Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter Oldenbourg September 13, 2022

Gender Gap in Schooling and Wages: Effects of Foreign Capital and Education Subsidies

  • Ujjaini Mukhopadhyay EMAIL logo
From the journal Review of Economics

Abstract

The paper develops a two-sector full employment general equilibrium model with endogenous schooling decisions. It aims to evaluate the effects of educational demand management policies on gender inequality in schooling and wage inequality. The results point towards the role of social norms in shaping parental discrimination against girls’ education, which accentuates gender gap in schooling due to gender-neutral education subsidy and rise in household income induced by foreign capital inflow. The two policies are favourable for gender wage gap if the agricultural sector is more female labour intensive than the manufacturing sector and returns to schooling are considerably higher for women than men. However, gender targeted education subsidy policies are in general beneficial with respect to both gendered schooling and wages. The paper contributes to the literature by identifying the role of factor intensity conditions and gender differentiated returns to education on the gendered schooling and labour market outcomes of demand side interventions in education. It also provides theoretical explanations to diverse impacts of these policies and suggests appropriate policy recommendations.

JEL Classification: I28; J16; J31

Corresponding author: Ujjaini Mukhopadhyay, Associate Professor, Department of Economics, Behala College, 32, Upen Banerjee Road, Parnashree, Kolkata 700060, West Bengal, India, E-mail:

Appendix

Total differentiation of (18) and (19) and use of envelope conditions yields

(A.1) θ M 1 W ˆ M 1 + θ F 1 W ˆ F 1 = θ K 1 r ˆ 1

(A.2) θ M 2 W ˆ M 1 + θ F 2 W ˆ F 1 = θ K 2 r ˆ 1

It may be noted that producers in each industry choose techniques of production so as to minimise unit costs. This leads to the condition that the distributive-share weighted average of changes in input-output coefficients along the unit isoquant in each industry must vanish near the cost-minimisation point. This states that an isocost line is tangent to the unit isoquant. For example, in mathematical terms, the cost-minimisation condition for sector 1 may be written as: θ M 1 a ˆ M 1 + θ F 1 a ˆ F 1 + θ K 1 a ˆ K 1 = 0 . This is called the envelope condition. See Caves et al. (1990) and/or Chaudhuri and Mukhopadhyay (2009).

Solving (A.1) and (A.2) by Cramer’s rule, we get

(A.3) W ˆ M 1 = ( r ˆ 1 / | θ | ) [ ( θ F 1 θ K 2 θ K 1 θ F 2 ) ]

(A.4) W ˆ F 1 = ( r ˆ 1 / | θ | ) [ ( θ K 1 θ M 2 θ M 1 θ K 2 ) ]

where | θ | = ( θ M 1 θ F 2 θ F 1 θ M 2 ) .

Total differentiation of (20)(22), use of (A.3) and (A.4) and rearrangement gives,

(A.5) λ K 1 X ˆ 1 + λ K 2 X ˆ 2 + A 1 r ˆ 1 = K ˆ

(A.6) λ M 1 X ˆ 1 + λ M 2 X ˆ 2 + A 2 r ˆ 1 = 0

(A.7) λ F 1 X ˆ 1 + λ F 2 X ˆ 2 + A 3 r ˆ 1 = 0

where,

A 1 = ( 1 / | θ | ) [ ( θ F 1 θ K 2 θ K 1 θ F 2 ) ( λ K 1 S K M 1 + λ K 2 S K M 2 ) + ( θ K 1 θ M 2 θ M 1 θ K 2 ) ( λ K 1 S K F 1 + λ K 2 S K F 2 ) + ( θ M 1 θ F 2 θ F 1 θ M 2 ) ( λ K 1 S K K 1 + λ K 2 S K K 2 ) ]

(A.8) A 2 = ( 1 / | θ | ) [ ( θ F 1 θ K 2 θ K 1 θ F 2 ) ( λ M 1 S M M 1 + λ M 2 S M M 2 ) + ( θ K 1 θ M 2 θ M 1 θ K 2 ) ( λ M 1 S M F 1 + λ M 2 S M F 2 ) + ( θ M 1 θ F 2 θ F 1 θ M 2 ) ( λ M 1 S M K 1 + λ M 2 S M K 2 ) ]

A 3 = ( 1 / | θ | ) [ ( θ F 1 θ K 2 θ K 1 θ F 2 ) ( λ F 1 S F M 1 + λ F 2 S F M 2 ) + ( θ K 1 θ M 2 θ M 1 θ K 2 ) ( λ F 1 S F F 1 + λ F 2 S F F 2 ) + ( θ M 1 θ F 2 θ F 1 θ M 2 ) ( λ F 1 S F K 1 + λ F 2 S F K 2 ) ]

(A.9) Δ = A 3 ( λ K 1 λ M 2 λ M 1 λ K 2 ) + A 2 ( λ K 2 λ F 1 λ K 1 λ F 2 ) + A 1 ( λ M 1 λ F 2 λ F 1 λ M 2 )

There can be two alternative cases.

Case I: λ M 2 λ F 1 > λ M 1 λ F 2

Use of (A.8) in (A.9) yields that Δ > 0 if

(A.10.1) ( i ) ( a F 2 a M 2 ) < ( d a K i / d W F ) k ( d a K i / d W M ) k < ( a F 1 a M 1 ) ( ii ) ( a K 1 a M 1 ) < ( d a F i / d r ) k ( d a F i / d W M ) k < ( a K 2 a M 2 )

Case II: λ M 2 λ F 1 < λ M 1 λ F 2

Again using (A.8) in (A.9) yields that Δ < 0 if

(A.10.2) ( i ) ( a K 2 a F 2 ) > ( d a M i / d r ) k ( d a M i / d W F ) k > ( a K 1 a F 1 ) ( ii ) ( a M 1 a F 1 ) > ( d a K i / d W M ) k ( d a K i / d W F ) k > ( a M 2 a F 2 )

where i denotes the sector, i = 1, 2 and k denotes the period, k = 1, 2.

In (A.10.1), condition (i) implies that the relative responsiveness of capital-output ratio to changes in female and male wages lies between the female labour intensities (with respect to male labour) in both the sectors. Condition (ii) implies that the relative responsiveness of female labour-output ratio to changes in return to capital and male wages lies between the capital intensities (with respect to male labour) in both the sectors.

In (A.10.2), condition (i) implies that the relative responsiveness of male labour-output ratio to changes in return to capital and female wages lies between the capital intensities (with respect to female labour) in both the sectors. Condition (ii) implies that the relative responsiveness of capital-output ratio to changes in male and female wages lies between the male labour intensities (with respect to female labour) in both the sectors.

Period 1

Effect of Foreign Capital Inflow

It is assumed that K ˆ > 0 .

Solving (A.5)(A.7) by Cramer’s rule, one gets

(A.11) r ˆ 1 = ( 1 / Δ ) [ K ˆ ( λ M 1 λ F 2 λ F 1 λ M 2 ) ]

(A.12) Case I: When   λ M 2 λ F 1 > λ M 1 λ F 2 ,    we get   r ˆ 1   <   0    if   Δ   >   0

Case II: When λ M 2 λ F 1 < λ M 1 λ F 2 , we get r ˆ 1 < 0 if Δ < 0 .

Use of (A.11) in (A.3) and (A.4) yields

(A.13.1) W ˆ M 1 > 0  and  W ˆ F 1 < 0  when  λ M 2 λ F 1 > λ M 1 λ F 2

(A.13.2) W ˆ M 1   <   0   and   W ˆ F 1   >   0    when   λ M 2 λ F 1   <   λ M 1 λ F 2

Total differentiation of Equation (23) yields

(A.14) W ˆ I 1 = W ˆ M 1 W ˆ F 1

Use of (A.13.1) and (A.13.2) in (A.14) gives

(A.15) W ˆ I 1   >   0    when   λ M 2 λ F 1   >   λ M 1 λ F 2    if   Δ   >   0

W ˆ 1 I < 0 when λ M 2 λ F 1 < λ M 1 λ F 2 if Δ < 0 .

Totally differentiating (24) gives

(A.16) Y ˆ H = W ˆ M 1 + W ˆ F 1

Using (A.3), (A.4) and (A.11) in (A.16) gives

(A.17) Y ˆ H = ( K ˆ / | θ | Δ ) [ ( λ M 1 λ F 2 λ F 1 λ M 2 ) { θ K 2 ( θ F 1 θ M 1 ) + θ K 1 ( θ M 2 θ F 2 ) } ]

It follows from (A.17) that when K ˆ > 0

(A.18) Y ˆ H   >   0    when   λ M 2 λ F 1   >   λ M 1 λ F 2    if   Δ   >   0

Y ˆ H   >   0   when   λ M 2 λ F 1   <   λ M 1 λ F 2    if   Δ   <   0

Period 2

Totally differentiating (21.1) and (22.1) we get

(A.6.1) λ M 1 X ˆ 1 + λ M 2 X ˆ 2 + A 2 r ˆ 2 = h M ( G M Y Y ˆ H + G M E E ˆ )

(A.7.1) λ F 1 X ˆ 1 + λ F 2 X ˆ 2 + A 3 r ˆ 2 = h F 1 ( G F Y Y ˆ H + G F E E ˆ + G F E F E ˆ F )

Here r ˆ 2 denotes the return to capital in sector 2.

Solving (A.5), (A.6.1) and (A.7.1) by Cramer’s rule, one gets

(A.19) r ˆ 2 = ( Y ˆ H / Δ ) [ λ K 1 { λ M 2 h F G F Y λ F 2 h M G M Y } λ K 2 { λ M 1 h F G F Y λ F 1 h M G M Y } ] + ( E ˆ / Δ ) [ h F G F E ( λ K 1 λ M 2 λ M 1 λ K 2 ) + h M G M E ( λ K 2 λ F 1 λ K 1 λ F 2 ) ] + ( E ˆ F / Δ ) [ λ K 1 λ M 2 h F G F E F ]

Effect of Rise in Household Income Due to Foreign Capital Inflow

It has already been stated that Y ˆ H > 0 when K ˆ > 0 in period 1 (see (A.18)). The dynamic effects of a rise in household income in period 2 are examined under two alternative factor intensity conditions:

From Equation (A.19) it follows that when Y ˆ H > 0

Case I: r ˆ 2 > 0 when λ M 2 λ F 1 > λ M 1 λ F 2 if

(A.20.1) ( i ) ( λ M 2 / λ F 2 ) > ( h M G M Y / h F G F Y ) > ( λ M 1 / λ F 1 ) ( ii ) Δ > 0

Case II: r ˆ 2 > 0 when λ M 2 λ F 1 < λ M 1 λ F 2 if

(A.20.2) ( i ) ( λ M 2 / λ F 2 ) > ( h M G M Y / h F G F Y ) > ( λ M 1 / λ F 1 ) ( ii ) Δ < 0

From (A.3), (A.4) and (A.19) we get

(A.21.1) W ˆ M 2   <   0    and   W ˆ F 2   >   0   when   λ M 2 λ F 1   >   λ M 1 λ F 2   if   A. 20.1   holds

(A.21.2) W ˆ M 2   >   0    and   W ˆ F 2   <   0    when   λ M 2 λ F 1   <   λ M 1 λ F 2    if   A. 20.2   holds.

Totally differentiating Equation (27),

(A.22) W I 2 W ˆ I 2 = Y ˆ H ( W M 2 h M G M Y W F 2 h F G F Y ) + E ˆ ( W M 2 h M G M E W F 2 h F G F E ) E ˆ F W F 2 h F G F E F + W ˆ M 2 W M 2 h M ( G M ) W ˆ F 2 W F 2 h F ( G F )

We consider the effect on gender wage inequality under two alternative factor intensity conditions.

Use of (A.3), (A.4) and (A.19) in (A.22) gives that when Y ˆ H > 0

Case I: W ˆ I 2 < 0 when λ M 2 λ F 1 > λ M 1 λ F 2 if

(A.23.1) ( i ) W M 2 h M G M Y < W F 2 h F G F Y ( ii ) ( A. 20.1 )  holds

Case II: W ˆ I 2 > 0 when λ M 2 λ F 1 < λ M 1 λ F 2 if

(A.23.2) ( i ) W M 2 h M G M Y < W F 2 h F G F Y ( ii ) ( A. 20.2 )  holds

Effect of Gender-Neutral Education Subsidy

It is assumed that E ˆ > 0 .

