was framed in an abstract and neutral fashion (climate change is never mentioned), and subjects were paid for their decisions. Schmidt and Ockenfels (2021) find that negotiations on a uniform minimum contribution to the public good are significantly and substantially more effective than a negotiation design with individual commitments as in Paris and negotiations on a common complex commitment as in Kyoto. This result is driven by two effects. First, negotiating a uniform minimum contribution to the public good induces all parties who participate in the negotiations to contribute almost efficiently (as predicted by the game-theoretic analysis). Second, while the participation rate is somewhat lower when a carbon price is negotiated as compared to Paris style negotiations, the free-riding effect is small. Furthermore, Schmidt and Ockenfels (2021) show that their qualitative results continue to hold even if contracts are nonbinding and cannot be enforced.

The advantage of the laboratory experiment of Schmidt and Ockenfels (2021) is its internal validity. The lab allows for a tight control of the environment and for many independent observations. Thus, the experiment can show that negotiation design has a statistically highly significant (and substantial) causal effect on the negotiation outcome. However, the experiment is very stylized, negotiations take place anonymously via a computer network, and subjects do not negotiate on climate action but on monetary outcomes of an abstract public good game. Thus, it is difficult to assess whether the experimental results of the lab carry over to the real world.[2] Our study addresses some of these problems. We look at negotiations following the rules of real COP negotiations, negotiations have a richer and more realistic context, they last for an entire day, and subjects are intrinsically motivated to represent the best interest of their countries. Following the taxonomy of Harrison and List (2004), our experiment is close to what they call a framed field experiment, because the experimental framework of climate change negotiations represents field context. However, our design differs from a framed field experiment as we use a standard subject pool of students. These subjects simulate negotiations in a field setting, an experimental design that is not quite captured in the taxonomy of Harrison and List (2004).

Our paper is related to several strands of the literature. First, there is a large literature on international environmental agreements going back to the canonical paper by Barrett (1994) and surveyed by Barrett (2005). This literature offers many important insights in the incentives to join international agreements and how to make them self-enforcing. However, it does not discuss the design of the negotiation process.

Second, there is a small literature on how to structure climate negotiations. In a series of papers, Weitzman (2014, 2015, 2017a, 2017b) compares negotiations on a uniform carbon price to negotiations on a vector of emission reductions. He argues that negotiating a uniform carbon price provides a salient focal point (as advocated by Schelling (1960)), and he shows formally that it aligns self-interest with the common good. This argument has been formalized by Weitzman (2014) and Schmidt and Ockenfels (2021). They model the fight against climate change as an asymmetric public good problem. All countries want to mitigate global warming, but some countries are more affected by climate change or have lower costs of introducing a carbon price than others and therefore want to implement more stringent policies. Thus, for each country, there is a most preferred carbon price that it wants to be applied to the world. Schmidt and Ockenfels (2021) show that this mechanism is strategy-proof, so for each country it is a weakly dominant strategy to propose the carbon price that would be optimal from its own perspective, if it was imposed by all other countries as well. MacKay et al. (2015) furthermore emphasize that a uniform carbon price is a reciprocal instrument (“I will if you will”). Nordhaus (2015, 2019 proposes a “climate club” that commits to a uniform carbon price for its members and imposes tariffs on the imports of non-members to compensate for the distortion of competition and to induce other countries to join the club. He points to the experience with other international agreements (Barrett 2003; Battaglini and Harstad 2016, 2020) showing that treaties tend to be stable only if they penalize free-riders.

Third, there is an experimental literature on the endogenous formation of institutions for successful public good provision. Dannenberg and Gallier (2020) offer an excellent survey of this literature. According to their classification our paper considers the case of a global public good (carbon emissions affect everybody) and an exclusive institution (the uniform carbon price applies to only those countries that support it). A closely related paper in this class is Kosfeld et al. (2009) who consider a public good game in which subjects can vote on the introduction of an institution that forces all members to contribute the full amount to the public good, while those who stay out are free how much to contribute. They find that institutions form in about half of all cases, and in most of them there is full participation. In contrast, in our setup countries are not forced to raise the carbon price to the efficient level. The minimum mechanism allows them to react to those countries that did not participate in the uniform carbon price. Several other papers explore the minimum contribution mechanism. Dannenberg et al. (2014) consider a repeated public good experiment in which all players are forced to participate (inclusive institution). They find that about 60 percent of the groups have an increasing minimum contribution level over time that approaches the social optimum at the end, while the other 40 percent implement a low level throughout the game. This may be explained by the fact that participation was not voluntary. A subject that was forced to participate can choose a very low contribution level which implies that all other contributions are equally low. In contrast, participation was voluntary in our setup. In Kocher et al. (2016) as well as in Martinsson and Persson (2019) the minimum contribution level was prespecified but lower than the efficient level. Both papers find that the large majority of subjects vote in favor of this mechanism. Almost all of the lab experiments in this literature do not allow subjects to communicate, while in our Model United Nations experiment parties had ample time to discuss and negotiate their actions. While almost all of the lab experiments take place in an abstract setting, there is one interesting experiment by Barrett and Dannenberg (2016) on climate negotiations. They study the “pledge and review” process of the Paris agreement in a lab experiment and show that pledges do not increase actual contributions over time.

