Abstract
This paper compares the all-or-nothing and proportionate damage rules for allocating damages in tort cases under evidentiary uncertainty. The focus is on how the two rules affect litigation expenditures by plaintiffs and defendants. The results of simulation experiments show that the expected judgment at trial is higher under the all-or-nothing rule for cases where the defendant did not take adequate care, but the judgment is higher under the proportionate rule when the defendant took more than adequate care. As for litigation expenditures, assuming equal costs of litigation, overall expenditures are higher under the all-or-nothing rule, except for very weak and very strong cases.
Appendix
With respect to the all-or-nothing rule, the first-order conditions for X and Y are:
From these conditions, it follows that
Putting this result back into the first-order conditions gives us the equilibrium expenditures for the plaintiff and defendant, respectively:
The expected value of trial for the plaintiff under this rule is
while the expected cost of trial for the defendant is
Under the proportional rule, the antiderivative of
equals
The first-order conditions are:
from which it follows that
Putting this result back in the first-order conditions gives us the Nash equilibrium effort levels of the two parties:
The resulting total expenditures of the plaintiff and the defendant, respectively, are
The expected judgment equals:
The expected value of trial for the plaintiff is
while the expected loss of the defendant equals:
Acknowledgement
We acknowledge the helpful comments of a reviewer and Francesco Parisi (the editor).
Bibliography
Abramowicz, Michael. 2001. “A Compromise Approach to Compromise Verdicts,” 89California Law Review231–313.10.2307/3481297Search in Google Scholar
Allen, Francis A., et al. 1964. “Comments on “Approaches to Court Imposed Compromise-the Uses of Doubt and Reason,” 58Northwestern University Law Review795–805.Search in Google Scholar
Katz, A. 1988. “Judicial Decisionmaking and Litigation Expenditure,” 8International Review of Law and Economics127–143.10.1016/0144-8188(88)90001-4Search in Google Scholar
Kaye, David H. 1982. “The Limits of the Preponderance of the Evidence Standard: Justifiably Naked Statistical Evidence and Multiple Causation,” 7American Bar Foundation Research Journal487–516.10.1111/j.1747-4469.1982.tb00464.xSearch in Google Scholar
Leshem, Shmuel, and Geoffrey MMiller. 2009. “All-or-Nothing Versus Proportionate Damages,” 38Journal of Legal Studies345–382.10.1086/593153Search in Google Scholar
Levmore, Saul. 1990. “Probabilistic Recoveries, Restitution, and Recurring Wrongs,” 19Journal of Legal Studies691–726.10.1086/467867Search in Google Scholar
Orloff, Neil, and JeryStedinger. 1983. “A Framework for Evaluating the Preponderance-of-the-Evidence Standard,” 131University of Pennsylvania Law Review1159–1174.10.2307/3311937Search in Google Scholar
Priest, George, and BenjaminKlein. 1984. “The Selection of Disputes for Litigation,” 13Journal of Legal Studies1–55.10.1086/467732Search in Google Scholar
Sanchirico, Christopher. 2001. “Relying on the Information of Interested – And Potentially Dishonest- Parties,” 3American Law and Economics Review320–357.Search in Google Scholar
Shavell, Steven. 1985. “Uncertainty Over Causation and the Determination of Civil Liability,” 28Journal of Law and Economics587–609.10.1086/467102Search in Google Scholar
©2015 by De Gruyter