From (A.19) it follows that when E ˆ > 0

Case I: r ˆ 2 > 0 when λ M 2 λ F 1 > λ M 1 λ F 2 if

(A.24.1) ( i ) ( λ M 2 / λ F 2 ) > ( h M G M E / h F G F E ) > ( λ M 1 / λ F 1 ) ( ii ) Δ > 0

Case II: r ˆ 2 > 0 when λ M 2 λ F 1 < λ M 1 λ F 2 if

(A.24.2) ( i ) ( λ M 2 / λ F 2 ) > ( h M G M E / h F G F E ) > ( λ M 1 / λ F 1 ) ( ii ) Δ < 0

From (A.3), (A.4) and (A.19) we get

(A.25.1) W ˆ M 2   <   0    and   W ˆ F 2   >   0    when   λ M 2 λ F 1   >   λ M 1 λ F 2    if   A. 24.1  holds.

(A.25.2) W ˆ M 2   >   0    and   W ˆ F 2   <   0    when   λ M 2 λ F 1   <   λ M 1 λ F 2   if   A. 24.2   holds.

Use of (A.3), (A.4) and (A.19) in (A.22) gives that when E ˆ > 0 .

We consider the effect on gender wage inequality under two alternative factor intensity conditions.

From (A.3), (A.4), (A.19) and (A.22) it follows that when E ˆ > 0

Case I: W ˆ I 2 < 0 when λ M 2 λ F 1 > λ M 1 λ F 2 if

(A.26.1) ( i ) W M 2 h M G M E < W F 2 h F G F E ( ii ) ( A . 24.1 )  holds

Case II: W ˆ I 2 > 0 when λ M 2 λ F 1 < λ M 1 λ F 2 if

(A.26.2) i   W M 2 h M G M E   >   W F 2 h F G F E ii   A. 24.2    holds

Effect of Gender-Targeted Education Subsidy

Now we assume that E ˆ F > 0 .

From (A.19) it follows that when E ˆ F > 0

(A.27.1) Case I:  r ˆ 2   >   0    when   λ M 2 λ F 1   >   λ M 1 λ F 2    if   Δ   >   0

(A.27.2) Case II:  r ˆ 2   <   0    when   λ M 2 λ F 1   >   λ M 1 λ F 2    if   Δ   <   0

From (A.3), (A.4) and (A.19) we get

(A.28.1) W ˆ M 2   <   0    and   W ˆ F 2   >   0    when   λ M 2 λ F 1   >   λ M 1 λ F 2    if   Δ   >   0

(A.28.2) W ˆ M 2   < 0    and   W ˆ F 2   >   0    when   λ M 2 λ F 1   >   λ M 1 λ F 2    if   Δ   <   0

From (A.3), (A.4), (A.19) and (A.22) it follows that when E ˆ F > 0

(A.29.1) Case I:   W ˆ I 2   <   0    when   λ M 2 λ F 1   >   λ M 1 λ F 2   if   Δ   >   0

(A.29.2) Case II:   W ˆ I 2   <   0    when   λ M 2 λ F 1   >   λ M 1 λ F 2    if   Δ   <   0

References

Alderman, H., Behrman, J.R., Ross, D., and Sabot, R. (1996). Decomposing the gender gap in cognitive skills in a poor rural economy. J. Hum. Resour. 31: 229–254, https://doi.org/10.2307/146049.Search in Google Scholar

Aslam, M. (2009). Education gender gaps in Pakistan: is the labor market to blame? Econ. Dev. Cult. Change 57: 747–784, https://doi.org/10.1086/598767.Search in Google Scholar

Baland, J.-M. and Robinson, J.A. (2000). Is child labor inefficient? J. Polit. Econ. 108: 663–679, https://doi.org/10.1086/316097.Search in Google Scholar

Becker, G.S. (1975). Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education, 2nd ed. Columbia University Press, New York and London.Search in Google Scholar

Becker, G.S. (1988). Family economics and macro behavior. Am. Econ. Rev. 78: 1–13, https://doi.org/10.1086/467147.Search in Google Scholar

Becker, G.S. and Tomes, N. (1976). Child endowments and the quantity and quality of children. J. Polit. Econ. 84: S143–62, doi:https://doi.org/10.3386/w0123.Search in Google Scholar

Behrman, J.R. and Knowles, J.C. (1999). Household income and child schooling in Vietnam. World Bank Econ. Rev. 13: 211–256, https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/13.2.211.Search in Google Scholar

