Abstract
In the past couple of decades, scholars have predominantly employed rent-seeking models to analyze litigation problems. In this paper, we build on the existing literature to show how alternative fee-shifting arrangements (e.g., the American rule and English rule with limited fee-shifting) affect parties’ litigation expenditures and their decisions to litigate. Contrary to the prevailing wisdom, we discover that, when fee shifting is limited, the English rule presents some interrelated advantages over the American rule, including the reduction of litigation rates and the possible reduction of expected litigation expenditures. Our results unveil a hidden virtue of limited fee shifting, showing that an increase in such limit may lead to a desirable sorting of socially valuable litigation.
Appendix A: Subgame-Perfect Nash Equilibrium Under the American Rule
Following Farmer and Pecorino (1999), we show first that for
Similarly, the defendant is not willing to deviate if
Case 1.
Thus, when
Case 2.
Case 2.1:
If
Finally, if
Case 2.2:
If
If
The last case is the most problematic. If
Appendix B: Subgame-Perfect Nash Equilibria Under the English Rule with Limited Fee – Shifting
B.1 Proof of impossibility of Y ≤ d < X
We show the impossibility by contradiction. For this, we first assume that both inequalities hold true. Based on the consequential definitions of the parties’ payoffs, we then show that these investments cannot be a Nash equilibrium.
Suppose
With these payoffs, we get the following first order condition for the defendant:
which simplifies to
It is useful to write this as:
The defendant’s second order condition is:
If we replace
Hence,
We now turn to the plaintiff’s foc. It is given by:
Inserting eq. [36] yields:
Then by our initial assumption we have:
which implies
As we already know that
or
which contradicts the initial assumption. Hence, there is no equilibrium with
B.2 Equilibrium with X , Y > d
We first check whether investment levels
Similarly, the defendant does not deviate if and only is
Knowing that his payoff will be
The plaintiff, on the other hand, is willing to file if and only if the defendant will not defend her case in court or
Equations [39] and [40] represent respectively the defendant’s and the plaintiff’s participation constraints. When they are satisfied, investment levels
To see that for
which after some algebra reduces to
B.3 Equilibrium with X , Y < d
We prove first that, for
The rest of the argument is in the text.
B.4 Equilibrium with X = Y = d
To prove the conditions under which
To see that the plaintiff will not increase X above d when
for
with equality only for
To show that the plaintiff will not invest any much higher amount, we consider the second derivative of her payoff:
Obviously, this is strictly negative if
We now turn to the claim that neither of the parties will reduce expenditures below d if
into
Inserting this into the second derivative
implies
Hence, for
Since for equal investments the derivative
is positive for
If
By a symmetric argument for the defendant, we find that he also invests more than the plaintiff if
Suppose that the defendant invests
which for
which is obviously positive if
By a corresponding argument, we also get
with strict inequality for
B.5 Equilibrium with X < Y = d for μ < 1 or Y < X = d for μ > 1
To prove the various claims of Section 4.4, we first recall that according to eq. [48]
We call this solution
Since
To make sure that
By continuity, the inequality prevails if d slightly increases above
Hence we have
which strictly increases in
Hence, reducing Y slightly results in a larger and thus still positive first derivative. Reducing Y further step by step always results in ever larger first derivatives and thus negative second derivatives by exactly the argument of eqs [53] through [54]. Hence, the defendant always gains by increasing his investment until he invests d, which completes the proof of d being the best reply to
The symmetric argument works for
To prove the payoffs of eqs [30] and [31], note that eq. [51] implies
The other expressions in eqs [30] and [31] can be derived accordingly.
Finally, we show that for
which is but a rewritten form of eq. [51] and obviously declines in
and thus
where the last inequality follows from the fact that for
Acknowledgment
We thank Daniel Pi and Samuel Brylski for their most valuable research and editorial assistance. We are grateful to Giuseppe Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe Di Vita, Ted Eisenberg, Luigi Alberto Franzoni, Eric Langlais, Giovanni Battista Ramello, Filippo Roda, Avraham Tabbach, two anonymous referees and to participants to the 8th SIDE – ISLE Conference (Italian Society of Law and Economics) in Rome, to the Workshop In Law and Economics in Hamburg, February 2013, to the 2nd International Workshop on the Economics Analysis of Litigation, Catania, June 2014 and to seminars at the University of Paris Ouest, Nanterre, Dept. of Economics, at the University of Bologna, Dept. of Economics and at the Bucerius Law School, Hamburg, for helpful discussions.