Finally, there is a literature in political science and education on simulation games (see, e.g., Boardman 1969; Lester and Stoil 1979; Asal 2005; Kauneckis and Auer 2013). This literature focuses on simulation games mainly as a pedagogical tool to foster student engagement and learning. A few exceptions are Penetrante (2012) and Matzner and Herrenbrück (2017). Penetrante (2012) used MUN simulation games as “case studies” to find stumbling blocks in negotiations and to analyze coalition building. Similarly, Matzner and Herrenbrück (2017) conducted three MUN conferences as experimental sessions to explore the conflicts that may arise when countries negotiate on climate engineering. However, none of these papers allows for statistical hypothesis testing. A methodological novel feature of our paper is the use of MUN simulations as a randomized controlled field experiment. This is related to Schwardmann et al. (2022) who used international debating competitions as a “field experiment” to study whether people persuade themselves about the moral and factual superiority of their position to better convince others.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 describes the setup of the MUN experiment. Section 3 derives the hypotheses that we want to test. Section 4 summarizes the experimental procedures and Section 5 reports the results. Section 6 concludes with a discussion of our new experimental method and our main results. A detailed documentation of the MUN experiment is provided in the Appendix.

2 The MUN Experiment: Design

For the experiment we collaborated with Model United Nations (MUN) associations at six universities across Germany and Switzerland. The idea of MUN goes back to the League of Nations simulations in Oxford and Harvard in the 1920s (Muldoon 1995). Today, MUN associations exist at hundreds of universities and high schools in most countries of the world. They are student organized and engage in extracurricular activities to prepare for simulated United Nations conferences. They teach their members debating and writing skills as well as critical thinking and leadership abilities, they organize local MUN events and send delegations to national and international MUN conferences.

A MUN conference simulates real United Nations conferences. Participants in a MUN conference (“delegates”) are assigned countries to represent. They have to conduct research on their country, formulate positions and come up with policy proposals that they will then debate with their fellow delegates at the conference, staying true to the actual position of the member they represent. During the conference, delegates have to adhere to the formal rules similar to those of real UN conferences. At the end of the conference delegates vote on written policies, called “resolutions” with the goal of passing them with a majority vote. The best performing delegates are often recognized with awards.

At each of the six universities we organized a one-day MUN conference on climate policy[3] with two separate committees (treatments) consisting of ten delegates and two chairs each. Delegates and chairs are allocated randomly to the two committees and to the countries they represent. There are ten nations, kept constant across all conferences, that are supposed to represent the world: Australia, Canada, China, European Union (EU), India, Japan, Russia, Saudi Arabia, South Africa, and the United States of America (USA).[4] These include the major CO2 emitters (USA, China, EU, and Japan), the major producers of fossil fuels (Saudi Arabia, Russia, USA, and Australia), and countries from the developing world (India and South Africa). The two chairs are supposed to strictly enforce the rules of the conference, but not to influence the negotiations otherwise.

Two weeks before the conference all participants receive the same “study guide” (available in the Appendix) which offers general information on the causes and consequences of climate change and a summary of the forecasted scenarios of the 5th Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). It also discusses different policy options to combat climate change and their estimated costs.[5] Participants are supposed to research the position of the country they represent and to write and hand in a position paper before the conference starts.

The position paper has to include (1) a statement on how the represented country will be affected by climate change, (2) what the country’s general position on climate action is, (3) a suggestion by how much the world as a whole should reduce CO2 emissions until 2030, 2040, and 2050 (as compared to 2010), (4) a suggestion by how much the respective country should reduce its own CO2 emissions until 2030, 2040, and 2050 (as compared to 2010), and (5) a short discussion of the advantages and disadvantages of carbon pricing from the perspective of the represented country. We incentivize the delegates to stay in character of their nation by publicly awarding a “Position Paper Award” (cinema voucher of about 10 Euros) to the best written and most authentic position paper at the end of the conference.[6] Furthermore, we proofread position papers and remind delegates whose position papers do not answer all five questions to think about the unanswered questions. The position papers are distributed among the delegates and chairs in each Committee. All participants are asked not to communicate about the conference before the conference starts.

Before the conference, the two committees receive a document called “Questions A Resolution Must Answer” (QARMA, available in the Appendix). This document is the only difference between the two committees. It sets up different negotiation frameworks. Committee 1 (C1) is instructed to get to a resolution that specifies goals for the reduction of worldwide CO2 emissions in 2030, 2040, and 2050, but these goals are nonbinding.[7] Actual reductions are achieved by nationally determined contributions, i.e. individual commitments of all countries supporting the resolution on how much they will reduce their own emissions by 2030, 2040, and 2050. Parties are also asked to indicate in the Annex how they plan to achieve these reductions (e.g. via carbon pricing, subsidizing green energy, imposing restrictions and regulations on CO2 emissions, etc.) Participants are told that these country-specific goals are binding commitments according to international law.[8] Note that the country-specific goals are “nationally determined” by each country alone after the resolution has been passed. This negotiation protocol shares key features of the negotiation protocol that led to the Paris agreement.

In Committee 2 (C2) the negotiation rules are different. Delegates are informed that there has been a previous agreement to introduce a common commitment via a uniform price for CO2 emissions (a “carbon price”). They are instructed to get to a resolution that specifies how high this uniform carbon price should be in 2030, 2040, and 2050. Each country is free how to implement the carbon price (by a carbon tax, emissions trading system, or some hybrid system) and how to spend the revenues from carbon pricing. However, for all countries supporting the resolution, the carbon price is binding. Again, participants are told that this agreement is a binding commitment according to international law. Countries that do not vote for the resolution are not bound by it. Delegates are informed that the common carbon price is accompanied by a carbon border adjustment tax to prevent carbon leakage.[9] They are instructed that the carbon price has to be uniform (i.e. the same for all countries supporting the resolution) and that the resolution cannot include any additional measures to mitigate climate change.

In both committees, a resolution needs at least five votes to be passed.[10] Countries that do not support the resolution are assumed to pursue “business as usual” which results in an increase of CO2 emissions by 40 percent of this country. Furthermore, in both committees, delegates are instructed not to discuss compensation payments for low income countries because there will be another UNFCCC conference on the introduction of a “Green Fund” that will deal with this issue separately.[11]

It is crucial for the experiment that the climate effects of the negotiation outcomes can be compared with each other. In the study guide we provide a table that informs delegates that there is a linear relationship between the reduction of CO2 emissions and the carbon price. For example, a carbon price of USD 0 yields an increase of emissions of 40 percent, a carbon price of USD 60 yields an increase of emissions of 0 percent, a carbon price of USD 120 yields a reduction of emissions of 40 percent and a carbon price of USD 180 yields a reduction of emissions of 80 percent. This linear relationship applies to all countries and to the world as a whole. It is clearly a simplification, but it corresponds roughly to estimates that have been reported by the IPCC AR5 (Edenhofer 2014) and the Report of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices (Stiglitz et al. 2017).[12] All delegates are instructed to take these numbers at face value.

The two committees are two experimental treatments that differ in only one respect: In Committee C1, individual commitments are negotiated, while in Committee C2 negotiations aim at a uniform common commitment. Note that carbon pricing is not restricted to Committee 2. The delegates in Committee 1 can also choose to adopt carbon prices. However, in C1 each country has to do this independently, while in C2 all countries supporting the resolution have to commit to a common uniform carbon price.

3 Hypotheses

The main question of our study is which negotiation protocol is more successful in achieving an effective agreement.[13] Following the literature discussed in the Introduction we predict that negotiations on a uniform carbon price are more successful than negotiations on individual commitments.

Hypothesis 1:

Negotiations in C2 achieve significantly higher reductions in CO2 emissions than negotiations in C1.

In C1, parties did not only state their nationally determined contributions, they also proclaimed a non-binding common goal, namely by how much they want to reduce global CO2 emissions. Because this common goal is nonbinding and nobody can be held responsible for not achieving it, we hypothesize that the individual commitments fail to achieve the stated common goal.

Hypothesis 2:

In C1 the proclaimed nonbinding common goal is significantly higher than the sum of the nationally determined contributions specified by each country individually.

How many countries will participate in signing the resolution? The Paris agreement was signed by all 197 nations on the planet, possibly because each nation was free how much to contribute to the commonly declared goal. But universal participation is not guaranteed. The USA was going to withdraw from the agreement while our experiments took place and some other countries were also on the fence. Thus, in C1 we expect most (but not necessarily all) countries to participate. In C2, a uniform carbon price is a much stronger commitment. Each party has an incentive not to participate but to free-ride on the efforts of the other parties.

Hypothesis 3:

Participation in the resolution is significantly higher in C1 than in C2.

A related question concerns the differences across countries in their contributions. In C2 the uniform carbon price forces all countries that participate in the resolution to impose the same price. Only those countries that do not participate have a carbon price of 0 and therefore higher emissions. In contrast, in C1 each country decides on its own how much to contribute. Some countries (like the EU or Japan) may behave altruistically; others (like the USA or Russia) may put their own interests first. Therefore, we hypothesize that the differences in contributions are likely to be larger in C1.

Hypothesis 4:

In C1 there will be large differences in the contributions of the different countries. In C2, emission reductions will be less unequal.

4 Experimental Procedures

The experiment was conducted in late 2018 and 2019. We held six MUN conferences in Germany and Switzerland lasting about 7 h (10:00 a.m. until 5:00 p.m.) each. Altogether we collected data from 144 participants (120 delegates and 24 chairs, see Table 1).[14]

Table 1:

Overview of experimental sessions and participants.

Session date Session location Participants
Committee 1 Committee 2 Total
15.12.2018 Bern (Switzerland) 12 12 24
23.03.2019 Munich (Germany) 12 12 24
18.05.2019 Zurich (Switzerland) 12 12 24
19.10.2019 Mannheim (Germany) 12 12 24
09.11.2019 Cologne (Germany) 12 12 24
30.11.2019 Tübingen (Germany) 12 12 24
Total 72 72 144

The communication language of the conference was English. Subjects received a flat payment of 20€ in Germany and 20CHF in Switzerland for their participation. Participants knew that the conference was part of an experiment, but they did not know what the experiment was about, nor did they know that the other committee negotiated under a different negotiation protocol. We separated the two committees from the very beginning and instructed the participants not to interact with members of the other committee before and during the conference. After a short introduction given in each committee by an experimenter, the conference was run by the chairs. One experimenter was sitting in the back of each room and kept a log.

Table 2 provides summary statistics of the participants (delegates only)[15] and survey evidence on how they evaluated the conference. On average, participants were 22.07 years old. 48 percent of them were female. Subjects studied on average in their 4th semester. On average participants had participated in 3.25 MUN conferences before and prepared on average 467.22 min (almost 8 h) for the conference. They rated the realism of their position paper at 5.32 on a seven-point Likert-scale ranging from 1 (“not realistic at all”) to 7 (“very realistic”). They evaluated their own performance at 4.82 (on the same scale), similar to the performance of the other participants (4.92). Furthermore, subjects evaluated the realism of the resolution at 4.24 and they were ‘rather satisfied’ with the resolution (4.71 on a seven-point-Likert-Scale ranging from 1 (“not satisfied at all”) to 7 (“very satisfied”)). The participants stated being very interested in the topic already before the conference but indicated an even (significantly) higher interest in the topic after the conference (one-sided Wilcoxon signed-rank test, z = 4.55, p < 0.001).[16] This survey evidence indicates that the MUN conferences succeeded in providing a fairly realistic framework for our simulation experiment.

Table 2:

Summary descriptive statistics for delegates across all six experimental sessions.

Variable Mean Std. dev. N Min. Max.
Age 22.07 2.74 119 16 29
Gender (female = 1) 0.48 0.50 120 0 1
Semester 4.33 2.64 98 1 12
MUN participations 3.25 3.14 116 0 20
Preparation time (in minutes) 467.22 330.78 116 50 2040
Evaluation: realism position paper 5.32 1.25 119 1 7
Evaluation: realism own performance 4.82 1.21 119 1 7
Evaluation: realism other’s performance 4.92 1.14 119 2 7
Evaluation: realism resolution 4.24 1.45 119 1 7
Satisfaction with resolution 4.71 1.63 119 1 7
Interest in topic before conference 5.55 1.27 119 1 7
Interest in topic after conference 5.98 1.13 119 2 7

Participants came from a broad variety of disciplines. Most of them studied economics (28%), law (22%) and other social sciences (21%). The balance Table A.1 in the Appendix shows that the differences among participants across treatments and experimental session are small.

5 Results

Figure 1 compares the average actual worldwide reductions of emissions in percent as compared to 2010 in C1 (individual commitments) and C2 (uniform common commitment) across the six COP meetings.[17] Note that positive values indicate emission reductions while negative values indicate increases in emissions.

Figure 1: 
Actual worldwide reductions of emissions (weighted average over all countries) in Committee C1 versus Committee C2 averaged over all COP meetings.
Figure 1:

Actual worldwide reductions of emissions (weighted average over all countries) in Committee C1 versus Committee C2 averaged over all COP meetings.

There are two main differences between the outcomes of treatments C1 and C2. First, average emission reductions of the years 2030–2050 are substantially higher in C2 (about 20 percent) than in C1 (about 5 percent). Second, the time path of emission reductions in C2 is significantly steeper than in C1. Both start with a similar reduction of emissions in 2030 of about −8 percent (i.e. an increase of emissions by +8 percent). However, in 2040 and in particular in 2050, the negotiation outcome in C2 is much more ambitious as compared to C1. In 2050 this difference is statistically significant.[18]

Result 1:

In 2050 the actual emission reductions of the ten countries are significantly higher in C2 than in C1. Furthermore, the time path of actual average reductions is significantly steeper in C2 than in C1.

Result 1 confirms Hypothesis 1 in 2050. It is supported by a one-sided Wilcoxon signed-rank test (z = 2.071, p = 0.019) comparing the actual CO2 emission reductions of the ten countries in Committee C1 (as stated in the Annex if they support the resolution and “business as usual” otherwise) with the actual CO2 emission reductions of the ten countries in Committee C2 (again depending on voting behavior on the resolution) for the year 2050 in all experimental sessions.[19]

Result 1 is further backed up by linear mixed effects regressions (see Table 3). Here we compare the actual average worldwide abatement levels over 2030–2050 between the two treatments and for the different years. In all three models, the dependent variable is the actual average CO2 emissions reduction in the years 2030, 2040, and 2050. We include a random effect of the location as a matching group variable in all three Models. In Model 1, we further add a random effect of time to account for possible dependencies of the three responses (2030, 2040, and 2050) of one committee (repeated observations) and hence to account for the nested structure of our data.[20]

Table 3:

Determinants of actual average CO2 emission reductions 2030–2050 grouped on experimental session level.

(1) (2) (3)
(Intercept) 5.54 (6.46) −36.41a (9.03) −19.29a (6.36)
C2 treatment 14.48 (10.39) 14.48 (10.39) −19.76 (12.02)
Year 20.98a (3.75) 12.42a (2.20)
C2 treatment x year 17.12b (9.79)
Akaike inf. criterion 355.08 336.97 333.93
Bayesian inf. criterion 363.00 344.89 343.43
Log likelihood −172.54 −163.49 −160.97
Observations 36 36 36
  1. ap < 0.01, bp < 0.1. Regression results from mixed effects models. Abatement levels of carbon emissions was the dependent variable in all three Models. Random intercepts are associated with location in all three Models and additionally with time in Model 1. Robust standard errors adjusted for six location clusters are provided in parentheses.

The treatment itself increases actual worldwide reductions of emissions, but the effect is statistically not significant (Model 1, coefficient = 14.48, p = 0.163). However, reductions of emissions significantly increase over time (Model 2, coefficient = 20.98, p < 0.001). Furthermore, we find a (marginally) significant interaction between treatment and time (Model 3, coefficient = 17.12, p = 0.080).[21]

What drives the difference in emission reductions between the two treatments? If we look at the resolutions that are passed by the committees, then the negotiations in C1 are on average more ambitious than the C2 resolutions, in particular in 2030. However, there is a large and statistically significant difference between the resolution and the actual reduction of emissions in treatment C1, but not in treatment C2. This is shown in Figure 2:

Figure 2: 
Resolutions versus actual reductions. The left bars depict the reductions of emissions as announced in the resolutions, the right bars the actual reductions of emissions in all countries (national commitments weighted by country size).
Figure 2:

Resolutions versus actual reductions. The left bars depict the reductions of emissions as announced in the resolutions, the right bars the actual reductions of emissions in all countries (national commitments weighted by country size).