Bhalotra, S. (2001). Parent altruism, Mimeograph, University of Bristol, Available at: <http://info.worldbank.org/etools/docs/voddocs/190/374/parent_altruism.pdf>.Search in Google Scholar

Björkman-Nyqvist, M. (2013). Income shocks and gender gaps in education: evidence from Uganda. J. Dev. Econ. 105: 237–253.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2013.07.013Search in Google Scholar

Blau, F.D. and Kahn, L.M. (2000). Gender differences in pay. J. Econ. Perspect. 14: 75–99, https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.14.4.75.Search in Google Scholar

Braunstein, E. (2006). Foreign direct investment, development and gender equity: a review of research and policy, Occasional paper 12. United Nations Research Institute for Social Development.Search in Google Scholar

Braunstein, E. and Brenner, M. (2007). Foreign direct investment and gendered wages in Urban China. Fem Econ 13: 213–237.10.1080/13545700701439432Search in Google Scholar

Bui, A.T., Nguyen, C.V., and Pham, T.P. (2019). Impact of foreign investment on household welfare: evidence from Vietnam. J. Asian Econ. 64, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.asieco.2019.07.003.Search in Google Scholar

Burça, K., Emel, M., Şirin, S., and Ebru, V. (2014). Changes in global trade patterns and women’s employment in manufacturing: An analysis over the period of Asianization and de-industrialization, Discussion Paper, No. 2014/1. Turkish Economic Association, Ankara.Search in Google Scholar

Burney, N.A. and Irfan, M. (1995). Determinants of child school enrolment: evidence from LDCs using choice theoretic approach. Int. J. Soc. Econ. 22: 24–40, https://doi.org/10.1108/03068299510075113.Search in Google Scholar

Cardoso, E. and Souza, A.P. (2003). The impact of cash transfers on child labor and school attendance in Brazil. Draft, Instituto de Estudos do Trabalho eSociedade, Brazil.Search in Google Scholar

Carneiro, P. and Heckman, J.J. (2004). Human capital policy. In: Heckman, J.J. and Krueger, A.B. (Eds.), Inequality in America. MIT Press, Cambridge.10.2139/ssrn.434544Search in Google Scholar

Caves, R.E., Frankel, J.A., and Jones, R.W. (1990). World trade and payments, 5th ed. London: Brown Higher Education, Scott, Foresman and Little.Search in Google Scholar

Chaudhuri, S. and Mukhopadhyay, U. (2009). Revisiting the informal sector: a general equilibrium approach. Springer, New York.10.1007/978-1-4419-1194-0Search in Google Scholar

Chaudhury, N. and Parajuli, D. (2010). Conditional cash transfers and female schooling: the impact of the female school stipend programme on public school enrollments in Punjab. Pakistan Appl. Econ. 42: 3565–3583, https://doi.org/10.1080/00036840802167376.Search in Google Scholar

Checchi, D., De Simone, G., and Ricardo, F. (2007). Skilled migration, FDI and human capital investment, Discussion Paper No. 2795. Institute for the Study of Labor, Bonn.10.2139/ssrn.987857Search in Google Scholar

Chesterfield, R. and Rubio, F.E. (1995). Incentives for the participation of Guatemalan indigenous girls in primary education: the first year of implementation of the EDUQUE A LA NINA project. Academy of Education Development.Search in Google Scholar

Chuang, E.K., Mensch, B.S., Psaki, S.R., Haberland, N.A., and Kozak, M.L. (2019). Policies and interventions to remove gender-related barriers to girls’ school participation and learning in low-and middle-income countries: a systematic review of the evidence. Campbell Syst. Rev. 15: e1047, https://doi.org/10.1002/cl2.1047.Search in Google Scholar

Das, M.B. and Desai, S. (2003). Why are educated women less likely to be employed in India? Testing competing hypotheses social protection, Discussion Paper Series No. 0313.Search in Google Scholar

Divakaran, S. (1996). Gender based wage and job discrimination in urban India. Indian J. Lab. Econ. 39: 235–258.Search in Google Scholar

Dougherty, C. (2005). Why are the returns to schooling higher for women than for men? J. Hum. Resour. 40: 969–988, https://doi.org/10.3368/jhr.xl.4.969.Search in Google Scholar

