Abstract
Behavioral economics has highlighted the impact of various biases on economic outcomes. This essay reviews how biases have been incorporated into economic models of the law and the resulting implications for the assessment of different legal rules and policies. It focuses on two contexts. The first concerns biases that affect consumer purchases of risky products. Using a standard accident model that incorporates various forms of consumer bias, we discuss how bias can affect the efficient assignment of liability for product-related accidents. The second context concerns biases that affect the administration of law, particularly regarding the adjudication of guilt, the lawmaking function of trials, and criminal sentencing. We examine procedural rules like precedent and sentencing guidelines, both of which are aimed at curtailing judicial bias.
Acknowledgments
We acknowledge the comments of Francesco Parisi.
This appendix proves that s
* < 1 in the present-bias model when β < 1. Equilibrium consumption in this case,
The derivative of this expression with respect to s gives
After substituting from (23) and (25), this becomes
Evaluating this expression at s = 1 gives
Finally, from (23) we have
from which it follows that (A4) is negative, thus proving that s * < 1.
References
Adelstein, R. (2017). The exchange order: property and liability as an economic system. Oxford University Press, New York.10.1093/oso/9780190694272.001.0001Search in Google Scholar
Arlen, J. (1998). Comment: the future of behavioral economic analysis of law. Vanderbilt Law Rev. 51: 1765–1788.Search in Google Scholar
Baniak, A. and Grajzl, P. (2017). Optimal liability when consumers mispredict product usage. Am. Law Econ. Rev. 19: 202–243.Search in Google Scholar
Bebchuk, L. (1984). Litigation and settlement under imperfect information. Rand J. Econ. 15: 404–415. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555448.Search in Google Scholar
Becker, G. (1968). Crime and punishment: an economic approach. J. Polit. Econ. 76: 169–217. https://doi.org/10.1086/259394.Search in Google Scholar
Champion, D. (1989). The U.S. sentencing guidelines: implications for criminal justice. Praeger, New York.Search in Google Scholar
Choi, A.H. and Spier, K. (2014). Should consumers be permitted to waive products liability? Product safety, private contracts, and adverse selection. J. Law Econ. Organ. 30: 734–766. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewt019.Search in Google Scholar
Cooter, R. and Kornhauser, L. (1980). Can litigation improve the law without the help of judges? J. Leg. Stud. 9: 139–163. https://doi.org/10.1086/467632.Search in Google Scholar
Cooter, R., Kornhauser, L., and Lane, D. (1979). Liability rules, limited information, and the role of precedent. Bell J. Econ. 10: 366–373. https://doi.org/10.2307/3003338.Search in Google Scholar
Cooter, R. and Rubinfeld, D. (1989). Economic analysis of legal disputes and their resolution. J. Econ. Lit. 27: 1067–1097.Search in Google Scholar
Friedman, L. (2004). Law in America: a short history. Modern Library, New York.Search in Google Scholar
Friehe, T., Rößler, C., and Dong, X. (2020). Liability for third-party harm when harm-inflicting consumers are present biased. Am. Law Econ. Rev. 22: 75–104. https://doi.org/10.1093/aler/ahz013.Search in Google Scholar
Gennaioli, N. and Shleifer, A. (2007a). The evolution of common law. J. Polit. Econ. 115: 43–68. https://doi.org/10.1086/511996.Search in Google Scholar
Gennaioli, N. and Shleifer, A. (2007b). Overruling and the instability of law. J. Comp. Econ. 35: 309–328. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2007.02.003.Search in Google Scholar
Goodman, J. (1978). An economic analysis of the evolution of the common law. J. Leg. Stud. 7: 393–406. https://doi.org/10.1086/467600.Search in Google Scholar
Gould, J. (1973). The economics of legal conflicts. J. Leg. Stud. 2: 279–300. https://doi.org/10.1086/467499.Search in Google Scholar
Gul, F. and Pesendorfer, W. (2001). Temptation and self-control. Econometrica 69: 1403–1435. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00252.Search in Google Scholar
Gul, F. and Pesendorfer, W. (2004). Self-control, revealed preference and consumption choice. Rev. Econ. Dynam. 7: 243–264. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.red.2003.11.002.Search in Google Scholar
Harris, J. (1970). On the economics of law and order. J. Polit. Econ. 78: 165–174. https://doi.org/10.1086/259616.Search in Google Scholar