Result 2:

There is no significant difference in the resolutions passed in C1 and C2. However, the emission reductions in the resolutions are substantial and statistically significantly higher than the actual reductions of emissions for 2030, 2040, and 2050 in C1, but small and not significantly different in C2.

Result 2 confirms Hypothesis 2. It is supported by Wilcoxon signed-rank tests (two-sided test, z = −1.614, p = 0.107), indicating that the resolutions passed are not statistically significantly different between C1 and C2. Furthermore, the emission reductions as announced in the resolutions are statistically significantly higher than the actual average emission reductions for 2030, 2040, and 2050 in C1 (one-sided tests, z = 2.201, p = 0.014), while they do not differ in C2 (two-sided tests, z = 1.408, p = 0.159).

There are two reasons for Result 2. First, in C2 the minimum price for carbon is binding for all countries that passed the resolution. In contrast, in the C1 negotiations, the actual reductions of emissions are determined by nationally determined contributions while the non-binding goal of worldwide emission reductions is just cheap talk. In fact, while some countries reduce their emissions by more than the goal of the resolution, most countries reduce substantially less and do not live up to the proclaimed goal in the resolution that they passed. This is illustrated in Figure 3 that considers only negotiations in C1 and looks only at those cases where a country voted in favor of a resolution. As can be seen from the figure, while the EU, Japan, Canada and Australia reduced their emissions by more than required by the resolutions, India, South Africa, Russia, and China reduced their emissions much less. The USA did not reduce them at all, and Saudi Arabia even increased their emissions on average in the years 2030–2050.

Figure 3: 
Proclaimed goal versus actual reductions of each country in C1. The left bars depict the average announced reduction in those resolutions that the country voted for, the right bars depict the average actual reductions in all cases in which the country voted for the resolution.
Figure 3:

Proclaimed goal versus actual reductions of each country in C1. The left bars depict the average announced reduction in those resolutions that the country voted for, the right bars depict the average actual reductions in all cases in which the country voted for the resolution.

The second reason is that resolutions are supported by fewer countries in C1 negotiations than in C2 negotiations. This is shown in Figure 4. While in C1 the resolution was passed on average by 80 percent of all countries, it was accepted by 93 percent in C2.

Figure 4: 
Fraction of countries that voted in favor of the resolution in Committee C1 and Committee C2 (averaged over all COP meetings).
Figure 4:

Fraction of countries that voted in favor of the resolution in Committee C1 and Committee C2 (averaged over all COP meetings).

Result 3:

In C2 significantly more countries support the resolution than in C1.

Result 3 is supported by a Fisher’s exact test, which shows that a nation is statistically significantly more likely to vote in favor of the resolution if it is in C2 than if it is in C1 (p = 0.029). We further run a binary logistic regression, including the voting behavior as dependent variable and the treatment as predictor variable. Being in C2 significantly increases the probability of voting Yes versus voting No (coefficient = 1.25, p = 0.041, odds ratio = 3.5).

Result 3 clearly refutes Hypothesis 3. This may be surprising at first glance. After all, in C1 each country is free to choose its nationally determined contribution. Thus, each country could simply vote for the resolution and then choose a much smaller reduction of its emissions than required by the resolution. In fact, this is what many countries did. However, some countries voted against the resolution, in particular the US (5 times), Russia (3 times), and Saudi Arabia (3 times), often because they wanted to make the point that the fight against climate change is harmful to their national interests. This reflects the fact that the Paris agreement was seen more critically in these countries at the time of the experiments than in 2015 when the Paris agreement was signed.

On the other hand, in C2, the agreed upon common carbon price is binding for all countries that supported the resolution. Thus, a country can free-ride only by rejecting the resolution. This suggests a lower acceptance rate in C2 than in C1. However, in the discussions and actual negotiations during the MUN conferences we frequently observed that countries opposed to carbon pricing used their participation in the resolution as a bargaining chip. The delegates of Russia and Saudi Arabia (and less frequently of the USA) argued that a high carbon price of the other countries (combined with a border adjustment tax) is a major threat to their interests as exporters of fossil fuels. At the same time, they recognized that the majority of nations is determined to introduce carbon pricing to mitigate climate change. Thus, they tried to keep the carbon price as low as possible by leveraging their vote for the overall resolution. They promised to vote for the resolution, if the other countries agreed to carbon prices that were not too high.[22] This strategy often proved successful. Our observation of the actual negotiations indicate that the other countries probably would have adopted substantially higher carbon prices, in particular in 2030, if countries like Russia, Saudi Arabia, and the USA had stayed out.

The developing countries, in particular India, South Africa, and to a lesser degree China, sometimes objected to the idea that they should impose the same carbon price as the developed countries. Two main arguments convinced them to participate. First, they realized that they will suffer most from climate change and thus have a strong interest to induce the other countries to mitigate it. Thus, they leveraged their vote by pressing for a higher carbon price. Second, the prospect of the Green Fund played a role in all negotiations (both C1 and C2), even though this was not part of the official agenda. Developing countries speculated that they will succeed in a later conference to convince richer countries to contribute to a Green Fund aiming to support developing countries in their efforts to combat climate change.