Duraisamy, P. and Duraisamy, M. (2005). Regional differences in Wage Premia and returns to education by gender in India. Indian J. Lab. Econ. 48: 335–347.Search in Google Scholar

Elvira, M. and Saporta, I. (2001). How does collective bargaining affect the gender pay gap? Work Occup. 28: 469–490, https://doi.org/10.1177/0730888401028004005.Search in Google Scholar

Erola, J. (2012). Family background and the life cycle effects of father’s class and income. In: Lambert, P., Connelly, R., Blackburn, B., and Gayle, V. (Eds.), Social stratification: Trends and processes. Ashgate, London.Search in Google Scholar

Evans, D.K. and Yuan, F. (2019). What we learn about girls’ education from interventions that don’t focus on girls, Policy Research working paper no. WPS 8944. World Bank Group, Washington, DC.10.1596/1813-9450-8944Search in Google Scholar

Eyal, K., Woolard, I., and Burns, J. (2014). Cash transfers and teen education: evidence from South Africa, Report, unpublished.Search in Google Scholar

Filmer, D. and Schady, N. (2011). Does more cash in conditional cash transfer programs always lead to larger impacts on school attendance? J. Dev. Econ. 96: 150–157, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2010.05.006.Search in Google Scholar

Fink, G. and Peet, E. (2014). Returns to education in low and middle-income countries: evidence from the living standards and measurement surveys, Program on The Global Demography of Aging (PGDA) Working Paper No. 120. Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.Search in Google Scholar

Gandhi Kingdon, G. (1998). Does the labour market explain lower female schooling in India? J. Dev. Stud. 35: 39–65, https://doi.org/10.1080/00220389808422554.Search in Google Scholar

Gandhi Kingdon, G. (2002). Education of women and socio-economic development. In: Reason and revelation: studies in the Babi and Baha’i religions, Vol. 13. Kalimat Press, Los Angeles.Search in Google Scholar

Garn, J.V., Leslie, E.G., Dreibelbis, R., Saboori, S., Rheingans, R.D., and Freeman, M.C. (2013). A cluster-randomized trial assessing the impact of school water, sanitation and hygiene improvements on pupil enrolment and gender parity in enrolment. J. Water, Sanit. Hyg. Dev. 3: 592–601, https://doi.org/10.2166/washdev.2013.217.Search in Google Scholar

Gittens, D. (2006). The effects of foreign direct investment on the accumulation of human capital in developing countries: are there implications for future growth? Fordham Economics Dissertations No. 3. Department of Economics, Fordham University, New York.Search in Google Scholar

Glick, P. (2008). What policies will reduce gender schooling gaps in developing countries: evidence and interpretation. World Dev. 36: 1623–1646, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2007.09.014.Search in Google Scholar

Glick, P. and Sahn, D.E. (2000). Schooling of girls and boys in a West African country: the effects of parental education, income, and household structure. Econ. Educ. Rev. 19: 63–87, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0272-7757(99)00029-1.Search in Google Scholar

Goldin, C. (2002). A pollution theory of discrimination: male and female occupations and earnings, NBER Working Paper No. 8985.10.3386/w8985Search in Google Scholar

Graham, E.M. (2000). Fighting the wrong enemy: antiglobal activists and multinational enterprises. Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC.Search in Google Scholar

Grimm, M. (2011). Does household income matter for children’s schooling? Evidence for rural SubSaharan Africa. Econ. Educ. Rev. 30: 740–754, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econedurev.2011.03.002.Search in Google Scholar

Hannum, E., Zhang, Y., and Wang, M. (2013). Why are returns to education higher for women than for men in urban China? China Q. 215: 616–640, https://doi.org/10.1017/S0305741013000696.Search in Google Scholar

Helble, M. and Takeda, A. (2020). Do women benefit from FDI? FDI and labor market outcomes in Cambodia. In: ADBI Working Paper Series No. 1093. Asian Development Bank Institute, Tokyo.Search in Google Scholar

Huffman, M. (2004). Gender inequality across local wage hierarchies. Work Occup. 21: 323–344, https://doi.org/10.1177/0730888404266384.Search in Google Scholar

ILO (2010). Women in labour markets: measuring progress and identifying challenges. International Labour Office, Geneva.Search in Google Scholar

Jacoby, H.G. and Skoufias, E. (1997). Risk, financial markets, and human capital in a developing country. Rev. Econ. Stud. 64: 311–335, https://doi.org/10.2307/2971716.Search in Google Scholar

Khandker, S., Pitt, M., and Fuwa, N. (2013). Subsidy to promote girls’ secondary education: the female stipend program in Bangladesh. Gender Impact - the World Bank’s Gender Impact Evaluation Database. World Bank, Washington, DC.Search in Google Scholar

Khandker, S.R., Samad, H.A., Fuwa, N., and Hayashi, R. (2021). The female secondary stipend and assistance program in Bangladesh: what did it accomplish? ADB South Asia Working Paper Series No. 81. Asian Development Bank, Mandaluyong.10.22617/WPS210021-2Search in Google Scholar

Kim, J., Alderman, H., and Orazem, P. (1999). Can private school subsidies increase enrollment for the poor? The quetta urban fellowship program. World Bank Econ. Rev. 13: 443–465, https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/13.3.443.Search in Google Scholar

King, E., Orazem, P., and Wohlgemuth, D. (1999). Central mandates and local incentives: the Colombia education voucher program. World Bank Econ. Rev. 13: 467–491, https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/13.3.467.Search in Google Scholar

Krueger, A.B. (2004). Inequality, too much of a good thing. In: Heckman, J.J. and Krueger, A.B. (Eds.), Inequality in America: What role for human capital policies? Edited with an introduction by Benjamin M. Friedman. Alvin Hansen Symposium on Public Policy series. MIT Press, Cambridge and London, pp. 1–75.10.4324/9780429494468-4Search in Google Scholar

Lemieux, T. (2008). The changing nature of wage inequality. J. Popul. Econ. 21: 21–48.10.3386/w13523Search in Google Scholar

Maluccio, J.A. (2003). Education and child labor: experimental evidence from a Nicaraguan conditional cash transfer program. In: Orazem, P.F., Sedlacek, G., and Tzannatos, Z. (Eds.), Child labor and education in Latin America. Inter- American Development Bank and The World Bank, Washington, DC.10.1057/9780230620100_12Search in Google Scholar

Mayer, S.E. (2002). The influence of parental income on children’s outcomes. Knowledge Management Group, Ministry of Social Development, Wellington, New Zealand.Search in Google Scholar

Mincer, J. (1993). Studies in human capital. Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, Aldershot.10.4337/9781782541554Search in Google Scholar

Mitra, A. (2019). Returns to education in India: capturing the heterogeneity. Asia Pac. Pol. Stud. 6: 151–169, https://doi.org/10.1002/app5.271.Search in Google Scholar

Mollel, N.S. and Chong, R. (2017). Socio-cultural constraints of girls’ access to education in Mtwara district, Tanzania. Khazar J. Humanit. Soc. Sci. 20: 108–125, https://doi.org/10.5782/2223-2621.2017.20.3.108.Search in Google Scholar

Montenegro, C.E. and Patrinos, H.A. (2014). Comparable estimates of returns to schooling around the world, Policy Research Working Paper 7020. Education Global Practice Group. World Bank Group, Washington DC.10.1596/1813-9450-7020Search in Google Scholar

Motkuri, V. and Naik, S.V. (2016). Growth and structure of workforce in India: an analysis of census data. Indian Econ. J. 64: 57–74, https://doi.org/10.1177/0019466216652753.Search in Google Scholar

Mukhopadhyay, U. (2015). Economic liberalisation and gender inequality in labour market: a theoretical approach. Rev. Urban Reg. Dev. Stud. 27: 68–87, https://doi.org/10.1111/rurd.12032.Search in Google Scholar

Mukhopadhyay, U. and Chaudhuri, S. (2013). Economic liberalization, gender wage inequality and welfare. J. Int. Trade Econ. Dev. 22: 1214–1239, https://doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2012.654400.Search in Google Scholar

Nasir, Z.M. (2002). Returns to human capital in Pakistan: a gender disaggregated analysis. Pakistan Dev. Rev. 41: 1–28, doi:https://doi.org/10.30541/v41i1pp.1-28.Search in Google Scholar

Nunnenkamp, P. (2002). Determinants of FDI in developing countries: has globalization changed the rules of the game? Working Paper No. 1122. Kiel Institute for World Economics, Kiel, Germany.Search in Google Scholar

