Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter May 15, 2013

Off-the-record target zones: theory with an application to Hong Kong’s currency board

  • Yu-Fu Chen EMAIL logo , Michael Funke and Nicole Glanemann

Abstract

This paper provides a modelling framework for evaluating the exchange rate dynamics of a target zone regime with undisclosed bands. We generalize the literature to allow for asymmetric one-sided regimes. Market participants’ beliefs concerning an undisclosed band change as they learn more about central bank intervention policy. We apply the model to Hong Kong’s one-sided currency board mechanism. In autumn 2003, the Hong Kong dollar appreciated from close to 7.80 per US dollar to 7.70, as investors feared that the currency board would be abandoned. In the wake of this appreciation, the monetary authorities finally revamped the regime as a symmetric two-sided system with a narrow exchange rate band.


Corresponding author: Yu-Fu Chen, University of Dundee, Economic Studies, 3 Perth Road, School of Business, Dundee, Scotland DD1 4HN, UK

  1. 1

    An in-depth discussion of Hong Kong’s currency board including technical details is available at http://www.hkma.gov.hk/eng/publications-and-research/reference-materials/monetary/review-of-currency-board-arrangements.shtml. For a perceptive and thorough discussion, see Latter (2007).

  2. 2

    In the empirical exchange rate literature, the performance of currency board systems has been discussed ad nauseam. For example, Ghosh, Gulde and Wolf (2000) have found that currency boards exhibit better inflation performance than soft pegs, mostly due to a credibility effect. Oliva, Rivera-Batiz and Sy (2001) have developed a simple model of a currency board and its credibility allowing a comparison between a currency board and other exchange rate regimes in terms of the inflation – unemployment trade-off and credibility. Regarding growth, currency boards also do better than soft pegs. An explanation for this fact is provided by the growing body of macroeconomic evidence suggesting that volatility is detrimental for economic growth, especially when financial opportunities are limited. See, for example, Aghion et al. (2006) and Aghion and Howitt (2009), pp. 329–339.

  3. 3

    The result of this surprise move was that interbank interest rates jumped and the overnight rate hit 280%. This successfully stemmed the speculative outflow of US dollars. Overnight rates dropped back to about 5% within a few days.

  4. 4

    As a historical note, while no formal strong-side intervention point was introduced, the Subcommittee on Currency Board Operations already considered the options in this area in meetings in October 1999 and July 2000 and “agreed that there would be scope to review the arrangement again, should the need arise” [Hong Kong Monetary Authority, Research Department (2000)].

  5. 5

    For an analysis of the strong-side pressure on the HKD and particularly the HKMA’s response, see IMF (2005). This paper also offers a simple second-generation currency crisis framework for modelling trade-offs faced by the HKMA.

  6. 6

    Rodríuez-Lóez and Mendizabal (2006) have presented a model in which the width of the band, the credibility of the target zone regime, and the volatility of the exchange rate is made explicit. Balancing risks and benefits of fluctuating exchange rates leads to the conclusion that self-declared free-floaters find it optimal to target a narrower implicit (unofficial) band inside an officially announced broad band. This modelling result is consistent with ample indications for the presence of such narrower implicit bands.

  7. 7

    An implicit strong-side band is likely because history has shown that Hong Kong’s policymakers place a heavy emphasis on exchange rate stability (vis-à-vis the USD). The HKMA views the currency board system as an important barometer of Hong Kong’s economic and political conditions. The associated strong external position, characterised by sizable foreign exchange reserves, provides a buffer against short-term external shocks. However, the long-term sustainability of the currency board system will depend crucially on prudent fiscal policies, and high flexibility of goods and factor markets.

  8. 8

    For a thorough review of the theoretical and empirical target zone literature see Duarte, Andrade and Duarte (2013).

  9. 9

    Unfortunately, Klein’s (1992) modelling approach does not lend itself naturally to the asymmetric one-sided band exchange rate regime case. It explains why we depart from Klein’s (1992) approach on technical grounds. Alternative one-sided target zone modelling frameworks without learning from interventions are available in Krugman and Rotemberg (1990) and Veestraeten (2001). With different methodology, Klein and Lewis (1993) have presented a symmetric target zone model with probability-of-intervention learning and applied the framework to the European Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM).

  10. 10

    A thorough description of the approach is provided by Sarno and Taylor (2003), pp. 177–184.

  11. 11

    The interested reader is referred to Appendix A.1 for the derivation. Note that the closed-form solution in Klein (1992) is more appealing because it is derived for the symmetric case where the integrals are characteristic.

  12. 12

    In dynamic economic models backward-looking expectations with systematic forecasting errors are inconsistent with rational behaviour. In nonlinear dynamic models, exhibiting seemingly unpredictable breaks due to the sporadic nature of the interventions, however, simple “rule of thumb” backward-looking expectation rules may yield non-systematic forecasting errors. Furthermore, numerous survey studies, such as Cheung and Chinn (2001) and Menkhoff (1998), uniformly confirm that speculators in foreign exchange markets generally do not rely on mathematically well-defined econometric or economic models, but instead follow simple backward-looking trading rules.

  13. 13

    In Klein’s (1992) model, the first intervention is such a landmark decision for the future. This implies that after the first intervention the model with undisclosed band width collapses to the standard Krugman (1991) model with full faith in the target zone.

  14. 14

    Whether

    is determined to belong to the upper or lower interval, which influences the conditions in the conditional probability functions, is negligible for the exchange rate movements, as only a null set is integrated.

  15. 15

    Convex functions are typically used in macroeconomic models with adjustment costs to penalise swift changes in variables and thereby to induce gradual movements over time. Among the many models with convex adjustment costs, quadratic functions have been by far the most common specification, essentially for tractability reasons. Without loss of generality and for mathematical convenience, we also assume a quadratic specification.

  16. 16

    In our framework, we approximate the relevant considerations with the simplest functional forms to keep the model tractable and the conclusions less susceptible to certain twists in the functions. The derivation of λ is shown in Appendix A.2.

  17. 17

    The interested reader might look at the derivation in Appendix A.3. A hypergeometric function can be defined in the form of a convergent hypergeometric series. Many functions can be expressed as special cases of a hypergeometric function (eg exponential, gamma, trigometrical and the Bessel functions).

  18. 18

    The HKMA’s foreign currency market interventions are carried out in an open and transparent manner and so are public knowledge. In all cases, the interventions are announced on the day they occur. Agents can therefore distinguish between movements in f due to interventions and fluctuations due to equation (3).

  19. 19

    Technically expressed, the coefficients ai in equation (32) show the importance of the last interventions. However, expectations are also influenced by V1 (compare the effects of different V1 by means of Figure 3). Therefore, there is also room for expectations, which are not primarily anchored by past interventions.

  20. 20

    The 1-year forward rate of the HKD was consistently outside the convertibility zone between October 2005 and the start of 2007. This is known as the 100% credibility test developed by Svensson (1992, 1994) and indicates that financial market participants have initially revealed skepticism about the ability of the new strong side CU to limit exchange rate fluctuations. Intermittent upward pressure on the HKD occurred again in autumn 2007 when HKMA interventions again were aimed at anchoring market expectations.

  21. 21

    The HKMA would not be the first central bank to do this. For example, the ERM currencies were normally allowed to fluctuate no more than 2.25% above or below their fixed bilateral rates. The Netherlands and Austria had narrow bands of ±0.6%, while Portugal and Spain had wider bands of ±6%. Italy and the UK were forced to leave the ERM on 17 September 1992 when both currencies came under speculative pressure. Fluctuation bands were then widened to ±15% in 1993 to avoid defending the indefensible.

  22. 22

    Interventions refer to net injections or withdrawals of funds by the HKMA in the interbank money market. For the daily market operations data, see http://www.info.gov.hk/hkma/eng/statistics/msb/index.htm.

  23. 23

    Interventions were necessary because markets believed that the HKD would appreciate alongside the RMB made the automatic adjustment mechanisms of the currency board system ineffective. For an econometric logit analysis of monetary operations conducted by the HKMA, using daily data for the one-sided regime between September 1998 and December 2001, see Gerlach (2005). For an analysis of intra-marginal interventions, also see Svensson (1992).

  24. 24

    In the theoretical modelling framework, V1 is assumed to be exogenous, neglecting central bank incentives to influence expectations with announcements. Rational central banks choose “verbal intervention” as a toolkit since it has the ability to enhance the predictability of monetary policy decisions and potentially to help achieve central banks’ macroeconomic objectives. On the other hand, when optimal policies are dynamically inconsistent, announcements will only be considered cheap talk. For a survey of this partially credible commitment device, see Blinder et al. (2008).

  25. 25

    Further points after the next interventions yielded qualitatively similar, although quantitatively different, results. For brevity of exposition, only the exchange rate dynamics for SII and SIII is presented here. Interested readers may obtain further calibrations of the model dynamics from the authors upon request.

  26. 26

    Please note that the upper band of the target zone has not been tested to the limit during the sample period.

  27. 27

    See, for example, Chen, Funke, and Glanemann (2011).