Another interesting finding is that the reductions of emissions are much more evenly distributed across countries in C2 than in C1. Figure 5 shows that the average reductions in each country for 2030–2050 are all between 12 and 22 percent if they negotiate a carbon price, while they fluctuate widely between almost 55 percent and minus 33 percent if parties rely on nationally determined contributions. In sum, this leads to an overall lower actual average reduction over 2030–2050 in Committee 1 (about 5 percent) compared to a high reduction in Committee 2 (about 20 percent). Thus, despite the large contributions by four countries in C1, the carbon emission reductions are still below the reductions in C2.

Figure 5: 
Reduction of emissions of each country in Committee C1 and Committee C2 in 2030–2050 (averaged over all COP meetings).
Figure 5:

Reduction of emissions of each country in Committee C1 and Committee C2 in 2030–2050 (averaged over all COP meetings).

Result 4:

There are substantial and highly significant differences in the reductions of emissions for 2030–2050 between countries in C1, while these differences are much smaller and statistically not significant in C2.

Result 4 confirms Hypothesis 4. It is supported by nonparametric Kruskal–Wallis tests, which indicate significant differences of emission reductions between the countries in C1 (H(9) = 103.15, p < 0.001), but not in C2 (H(9) = 1.53, p = 0.997). We further analyze the differences for each country separately. In a first step, we compare the differences in 2030–2050 between C1 and C2 for each country. Supported by two-sided Wilcoxon signed-rank tests, we find that CO2 emission reduction goals are significantly different between C1 and C2 for all countries, except India and South Africa. In a second step, we run one-sided tests to further explore those eight countries showing significant differences. One-sided Wilcoxon signed-rank tests reveal that for the EU, Japan, Canada, and Australia, CO2 emission reduction goals are significantly higher in C1 than in C2. On the contrary, the CO2 emission reduction goals for China, Russia, Saudi Arabia, and the USA are significantly higher in C2 than in C1.

Result 4 is partially imposed by the negotiation design. In C2, countries have to agree to a uniform minimum price for carbon, so all countries that agree to the resolution automatically impose the same carbon price that yields the same reduction of emissions. During the negotiations in C2, some countries like the EU and Japan announced that they were willing to voluntarily impose a higher carbon price than the minimum carbon price agreed upon in the Resolution, but this was not accounted for in the actual emission reductions. If the negotiation protocol would have allowed for voluntary higher commitments in C2, this would have led to a less equal distribution of reductions and it might have further increased overall emissions in C2.[23]

It is interesting to compare the experimental outcomes for the different countries to the real nationally determined contributions listed by these countries in the Annexes to the Paris agreement. However, countries have lot discretion how to list and count their contributions, and not all countries submitted their NDC. Climate Action Tracker (CAT)[24] is an independent scientific analysis platform that tracks government climate action over time. Through its analyses and estimates, CAT helps to compare officially submitted NDCs. In the Appendix, we compare the real NDCs of the Paris Agreement available at the time of our experiments (as measured by CAT) to the average behavior in C1 for 2030 and 2050. As can be seen in Table A.6, the large majority of the pledges in C1 are very close to the NDC counterparts. This confirms that the subjects took their roles in the simulated negotiations seriously.

6 Conclusions

MUN simulations are a novel experimental method that combines some of the advantages of laboratory and field experiments. They provide a formally structured framework that makes it possible to observe the outcomes of many simulated COP conferences on the same topic that were held under the exact same rules, with tight control over the preparation and the information provided to the participants. Thus, MUN conferences allow the experimenter to apply similarly high standards of replicability as in lab experiments, while at the same time enriching the experimental context and making the negotiations more realistic. This increases external validity. MUN simulations do not use monetary incentives but rely on the intrinsic motivation of the participants to engage with a complex topic and to represent “their” nation as genuinely as possible. This may be closer to the motivation of real delegates than paying the subjects small amounts of money for a narrowly defined performance.[25] The lively and dynamic debating process allows researchers to account for the complexity of negotiation processes and to collect data on a variety of interesting variables, as for instance which arguments are used, which coalitions are formed (and abandoned), and which strategies are employed. These observations are insightful, but it is sometimes difficult to draw statistically validated conclusions from them.

Of course, the new method also has its drawbacks. It requires a large organizational effort which limits the number of observations. Furthermore, the increase of external validity goes along with less control and thereby less internal validity of the experiment as compared to the lab.

Despite these drawbacks, MUN simulations can provide valuable empirical information in addition to lab experiments and case studies. Result 1 shows that negotiating a common commitment on a uniform carbon price is more successful in reducing carbon emissions in the long run than negotiating a non-binding common goal that has to be achieved by individual commitments, confirming the lab experiment of Schmidt and Ockenfels (2021). Thus, our experiment provides causal evidence that the negotiation setup affects the reductions of carbon emissions.

There are several other results that have important implications. First, Result 2 shows that the individual commitments (as in Paris style negotiations) do not live up to the non-binding common goal that the parties agreed upon. This is directly in line with projections of the Paris agreement (e.g. Clémençon 2016, Rogelj et al. 2016, Jiang et al. 2019, UNEP 2019) showing that the intended nationally determined pledged CO2 emission reductions are not sufficient to reach the two-degree-goal.

Result 3 shows that participation in the agreement is higher if a uniform carbon price is negotiated. This result is surprising as it is less costly for the nations to join a nonbinding agreement, such as the Paris Agreement, as compared to a binding agreement, such as on a uniform global carbon price. However, a uniform carbon price limits free-riding because fossil fuel producers can leverage their participation for keeping the carbon price low.

Our final Result 4 shows that in C1 some countries (e.g. EU, Japan, Canada, and Australia) frequently reduced their emissions by more than the common goal, while other countries (e.g. Russia, Saudi Arabia, and the USA) contributed very little. The uniform carbon price in C2 forced all participating countries to contribute the same. Countries were not allowed to register additional voluntary climate action in the resolution. The discussions in C2 and the results of C1 showed, however, that some countries would have been prepared to do much more. This might have further increased the effectiveness of the carbon price negotiations.

Taken together our results lend some support for the proposal to focus international climate negotiations on a uniform carbon price. However, additional research is required to test the validity of this proposal. Furthermore, it is important to study how to best negotiate a Green Fund that is necessary to support developing countries in their efforts to combat and deal with climate change. These problems have been left aside in our study. Finally, it would be very interesting to study the dynamic features of different negotiation designs: Is it more difficult to achieve an upward spiral over time of individual commitments or of a uniform common commitment?


Corresponding author: Klaus M. Schmidt, Department of Economics, University of Munich, Ludwigstraße 28, D-80539 Munich, Germany, E-mail:
We would like to thank Friedrich Breyer, Uwe Cantner, Ernst Fehr, Michael Gerfin, Jonas Meier, Axel Ockenfels, Doina Radulescu, Tobias Regner, Asri Özgümüs, Wladislaw Mill, Ralph Winkler, the editor and two anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions. Financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft through CRC TRR 190 (project number 280092119) is gratefully acknowledged. Tanja Mitric, Timothy Rabozzi, Friederike Reichel, and Gabriel Vollert provided excellent research assistance. Moreover, we would like to thank the following MUN Associations for their support: Model United Nations University of Bern, ETH Model United Nations, MUN Team UZH, Model United Nations TU Munich e.V., MUNAM e.V., Model United Nations Mannheim e.V., Cologne MUN Society e.V., and United Nations Hochschulgruppe Tübingen.

Award Identifier / Grant number: CRC TRR 190, project number 280092119

  1. Article Note: This article is part of the special issue “A New Decade of Research on the Economics of Climate Change: Towards an Integrated View on a Sustainable Use of the Biosphere” published in the Journal of Economics and Statistics. Access to further articles of this special issue can be obtained at www.degruyter.com/jbnst.

References

Asal, V. (2005). Playing games with international relations. Int. Stud. Perspect. 6: 359–373, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1528-3577.2005.00213.x.Search in Google Scholar

Barrett, S. (1994). Self-enforcing international environmental agreements. Oxf. Econ. Pap. 46: 878–894.10.1093/oep/46.Supplement_1.878Search in Google Scholar

Barrett, S. (2003). Environment and statecraft: the strategy of environmental treaty-making. Oxford University Press, Oxford.10.1108/meq.2003.14.5.622.3Search in Google Scholar

Barrett, S. (2005). The theory of international environmental agreements. In: Mäler, K.G. and Vincent, J.R. (Eds.), Handbook of environmental economics: vol. 3, economywide and international environmental issues. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 1457–1516.10.1016/S1574-0099(05)03028-7Search in Google Scholar

Barrett, S. and Dannenberg, A. (2016). An experimental investigation into ‘pledge and review’ in climate negotiations. Clim. Change 138: 339–351, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-016-1711-4.Search in Google Scholar

Battaglini, M. and Harstad, B. (2016). Participation and duration of environmental agreements. J. Polit. Econ. 124: 160–204.10.1086/684478Search in Google Scholar

Battaglini, M. and Harstad, B. (2020). The political economy of weak treaties. J. Polit. Econ. 128: 544–590, https://doi.org/10.1086/704610.Search in Google Scholar

Boardman, R. (1969). The theory and practice of educational simulation. Educ. Res. 11: 179–184, https://doi.org/10.1080/0013188690110302.Search in Google Scholar

Clémençon, R. (2016). The two sides of the Paris climate agreement. J. Environ. Dev. 25: 3–24, https://doi.org/10.1177/1070496516631362.Search in Google Scholar

Dannenberg, A. and Gallier, C. (2020). The choice of institutions to solve cooperation problems: a survey of experimental research. Exp. Econ. 23: 716–749, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-019-09629-8.Search in Google Scholar

Dannenberg, A., Lange, A., and Sturm, B. (2014). Participation and commitment in voluntary coalitions to provide public goods. Economica 81: 257–275, https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12073.Search in Google Scholar

Edenhofer, O. (Ed.) (2014). Climate change 2014: mitigation of climate change: working group III contribution to the fifth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Search in Google Scholar

Harrison, G.W. and List, J.A. (2004). Field experiments. J. Econ. Lit. 42: 1009–1055, https://doi.org/10.1257/0022051043004577.Search in Google Scholar

Jiang, X., Peters, G.P., and Green, C. (2019). Global rules mask the mitigation challenge facing developing countries. Earth’s Future 7: 428–432, https://doi.org/10.1029/2018EF001078.Search in Google Scholar

Kauneckis, D.L. and Auer, M.R. (2013). A simulation of international climate regime formation. Simulat. Gaming 44: 302–327, https://doi.org/10.1177/1046878112470542.Search in Google Scholar