References
Baumann, F. and T.Friehe. 2010. “Contingent Fees Meet the British Rule: An Exploratory Study,” 150Public Choice499–510.Search in Google Scholar
Baye, M. , D.Kovenock and C.G.De Vries. 2005. “Comparative Analysis of Litigation Systems: An Auction-Theoretic Approach,” 115Economic Journal583–601.Search in Google Scholar
Baik, K.H. and I.-G.Kim. 2007a. “Contingent Fees Versus Legal Expenses Insurance,” 27International Review of Law and Economics351–361.Search in Google Scholar
Baik, K.H. and I.-G.Kim. 2007b. “Equilibrium Contingent Compensation in Contests with Delegation,” 73Southern Economic Journal986–1002.Search in Google Scholar
Braeutigam, R. , B.Owen and J.Panzar. 1984. “An Economic Analysis of Alternative Fee-Shifting Systems,” 47Law and Contemporary Problems173–185.Search in Google Scholar
Bungard, B.C. 2006. “Fee! Fie! Foe! Fum!: I Smell the Efficiency of the English Rule: Finding the Right Approach to Tort Reform,” 31Seton Hall Legislative Journal 1–64.Search in Google Scholar
Chen, K.-P. and J.-S.Wang. 2007. “Fee-Shifting Rules in Litigation with Contingency Fees,” 23Journal of Law Economics and Organization519–546.Search in Google Scholar
Congleton, R.D. , A.L.Hillman and K.A.Konrad. 2008. 40 Years of Research on Rent-Seeking, Volume 2: Applications: Rent-Seeking in Practice. Berlin: Springer.Search in Google Scholar
Dari-Mattiacci, G. and F.Parisi. 2014. “Returns to Effort in Rent-Seeking Games,” 159Public Choice 12–37.Search in Google Scholar
Garoupa, N.M. and F.Parisi. 2006. “Should the Prosecutor Pay for Failure of Conviction?” Mimeo.Search in Google Scholar
Garoupa, N.M. and L.Echazu. 2012. “Why Not Adopt a Loser-Pays-All Rule in Criminal Litigation?,” 32International Review of Law and Economics 233–241.Search in Google Scholar
Hause, J.C. 1989. “Indemnity, Settlement, and Litigation, or I’ll Be Suing You,” 18The Journal of Legal Studies157–179.Search in Google Scholar
Higgins, R.S. , W.F.Shughart II and R.D.Tollison. 1985. “Free Entry and Efficient Rent-Seeking,” 46Public Choice247–258.Search in Google Scholar
Hillman, A.L. 2012. “Rent-Seeking,” in W.F.Shughart II, L.Razzolini, and M.Reksulak, eds. The Elgar Companion to Public Choice, 2nd Edition). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Search in Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, J. and E.Osborne. 2001. “Truth, Effort, and the Legal Battle,” 108Public Choice169–195.Search in Google Scholar
Hughes, J.W. and E.A.Snyder. 1995. “Litigation and Settlement Under the English and American Rules: Theory and Evidence,” 38Journal of Law and Economics225–250.Search in Google Scholar
Hyde, C.E. and P.L.Williams. 2002. “Necessary Costs and Expenditure Incentives Under the English Rule,” 22International Review of Law and Economics133–152.Search in Google Scholar
Kaplow, L. 1986. “Private Versus Social Costs in Bringing Suits,” 15Journal of Legal Studies371–385.Search in Google Scholar
Katz, A. 1987. “Measuring the Demand for Litigation: Is the English Rule Really Cheaper?,” 3Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization143–176.Search in Google Scholar
Katz, A. 1988. “Judicial Decisionmaking and Litigation Expenditure,” 8International Review of Law and Economics127–143.Search in Google Scholar
Kirstein, R. and D.Schmidtchen. 1997. “Judicial Detection Skill and Contractual Compliance,” 17International Review of Law and Economics, Elsevier509–520.Search in Google Scholar
Kritzer, H.M. 2002. “Lawyer Fees and Lawyer Behavior in Litigation: What Does the Empirical Literature Really Say?,” 80Texas Law Review 1943–1984.Search in Google Scholar
Kobayashi, B. and J.Lott. 1996. “In Defense of Criminal Defense Expenditures and Plea Bargaining,” 16International Review of Law and Economics397–416.Search in Google Scholar
Luppi, B. and F.Parisi. 2012. “Litigation and Legal Evolution: Does Procedure Matter?,” 152Public Choice181–201.Search in Google Scholar
Luppi, B. and F.Parisi. 2015. “Litigation as Rent-Seeking,” in R.Congleton and A.Hillman, eds. Companion to Rent – Seeking. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Search in Google Scholar
Menell, P. 1983. “A Note on Private Versus Social Incentives to Sue in a Costly Legal System,” 12Journal of Legal Studies41–52.Search in Google Scholar
Miceli, T.J. 2010. “Legal Change and the Social Value of Lawsuits,” 30International Review of Law and Economics203–208.Search in Google Scholar
Miceli, T.J. 2009. “Legal Change: Selective Litigation, Judicial Bias, and Precedent,” 38Journal of Legal Studies157–168.Search in Google Scholar
Parisi, F. 2002. “Rent-Seeking Through Litigation: Adversarial and Inquisitorial Systems Compared,” 22International Review of Law and Economics193–216.Search in Google Scholar
Reinganum, J.F. and L.L.Wilde. 1986. “Settlement, Litigation, and the Allocation of Litigation Costs,” 17RAND Journal of Economics557–566.Search in Google Scholar
Rowe, T.D. Jr . 1982. “The Legal Theory of Attorney Fee-Shifting: A Critical Overview,” Duke Law Journal, 651–680.Search in Google Scholar
Shavell, S. 1982. “The Social Versus the Private Incentive to Bring Suit in a Costly Legal System,” 11Journal of Legal Studies333–339.Search in Google Scholar
Shavell, S. 1997. “The Fundamental Divergence Between the Private and the Social Motive to Use the Legal System,” 26Journal of Legal Studies575–612.Search in Google Scholar
Tullock, G. 1975. “On the efficient organization of trials,” 28 Kyklos745–62.Search in Google Scholar
Tullock, G. 1980. “Efficient Rent-Seeking,” in J.Buchanan, G.Tollison and G.Tullock, eds. Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society. Austin: Texas Am University Press, 97–112.Search in Google Scholar
©2015 by De Gruyter