Nunnenkamp, P., Schweickert, R., and Wiebelt, M. (2006). Distributional effects of FDI: How the interaction of FDI and economic policy affects poor households in Bolivia, Kiel Working Papers 1281. Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Kiel, Germany.10.1111/j.1467-7679.2007.00379.xSearch in Google Scholar

Oostendorp, R. (2009). Globalization and the gender wage gap. World Bank Econ. Rev. 23: 141–161, https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhn022.Search in Google Scholar

Patrinos, H.A. (2002). A review of demand-side financing initiatives in education, World Bank Report, No. 26959.Search in Google Scholar

Patrinos, H.A. and Ariasingam, D.L. (1997). Decentralization of education: demand-side financing. World Bank, Washington, DC.10.1596/0-8213-3930-3Search in Google Scholar

Patrinos, H.A. (2007). Demand-side financing in education, UNESCO IIEP; international Academy of education, IAE. UNESCO, IIEP, IAE, Paris, Brussels, p. 21, (Education Policy Series, 007).Search in Google Scholar

Polachek, S.W. (2004). How the human capital model explains why the gender wage gap narrowed, IZA DP No. 1102.10.2139/ssrn.527142Search in Google Scholar

Psacharopoulos, G. and Patrinos, H.A. (2018). Returns to investment in education a decennial review of the global literature, Policy Research Working Paper 8402. World Bank Group, Washington DC.10.1596/30154Search in Google Scholar

Qureshi, M.G. (2012). The gender differences in school enrolment and returns to education in Pakistan. Pakistan Dev. Rev. 51: 219–256, https://doi.org/10.30541/v51i3pp.219-256.Search in Google Scholar

Ravallion, M. and Wodon, Q. (2001). Does child labour displace schooling? Evidence on behavioural responses to an enrollment subsidy. Econ. J. 110: C158–C175, https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0297.00527.Search in Google Scholar

Schultz, T.P. (1993). Returns to women’s education. In: King, E.M. and Hill, M.A. (Eds.), Women’s education in developing countries: barriers, benefits and policies. Johns Hopkins University Press for the World Bank, Baltimore and London, pp. 51–93.Search in Google Scholar

Schultz, T.P. (2004). School subsidies for the poor: evaluating the Mexican Progresa poverty program. J. Dev. Econ. 74: 199–250, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2003.12.009.Search in Google Scholar

Seguino, S. (2002). Promoting gender equality through labor standards and living wages: an exploration of the issues. Paper prepared for presentation at Global Labor Standards and Living Wages Conference. PERI, Amherst.Search in Google Scholar

Sharma, S. (2020). The impact of foreign direct investment on gender inequality in India. Transnatl. Corp. 27: 39–59.10.18356/2076099x-27-3-5Search in Google Scholar

Siegmann, K.A. (2006). Globalisation, gender and equity – effects of foreign direct investment on labour markets in rural Indonesia. J. Econ. 3: 113–130, https://doi.org/10.4337/ejeep.2006.01.09.Search in Google Scholar

Tansel, A. and Güngör, N.D. (2012). Gender effects of education on economic development in Turkey, Discussion Paper No. 6532. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn.10.2139/ssrn.2056722Search in Google Scholar

Urciaga, G.J. and Hernandez, A.M.A. (2008). Wages, education and their private returns in the north-frontier of Mexico: a human capital study. Reg. Soc. XX: 33–56.Search in Google Scholar

Vijaya, R.M. and Kaltani, L. (2007). Foreign direct investment and wages: a bargaining power approach. J. World Syst. Res. 13: 83–95, https://doi.org/10.5195/jwsr.2007.361.Search in Google Scholar

Vijverberg, W.P.M. (1992). Educational investments and returns for women and men in Côte d’Ivoire. J. Hum. Resour. 28: 933–974.10.2307/146298Search in Google Scholar

World Bank. (2002). Bangladesh: female secondary school assistance project II, Project Appraisal Document (Report No. 23594-BD). World Bank, Washington DC.Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2021-10-30
Accepted: 2022-03-01
Published Online: 2022-09-13
Published in Print: 2022-08-26

© 2022 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 2.12.2023 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/roe-2021-0043/pdf
Scroll to top button