Hay, B. and Spier, K. (2005). Manufacturer liability for harms caused to others. Am. Econ. Rev. 95: 1700–1711. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282805775014416.Search in Google Scholar
Heiner, R. (1986). Imperfect decisions and the law: on the evolution of legal precedent and rules. J. Leg. Stud. 15: 227–261. https://doi.org/10.1086/467812.Search in Google Scholar
Hylton, K. (1990). Litigation and legal error under negligence. J. Law Econ. Organ. 6: 433–452.Search in Google Scholar
Hylton, K. (1993). Asymmetric information and the selection of disputes for litigation. J. Leg. Stud. 22: 187–210. https://doi.org/10.1086/468172.Search in Google Scholar
Jolls, C. (1998). Behavioral economic analysis of redistributive legal rules. Vanderbilt Law Rev. 51: 1653–1677.10.1017/CBO9781139175197.012Search in Google Scholar
Jolls, C. and Sunstein, C. (2006). Debiasing through law. J. Leg. Stud. 35: 199–241. https://doi.org/10.1086/500096.Search in Google Scholar
Jolls, C., Sunstein, C., and Thaler, R. (1998). A behavioral approach to law and economics. Stanford Law Rev. 50: 1471–1550. https://doi.org/10.2307/1229304.Search in Google Scholar
Kaplow, L. (2011). On the optimal burden of proof. J. Polit. Econ. 119: 1104–1140. https://doi.org/10.1086/664614.Search in Google Scholar
Kornhauser, L. (1989). An economic perspective on stare decisis. Chic. Kent. Law Rev. 65: 63–92.Search in Google Scholar
Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Q. J. Econ. 112: 443–478. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355397555253.Search in Google Scholar
Landes, W. (1971). An economic analysis of the courts. J. Law Econ. 14: 61–107. https://doi.org/10.1086/466704.Search in Google Scholar
Landes, W. and Posner, R. (1985). A positive economic theory of products liability. J. Leg. Stud. 14: 535–567. https://doi.org/10.1086/467785.Search in Google Scholar
Landes, W. and Posner, R. (1987). The economic structure of Tort law. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.10.4159/harvard.9780674864030Search in Google Scholar
Luppi, B. and Parisi, F. (2009). Beyond liability: correcting optimism bias through tort law. Queen’s Law J. 35: 47–66.Search in Google Scholar
Luppi, B. and Parisi, F. (2018). Behavioral models of tort law. In: Teitelbaum, J. and Zeiler, K. (Eds.). Research handbook on behavioral Law and economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, pp. 221–246.10.4337/9781849805681.00017Search in Google Scholar
Macey, J. (1989). Internal and external costs and benefits of stare decisis. Chic. Kent. Law Rev. 65: 93–113.Search in Google Scholar
Miceli, T. (1990). Optimal prosecution of defendants whose guilt is uncertain. J. Law Econ. Organ. 6: 189–201.Search in Google Scholar
Miceli, T. (1991). Optimal criminal procedure: fairness and deterrence. Int. Rev. Law Econ. 11: 3–10. https://doi.org/10.1016/0144-8188(91)90022-6.Search in Google Scholar
Miceli, T. (2008). Criminal sentencing guidelines and judicial discretion. Contemp. Econ. Policy 26: 207–215.10.1111/j.1465-7287.2007.00065.xSearch in Google Scholar
Miceli, T. (2009a). Criminal procedure. In: Garoupa, N. (Ed.). Criminal law and economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, pp. 125–144.Search in Google Scholar
Miceli, T. (2009b). Legal change: selection litigation, judicial bias, and precedent. J. Leg. Stud. 38: 157–168. https://doi.org/10.1086/587439.Search in Google Scholar
Miceli, T. (2010). Legal change and the social value of lawsuits. Int. Rev. Law Econ. 30: 203–208. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irle.2010.04.002.Search in Google Scholar
Miceli, T. (2019). The paradox of punishment: reflections on the economics of criminal justice. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham, Switzerland.10.1007/978-3-030-31695-2Search in Google Scholar
Miceli, T. and Cosgel, M. (1994). Reputation and judicial decision making. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 23: 31–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-2681(94)90095-7.Search in Google Scholar
Miceli, T., Segerson, K., and Wang, S. (2015). Products liability when consumers vary in their susceptibility to harm and may misperceive risk. Contemp. Econ. Policy 33: 468–476. https://doi.org/10.1111/coep.12086.Search in Google Scholar
Parisi, F. and Smith, V.L. (Eds.) (2005). The law and economics of irrational behavior. Stanford University Press, Stanford.10.1515/9781503625174Search in Google Scholar