Kocher, M.G., Martinsson, P., Persson, E., and Wang, X. (2016). Is there a hidden cost of imposing a minimum contribution level for public good contributions? J. Econ. Psychol. 56: 74–84, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2016.05.007.Search in Google Scholar

Kosfeld, M., Okada, A., and Riedl, A. (2009). Institution formation in public goods games. Am. Econ. Rev. 99: 1335–1355.10.1257/aer.99.4.1335Search in Google Scholar

Lester, J.P. and Stoil, M.J. (1979). Evaluating a role-specific simulation. Simulat. Game. 10: 167–181, https://doi.org/10.1177/104687817901000203.Search in Google Scholar

List, J. (2020). Non est disputandum de generalizability? A glimpse into the external validity trial. NBER Working Paper No. 27535.10.3386/w27535Search in Google Scholar

MacKay, D.J.C., Cramton, P., Ockenfels, A., and Stoft, S. (2015). Price carbon – I will if you will. Nature 526: 315–316, https://doi.org/10.1038/526315a.Search in Google Scholar

Martinsson, P. and Persson, E. (2019). Public goods and minimum provision levels: does the institutional formation affect cooperation? Scand. J. Econ. 121: 1473–1499, https://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12321.Search in Google Scholar

Matzner, N. and Herrenbrück, R. (2017). Simulating a climate engineering crisis. Simulat. Gaming 48: 268–290, https://doi.org/10.1177/1046878116680513.Search in Google Scholar

Muldoon, J.P. (1995). The model united nations revisited. Simulat. Gaming 26: 27–35.10.1177/1046878195261003Search in Google Scholar

Nordhaus, W. (2015). Climate clubs: overcoming free-riding in international climate policy. Am. Econ. Rev. 105: 1339–1370, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.15000001.Search in Google Scholar

Nordhaus, W. (2019). Climate change: the ultimate challenge for economics. Am. Econ. Rev. 109: 1991–2014, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.109.6.1991.Search in Google Scholar

Penetrante, A.M. (2012). Simulating climate change negotiations: lessons from modeled experience. Negot. J. 28: 279–314, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1571-9979.2012.00341.x.Search in Google Scholar

Rogelj, J., den Elzen, M., Höhne, N., Fransen, T., Fekete, H., Winkler, H., Schaeffer, R., Sha, F., Riahi, K., and Meinshausen, M. (2016). Paris agreement climate proposals need a boost to keep warming well below 2 °C. Nature 534: 631 EP, https://doi.org/10.1038/nature18307.Search in Google Scholar

Rooney-Varga, J.N., Sterman, J.D., Fracassi, E., Franck, T., Kapmeier, F., Kurker, V., Johnston, E., Jones, A.P., and Rath, K. (2018). Combining role-play with interactive simulation to motivate informed climate action: evidence from the world climate simulation. PLoS One 13: e0202877, https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0202877.Search in Google Scholar

Schelling, T.C. (1960). The Strategy of conflict. Harvard University Presss, Cambridge, Mass.Search in Google Scholar

Schmidt, K.M. and Ockenfels, A. (2021). Focusing climate negotiations on a uniform common commitment can promote cooperation. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U. S. A. 118: 1–6.10.1073/pnas.2013070118Search in Google Scholar

Schwardmann, P., Tripodi, E., and Van der Weele, J.J. (2022). Self-persuasion: evidence from international debating competitions. Am. Econ. Rev. 112: 1118–1146.10.1257/aer.20200372Search in Google Scholar

Stiglitz, J.E., Stern, N., Duan, M., Edenhofer, O., Giraud, G., Heal, G.M., La Rovere, E.L., Morris, A., Moyer, E., Pangestu, M., et al.. (2017). Report of the high-level commission on carbon prices. International Bank for Reconstruction and Development and International Development Association/The World Bank, New York.Search in Google Scholar

UNEP (2019). Emissions gap report 2019, Nairobi, Available at: https://www.unenvironment.org/resources/emissions-gap-report-2019.Search in Google Scholar

UNFCCC Secretariat (2015). Synthesis report on the aggregate effect of the intended nationally determined contributions, Available at: https://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2015/cop21/eng/07.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Voslinsky, A. and Azar, O.H. (2021). Incentives in experimental economics. J. Behav. Exp. Econ. 93: 101706, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2021.101706.Search in Google Scholar

Weitzman, M.L. (2014). Can negotiating a uniform carbon price help to internalize the global warming externality? J. Assoc. Environ. Resour. Econ. 1: 29–49, https://doi.org/10.1086/676039.Search in Google Scholar

Weitzman, M.L. (2015). Internalizing the climate externality: can a uniform price commitment help? Econ. Energy Environ. Policy 4: 37–50, https://doi.org/10.5547/2160-5890.4.2.mwei.Search in Google Scholar

Weitzman, M.L. (2017a). On a world climate assembly and the social cost of carbon. Economica 84: 559–586, https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12248.Search in Google Scholar

Weitzman, M.L. (2017b). Voting on prices vs. Voting on quantities in a world climate assembly. Res. Econ. 71: 199–211, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rie.2016.10.004.Search in Google Scholar


Supplementary Material

The online version of this article offers supplementary material (https://doi.org/10.1515/jbnst-2021-0054).


Received: 2021-10-28
Accepted: 2022-07-21
Published Online: 2022-09-09
Published in Print: 2023-10-26

© 2022 the author(s), published by De Gruyter, Berlin/Boston

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

Downloaded on 4.12.2023 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/jbnst-2021-0054/html
Scroll to top button