Appendix

A.1 Derivation of equation (19)

At first we solve the expectation values E(A1(Vl)) and E(A2(Vl)). Manipulations of the integrand provide the primitive

of
Therefore, we obtain

and

Now we derive the closed form expression (19) using both expectation values

A.2 Derivation of λ

An easy way to choose λ properly is to derive it from condition (25), which claims that

A.3 Derivation of equation (29)

Before we prove equation (29), we provide a short introduction to the hypergeometric function. The hypergeometric function 2F1 is the convergent Gauss hypergeometric series

where the circle of convergence is the unit circle |z|=1 and Γ(‧) denotes the gamma function.

The relationship between the factorial and the gamma function is defined as Γ(n+1)=n! for all n∈ℕ. The functional equation of the gamma function is xΓ(x)=Γ(x+1) for all x∈ℝ+.

An important property of hypergeometric functions is that the six functions 2F1[a±1, b; c; z], 2F1[a, b±1; c; z] and 2F1[a, b; c±1; z] are contiguous to 2F1[a, b;c;z]. They are used to express one of them as a linear combination of any two of the other contiguous functions and are derived by Gauss. The two relations that are applied in the following are

Another important property is

Property 3:2F1[a, b; b; z]=(1−z)a

A useful overview of the linear combinations and other interesting relations is given in Abramowitz and Stegun (1972).

Being equipped with this short introduction to hypergeometric functions 2F1, we turn to the calculation of the expectation E(A1(Vl)).

In order to prove the third equality, we show that the derivative of

equals the integrand in the second equation. As a preliminary, we consider the derivative of the hypergeometric function. The derivation of the hypergeometric function is

The third equality holds because the first summand in the line above is zero. For the fourth equality we use the functional equation of the gamma function, which results in a hypergeometric function with new parameters.

According to the order of the equal signs the properties 1–3 are applied:

Now, we have obtained all the ingredients for differentiating the above mentioned primitive.

The other expectation is given without proof of the primitive, as it is derived in a like manner.

Hence the closed form solution results in

A.4 Calculation of the coefficient aA

Suppose that market participants assign the same weight to the last N=8 interventions in their expectations formation process. In the case where SIV=ln(7.77) and SV=ln(7.754), these market operation dates and the corresponding HKD spot exchange rates are:

12.10.047.792510.11.047.7812
25.10.047.777108.12.047.7705
27.10.047.777710.12.047.7753
01.11.047.779927.05.057.7775

As a start, this enables us to calculate the logarithmised exchange rates

The value of aA for SIV= ln (7.77) can then be solved from

This equation is derived from equation (33). However, the question arises as to why the left hand side is equal to SIV. One has to take into consideration that whenever a smaller fundamental f is observed, the interval of possible intervention triggering exchange rates is truncated. Where does that leave us? In case of SIV, the original interval

is reduced to [S1, SIV] and so we can use SIV to calculate the unknown coefficient aA. The resulting parameter is aA≈0.309. In an analogous manner, aA≈0.827 is obtained for SV.

For the simulation of the exchange rate dynamics in SVI=ln(7.76) three further interventions are to be included in the computation:

25.10.077.750502.11.077.7597
30.10.077.7504

The corresponding value of aA thus evolves as aA≈0.546.

References

Abramowitz, M., and I. Stegun. 1972. Handbook of Mathematical Functions with Formulas, Graphs, and Mathematical Tables. New York: Dover Pubn Inc.Search in Google Scholar

Aghion, P., and P. Howitt. 2009. The Economics of Growth. Cambridge: The MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar

Aghion, P., P. Bacchetta, R. Ranciere, and K. Rogoff. 2006. “Exchange Rate Volatility and Productivity Growth: The Role of Financial Development.” NBER Working Paper 12117, National Bureau of Economic Research.10.3386/w12117Search in Google Scholar

Blinder, A., M. Ehrmann, M. Fratzscher, J. De Haan, and D.-J. Jansen. 2008. “Central Bank Communication and Monetary Policy: A Survey of Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Economic Literature 46: 910–945.10.1257/jel.46.4.910Search in Google Scholar

Calvo, G. A., and C. M. Reinhart. 2002. “Fear of Floating.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 379–408.10.1162/003355302753650274Search in Google Scholar

Chen, Y.-F., M. Funke, and N. Glanemann. 2011. “The Signalling Channel of Central Bank Interventions: Modelling the Yen / US Dollar Exchange Rate.” CESifo Working Paper Series 3610, CESifo Group Munich.10.2139/ssrn.1945093Search in Google Scholar

Cheung, Y.-W., and M. D. Chinn. 2001. “Currency Traders and Exchange Rate Dynamics: A Survey of the US Market.” Journal of International Money and Finance 20: 439–471.10.1016/S0261-5606(01)00002-XSearch in Google Scholar

Duarte, A. P., J. S., Andrade, and A. Duarte. 2013. “Exchange Rate Target Zones: A Survey of the Literature.” Journal of Economic Surveys 27: 247–268.10.1111/j.1467-6419.2011.00703.xSearch in Google Scholar

Fischer, S. 2001. “Distinguished Lecture on Economics in Government: Exchange Rate Regimes: Is the Bipolar View Correct?” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 15: 3–24.10.1257/jep.15.2.3Search in Google Scholar

Genberg, H., and C.-H. Hui. 2011. “The Credibility of Hong Kong’s Link from the Perspective of Modern Financial Theory.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 43: 185–206.10.1111/j.1538-4616.2010.00370.xSearch in Google Scholar

Gerlach, S. 2005. “Monetary Operations by Hong Kong’s Currency Board.” Journal of Asian Economics 15: 1119–1135.10.1016/j.asieco.2004.11.005Search in Google Scholar

Ghosh, A. R., A.-M. Gulde, and H. C. Wolf. 2000. “Currency Boards: More than a Quick Fix?” Economic Policy 15: 269–335.10.1111/1468-0327.00063Search in Google Scholar

Haas, M., S. Mittnik, and B. Mizrach. 2006. “Assessing Central Bank Credibility during the ERM Crises: Comparing Option and Spot Market-Based Forecasts.” Journal of Financial Stability 2: 28–54.10.1016/j.jfs.2005.02.012Search in Google Scholar

Hong Kong Monetary Authority, Research Department. 2000. “Record of discussion of the meeting of the exchange fund advisory committee sub- committee on currency board operations held on 5 July 2000.” URL http://www.info.gov.hk/hkma/eng/press/2000/20000802e3.htm.Search in Google Scholar

IMF. 2005. “People’s Republic of China – Hong Kong Special Administrative Region: Selected Issues.” IMF Country Report, No. 05/62: 16–31.Search in Google Scholar

Klein, M. W. 1992. “Big Effects of Small Interventions: The Informational Role of Intervention in Exchange Rate Policy.” European Economic Review 36: 915–924.10.1016/0014-2921(92)90065-5Search in Google Scholar

Klein, M. W., and K. K. Lewis. 1993. “Learning About Intervention Target Zones.” Journal of International Economics 35: 275–295.10.1016/0022-1996(93)90020-XSearch in Google Scholar

Krugman, P. 1991. “Target Zones and Exchange Rate Dynamics.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106: 669–682.10.2307/2937922Search in Google Scholar

Krugman, P., and J. Rotemberg. 1990. “Target Zones and Limited Reserves.” NBER Working Paper 3418, National Bureau of Economic Research.10.3386/w3418Search in Google Scholar

Latter, T. 2007. Hong Kong’s Money: The History, Logic and Operation of the Currency Peg. Hong Kong: Hong Kong University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Malz, A. 1997. “Estimating the Probability Distribution of the Future Exchange rate from Option Prices.” Journal of Derivatives 5: 18–36.10.3905/jod.1997.407988Search in Google Scholar

Menkhoff, L. 1998. “The Noise Trading Approach – Questionnaire Evidence from Foreign Exchange.” Journal of International Money and Finance 17: 547–564.10.1016/S0261-5606(98)00016-3Search in Google Scholar

Oliva, M.-A., L. A. Rivera-Batiz, and A. N. R. Sy. 2001. “Discipline, Signaling, and Currency Boards.” Review of International Economics 9: 608–625.10.1111/1467-9396.00303Search in Google Scholar

Rodríguez-López, J., and H. R. Mendizabal. 2006. “How Tight should One’s Hands be Tied? Fear of Floating and the Credibility of Exchange Rate Regimes.” Topics in Macroeconomics 6: Article 4.10.2202/1534-5998.1401Search in Google Scholar

Sarno, L., and M. Taylor. 2003. The Economics of Exchange Rates. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511754159Search in Google Scholar

Svensson, L. E. O. 1992. “An Interpretation of Recent Research on Exchange Rate Target Zones.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 6: 119–144.10.1257/jep.6.4.119Search in Google Scholar

Svensson, L. E. O. 1994. “Why Exchange Rate Bands?: Monetary Independence in Spite of Fixed Exchange Rates.” Journal of Monetary Economics 33: 157–199.10.1016/0304-3932(94)90018-3Search in Google Scholar

Veestraeten, D. 2001. “Conditional Distributions in the Krugman Target Zone Model and Undeclared Narrower Bands.” Center for Economic Studies - Discussion Paper 0102, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Centrum voor Economische Studiën.Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2013-05-15
Published in Print: 2013-09-01

©2013 by Walter de Gruyter Berlin Boston

Downloaded on 8.6.2023 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/snde-2012-0034/html
Scroll to top button