Png, I. (1986). Optimal damages and subsidies in the presence of legal error. Int. Rev. Law Econ. 6: 101–105. https://doi.org/10.1016/0144-8188(86)90042-6.Search in Google Scholar
Polinsky, A.M. and Rogerson, W. (1983). Products liability, consumer misperceptions, and market power. Bell J. Econ. 14: 581–589. https://doi.org/10.2307/3003659.Search in Google Scholar
Polinsky, A.M. and Shavell, S. (2007). The theory of public law enforcement. In: Polinsky, A. and Shavell, S. (Eds.), Handbook of law and economics, vol. 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 403–454.10.3386/w11780Search in Google Scholar
Polinsky, A.M. and Shavell, S. (2001). Corruption and optimal law enforcement. J. Publ. Econ. 81: 1–24. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0047-2727(00)00127-4.Search in Google Scholar
Posner, R. (2003). Economic analysis of law, 6th ed. New York: Aspen.Search in Google Scholar
Priest, G. (1977). Common law process and selection of efficient rules. J. Leg. Stud. 6: 65–82. https://doi.org/10.1086/467563.Search in Google Scholar
Priest, G. and Klein, B. (1984). The selection of disputes for litigation. J. Leg. Stud. 13: 1–55. https://doi.org/10.1086/467732.Search in Google Scholar
Reinganum, J. (1988). Plea bargaining and prosecutorial discretion. Am. Econ. Rev. 78: 713–728.Search in Google Scholar
Rizzo, M. (1987). Rules versus cost-benefit analysis in the common law. In: Dorn, J. and Manne, H. (Eds.). Economic liberties and the judiciary. George Mason University Press, Fairfax, VA.Search in Google Scholar
Rubin, P. (1977). Why is the common law efficient? J. Leg. Stud. 6: 51–63. https://doi.org/10.1086/467562.Search in Google Scholar
Segerson, K. and Tsvetanov, T. (2013). Regulation versus liability: a behavioral economics perspective. In: Miceli, T. and Baker, M. (Eds.). Research handbook on economic models of law. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, pp. 69–86.10.4337/9781781000151.00009Search in Google Scholar
Shavell, S. (1980). Strict liability versus negligence. J. Leg. Stud. 9: 1–25. https://doi.org/10.1086/467626.Search in Google Scholar
Shepherd, J. (2007). Blakely’s silver lining: sentencing guidelines, judicial discretion, and crime. Hastings Law J. 58: 533–589.Search in Google Scholar
Slovic, P., Fischhoff, B., and Lichtenstein, S. (1982). Facts versus fears: understanding perceived risk. In: Kahneman, D., Slovic, P. and Tversky, A. (Eds.). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 463–492.10.1017/CBO9780511809477.034Search in Google Scholar
Spence, M. (1977). Consumer misperceptions, product failure, and producer liability. Rev. Econ. Stud. 44: 561–572. https://doi.org/10.2307/2296908.Search in Google Scholar
Spier, K. (2007). Litigation. In: Polinsky, A. and Shavell, S. (Eds.), Handbook of law and economics, vol. 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 259–342.Search in Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. (1997). Behavioral analysis of law. Univ. Chic. Law Rev. 64: 1175–1195.10.2307/1600213Search in Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. (Ed.) (2000). Behavioral law & economics. Cambridge University Press, New York.10.1017/CBO9781139175197Search in Google Scholar
Tsvetanov, T. and Segerson, K. (2013). Re-evaluating the role of energy efficiency standards: a behavioral economics perspective. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 66: 347–362. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2013.04.006.Search in Google Scholar
Tsvetanov, T., Miceli, T., and Segerson, K. (2021). Products liability with temptation bias. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 186: 76–93. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2021.03.028.Search in Google Scholar
Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Science 185: 1124–1131. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.185.4157.1124.Search in Google Scholar
Ulen, T. (2013). Behavioral law and economics: law, policy, and science. Supreme Court Econ. Rev. 21: 5–42. https://doi.org/10.1086/675264.Search in Google Scholar
Whitman, D. (2000). Evolution of the common law and the emergence of compromise. J. Leg. Stud. 29: 753–781. https://doi.org/10.1086/468092.Search in Google Scholar
Zeiler, K. (2019). Mistakes about mistakes. Eur. J. Law Econ. 48: 9–27. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-018-9596-5.Search in Google Scholar
© 2021 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston