Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter February 21, 2015

Comparing All-or-Nothing and Proportionate Damages: A Rent-Seeking Approach

  • Jef De Mot and Thomas J. Miceli EMAIL logo
From the journal Review of Law & Economics

Abstract

This paper compares the all-or-nothing and proportionate damage rules for allocating damages in tort cases under evidentiary uncertainty. The focus is on how the two rules affect litigation expenditures by plaintiffs and defendants. The results of simulation experiments show that the expected judgment at trial is higher under the all-or-nothing rule for cases where the defendant did not take adequate care, but the judgment is higher under the proportionate rule when the defendant took more than adequate care. As for litigation expenditures, assuming equal costs of litigation, overall expenditures are higher under the all-or-nothing rule, except for very weak and very strong cases.

JEL Classification: K13; K41

Appendix

With respect to the all-or-nothing rule, the first-order conditions for X and Y are:

FXF+(1F)YJXF2(XF+(1F))2J=CpXF(1F)(XF+(1F)Y)2J=Cd

From these conditions, it follows that

Y=CpCdX

Putting this result back into the first-order conditions gives us the equilibrium expenditures for the plaintiff and defendant, respectively:

CpX=CpF(1F)CdF+(1F)CpCd2JCdY=CpF(1F)CdF+(1F)CpCd2J

The expected value of trial for the plaintiff under this rule is

PX,YJCpX=FF+(1F)CpCdJCpF(1F)CdF+(1F)CpCd2J

while the expected cost of trial for the defendant is

PX,YJ+CdY=FF+(1F)CpCdJ+CpF(1F)CdF+(1F)CpCd2J

Under the proportional rule, the antiderivative of

P0XFP0XF+(1P0)Y(1F)

equals

XF((XFY(1F))P0Y(1F)ln((XFY(1F))P0+Y(1F))(XFY(1F))2

The first-order conditions are:

2XF2F(1F)Y+YF(1F)(ln(Y(1F)ln(XF)))YF(1F)(XFY(1F))2J2XF(XFY(1F))+XYF(1F)(ln(Y(1F)ln(XF))(XFY(1F))3FJ=CpXF(1F)+XF(1F)(ln(Y(1F)ln(XF)))+XF(1F)(XFY(1F))2J+2XF(XFY(1F))+XYF(1F)(ln(Y(1F)ln(XF))(XFY(1F))3(1F)J=Cd

from which it follows that

Y=CpCdX

Putting this result back in the first-order conditions gives us the Nash equilibrium effort levels of the two parties:

X=2FCpCd(1F)+F+CpCd(1F)lnCpCd1FFCp(1F)CpCdF3CpCdF(1F)JY=2FCpCd(1F)+F+CpCd(1F)lnCpCd1FFCd(1F)CpCdF3CpCdF(1F)J

The resulting total expenditures of the plaintiff and the defendant, respectively, are

CpX=2FCpCd(1F)+F+CpCd(1F)lnCpCd1FF(1F)CpCdF3CpCdF(1F)JCdY=2(FCpCd(1F))+(F+CpCd(1F))lnCpCd1FF((1F)CpCdF)3CpCdF(1F)J

The expected judgment equals:

E(J)=F+(1F)CpCdlnCpCd1FF1F(1F)CpCd2FJ

The expected value of trial for the plaintiff is

F+(1F)CpCd(lnCpCd1FF1)F(1F)CpCd2FJ2FCpCd(1F)+F+CpCd(1F)lnCpCd1FF(1F)CpCdF3CpCdF(1F)J

while the expected loss of the defendant equals:

F+(1F)CpCdlnCpCd1FF1F(1F)CpCd2FJ+2FCpCd(1F)+F+CpCd(1F)lnCpCd1FF(1F)CpCdF3CpCdF(1F)J

Acknowledgement

We acknowledge the helpful comments of a reviewer and Francesco Parisi (the editor).

Bibliography

Abramowicz, Michael. 2001. “A Compromise Approach to Compromise Verdicts,” 89California Law Review231313.10.2307/3481297Search in Google Scholar

Allen, Francis A., et al. 1964. “Comments on “Approaches to Court Imposed Compromise-the Uses of Doubt and Reason,” 58Northwestern University Law Review795805.Search in Google Scholar

Katz, A. 1988. “Judicial Decisionmaking and Litigation Expenditure,” 8International Review of Law and Economics127143.10.1016/0144-8188(88)90001-4Search in Google Scholar

Kaye, David H. 1982. “The Limits of the Preponderance of the Evidence Standard: Justifiably Naked Statistical Evidence and Multiple Causation,” 7American Bar Foundation Research Journal487516.10.1111/j.1747-4469.1982.tb00464.xSearch in Google Scholar

Leshem, Shmuel, and Geoffrey MMiller. 2009. “All-or-Nothing Versus Proportionate Damages,” 38Journal of Legal Studies345382.10.1086/593153Search in Google Scholar

Levmore, Saul. 1990. “Probabilistic Recoveries, Restitution, and Recurring Wrongs,” 19Journal of Legal Studies691726.10.1086/467867Search in Google Scholar

Orloff, Neil, and JeryStedinger. 1983. “A Framework for Evaluating the Preponderance-of-the-Evidence Standard,” 131University of Pennsylvania Law Review11591174.10.2307/3311937Search in Google Scholar

Priest, George, and BenjaminKlein. 1984. “The Selection of Disputes for Litigation,” 13Journal of Legal Studies155.10.1086/467732Search in Google Scholar

Sanchirico, Christopher. 2001. “Relying on the Information of Interested – And Potentially Dishonest- Parties,” 3American Law and Economics Review320357.Search in Google Scholar

Shavell, Steven. 1985. “Uncertainty Over Causation and the Determination of Civil Liability,” 28Journal of Law and Economics587609.10.1086/467102Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2015-2-21
Published in Print: 2015-3-1

©2015 by De Gruyter

Downloaded on 10.12.2023 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/rle-2014-0058/html
Scroll to top button