Abstract
Does the accuracy of verdicts improve or worsen if individual jurors on a panel are barred from deliberating prior to casting their votes? I study this question in a model where jurors can choose to exert costly effort to improve the accuracy of their individual decisions. I find that, provided the cost of effort is not too large, it is better to allow jurors to deliberate if jury size exceeds a threshold. For panels smaller than this threshold, it is more effective to instruct jurors to vote on the basis of their private information, without deliberations, and to use a simple majority rule to determine the collective decision (regardless of the voting rule used with deliberations). The smaller the cost of paying attention, the larger the threshold above which the switch to allowing deliberations becomes optimal. However, if the unanimity rule had to be maintained under the no-deliberations system, it would be better to allow deliberation. The results apply to binary decision making in any committee where the committee members incur some effort in reviewing the evidence. Examples are arbitration panels and tenure and promotion committees and some board of director meetings on issues such as whether to dismiss a CEO. As an extension I consider the case where jurors differ in their costs of effort.
References
Austen-Smith, D., and J.S Banks. 1996. “Information Aggregation, Rationality, and the Condorcet Jury Theorem,” 90 American Political Science Review 34–45.10.2307/2082796Search in Google Scholar
Austen-Smith, D., and T.J Fedderson. 2006. “Deliberation, Preference Uncertainty, and Voting Rules,” 100 American Political Science Review 209–217.10.1017/S0003055406062113Search in Google Scholar
Buechel, B, and L. Mechtenburg. 2016. “The Swing Voter’s Curse in Social Networks,” working paper.10.2139/ssrn.2910905Search in Google Scholar
Cai, H. 2009. “Costly Participation and Heterogeneous Preferences in Informational Committees,” 40 RAND Journal of Economics 173–189.10.1111/j.1756-2171.2008.00060.xSearch in Google Scholar
Coughlan, P.J. 2000. “In Defense of Unanimous Jury Verdicts: Mistrials, Communication and Strategic Voting,” 94 American Political Science Review 375–393.10.2307/2586018Search in Google Scholar
Fedderson, T., and W. Pesendorfer. 1998. “Convicting the Innocent: the Inferiority of Unanimous Jury Verdicts under Strategic Voting,” 92 American Political Science Review 23–35.10.2307/2585926Search in Google Scholar
Guha, B. 2011. “Preferences, Prisoners and Private Information: Was Socrates Rational at His Trial?” 31 European Journal of Law and Economics 249–264.10.1007/s10657-010-9151-5Search in Google Scholar
Guha, B. 2018. “Secret Ballots and Costly Information Gathering: the Jury Size Problem Revisited,” 54 International Review of Law and Economics 58–67.10.1016/j.irle.2017.10.005Search in Google Scholar
Hansen, M.H. 1991. The Athenian Democracy in the Age of Demosthenes: Structure, Principles and Ideology. Oxford, UK and Cambridge, USA: Blackwell.Search in Google Scholar
Helland, E., and Y. Raviv. 2008. “The Optimal Jury Size When Jury Deliberation Follows a Random Walk,” 134 Public Choice 255–262.10.1007/s11127-007-9222-5Search in Google Scholar
Hummel, P. 2012. “Deliberation in Large Juries with Diverse Preferences,” 150 Public Choice 595–608.10.1007/s11127-010-9718-2Search in Google Scholar
Koriyama, Y., and B. Szentes. 2009. “A Resurrection of the Condorcet Jury Theorem,” 4 Theoretical Economics 227–252.Search in Google Scholar
Leib, E.J. 2007. “A Comparison of Criminal Jury Decision Rules in Democratic Countries,” 5 Ohio State Journal of Criminal Law 629–644.Search in Google Scholar
Luppi, B., and F. Parisi. 2013. “Jury Size and the Hung Jury Paradox,” 42 Journal of Legal Studies 399–422.10.1086/670692Search in Google Scholar
Martinelli, C. 2006. “Would Rational Voters Acquire Costly Information?” 129 Journal of Economic Theory 225–251.10.1016/j.jet.2005.02.005Search in Google Scholar
McCannon, B. 2011. “Jury Size in Classical Athens: an Application of the Condorcet Jury Theorem,” 64 Kyklos 106–121.10.1111/j.1467-6435.2010.00497.xSearch in Google Scholar
McCannon, B., and P. Walker. 2016. “Endogenous Competence and a Limit to the Condorcet Jury Theorem,” No (16-12), Department of Economics, West Virginia University.10.1007/s11127-016-0366-zSearch in Google Scholar
Mukhopadhyaya, K. 2003. “Jury Size and the Free Rider Problem,” 19 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 24–44.10.1093/jleo/19.1.24Search in Google Scholar
Neilson, W., and H. Winter. 2008. “Votes Based on Protracted Deliberations,” 67 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 308–321.10.1016/j.jebo.2006.10.007Search in Google Scholar
Persico, N. 2004. “Committee Design with Endogenous Information,” 71 Review of Economic Studies 165–191.10.1111/0034-6527.00280Search in Google Scholar
Salerno, J.M, and S.S Diamond. 2010. “The Promise of a Cognitive Perspective on Jury Deliberation,” 17 Psychonomic Bulletin and Review 174–179.10.3758/PBR.17.2.174Search in Google Scholar
Triossi, M. 2013. “Costly Information Acquisition: Is It Better to Toss a Coin?” 82 Games and Economic Behavior 169–191.10.1016/j.geb.2013.07.008Search in Google Scholar
© 2020 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston