Abstract
Plain vanilla options have a single underlying asset and a single condition on the payoff at the expiration date. For this class of options, a well known result of Duffie, Pan, and Singleton (Duffie, D., J. Pan, and K. Singleton. 2000. “Transform Analysis and Asset Pricing for Affine Jump-Diffusions.” Econometrica 68: 1343–1376. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00164.) shows how to invert the characteristic function to obtain a closed-form formula for their prices. However, multiple-asset and multiple-condition derivatives such as rainbow options cannot be priced within this framework. This paper provides an analytical solution for options whose payoffs depends on two or more conditions. We take the advantage of the inversion of the Fourier transform, resorting to neither Black and Scholes’s framework, nor the affine models’s settings. Numerical experiments based on the aforementioned class of derivatives are provided to illustrate the usefulness of the proposed approach.
Acknowledgments
We thank an anonymous referee and Bruce Mizrach (the editor) for comments and suggestions that improved the article substantially. We also thank Guillaume Nolin and Maren Hansen, Glen Keenleyside and Foutse Khomh for comments and suggestions. This research was initiated while Tafolong was working at Desjardins Group. A previous version circulated under the title: “Pricing Multiple Triggers Contingent Claims.” The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors. No responsibility for them should be attributed to the Bank of Canada or the National Bank of Canada. Remaining errors are ours.
Appendix
A Proof of Proposition 2
For 0<τ1, τ2<+∞ and y1, y2∈ℝ, let us define the expression 𝕀 by the following relation:
Because
Since we disregard the exact order in which the integral has been composed, integrand permutations conserve the value of the integral, and 𝕀 can be expressed as follows:
To proceed with the determination of 𝕀, we make use of the following relation. For τ1>0, τ2>0,
Using the usual trigonometric identity, (21) becomes (22) as follows
Furthermore, the following result holds for every τ>0:
Pooling together the relation (23) with the bounded convergence theorem and using the fact that
We determine each of the expressions above in order to compute 𝕀. Firstly, we proceed by computing the expression I
We know that, whenever one of y1 or y2 is +∞, we recover Duffie, Pan, and Singleton (2000) one-condition framework; then, from their Proposition 2, we have
Plugging these relations into I yields
The second expression, II, is derived as follows
where
From Proposition 2 of Duffie, Pan, and Singleton (2000) we also have
Likewise, III is computed as
Finally, the last term, IV, is expressed as
In conclusion, we can express the following limit:
B Proof of Lemma 1
The proof of Lemma 1 relies on the following combinatory identity:
Substituting
We therefore show equation (11) of Lemma 1 by combinatory identity.
Substituting QA by its expression (11) in 𝕀A leads to
C Proof of Lemma 2
Henceforth, to simplify our notations, we drop the multiple occurrences of Xt, T, χ from the expression of Ga,b(z, Xt, T). By definition, we have
Using the fact that
we have
where
Replacing QA by its expression in 𝕀A leads to
We are now ready to demonstrate the lemma. The goal is to show that
In other words, we endeavor to prove that
To do so, we proceed by induction. Suppose that the relation holds for each subset of E whose member’s cardinality is less than or equal to |A|. Let us show that the relation is also fulfilled for the subset with |A|+1 elements. Denoting A+1≡A∪{y∣A∣+1}, we have
By induction, we can apply (32) to
thus
hence
By the definition of Ga,b(·), we have
and therefore
Replacing
implies that
Hence
By noting that
we can rewrite 𝕁A+1 as the following
Rearranging the summation leads to
which implies
Using the induction assumption up to 𝕁A, we have
Thus
In other words
This ends the proof of Lemma 2.
D Proof of Proposition 3
The proof of Proposition 3 relies on Lemma 2 and an application of the Möbius inversion for the Boolean algebra of subsets of a finite set [see Hazewinkel (2002) and Rota (1964)].
Define A⊆E,
where 𝕀A, A⊆E is given by (10).
Lemma 2 implies that
The Möbius inversion says that (35) is equivalent to
and the proof of Proposition 3 is completed with A=E in (36).
E Some ARV model features
Below we provide some ARV model properties.
E.1 The density
The joint conditional density of returns (Rt) and realized variance-covariance matrix (RVt) is
where
and
where
E.2 Model characteristics
It follows from (14) that the conditional variance can be expressed as
Given that
the model is well defined (in the sense that the support of distribution of Σt is the symmetric positive definite real matrix) whenever the following condition is fulfilled:
and we can express ω as
Further, given that
the variance matrix is covariance-stationary if all the eigenvalues of ββ′+αα′ are <1.
E.3 Proof of Proposition 4, the conditional expectation of log returns
Hence
E.4 Proof of the moment-generating functions
E.4.1 Proof of Proposition 5
with
In the following, we provide more details on the proof of that result:
E.4.2 Proof of Proposition 6
References
Ahn, D., and B. Gao. 1999. “A Parametric Nonlinear Model of Term Structure Dynamics.” Review of Financial Studies 12: 721–762. http://rfs.oxfordjournals.org/content/12/4/721.abstract.10.1093/rfs/12.4.721Search in Google Scholar
Andersen, L., and J. Andreasen. 2000. “Jump-Diffusion Processes: Volatility Smile Fitting and Numerical Methods for Option Pricing.” Review of Derivatives Research 4: 231–262. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A%3A1011354913068.Search in Google Scholar
Andersen, T. G., T. Bollerslev, F. X. Diebold, and H. Ebens. 2001. “The Distribution of Realized Stock Return Volatility.” Journal of Financial Economics 61: 43–76. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304405X01000551.Search in Google Scholar
Bakshi, G., C. Cao, and Z. Chen. 1997. “Empirical Performance of Alternative Option Pricing Models.” The Journal of Finance 52: 2003–2049. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1997.tb02749.x.10.1111/j.1540-6261.1997.tb02749.xSearch in Google Scholar
Bates, D. 1996. “Jumps and Stochastic Volatility: Exchange Rate Processes Implicit in Deutsche Mark Options.” Review of Financial Studies 9: 69–107. http://rfs.oxfordjournals.org/content/9/1/69.abstract.10.1093/rfs/9.1.69Search in Google Scholar
Buraschi, A., P. Porchia, and T. Fabio. 2010. “Correlation Risk and Optimal Portfolio Choice.” The Journal of Finance 65: 393–420. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01533.x.10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01533.xSearch in Google Scholar
Buraschi, A., P. Porchia, and T. Fabio. 2014. “When Uncertainty Blows in the Orchard: Comovement and Equilibrium Volatility Risk Premia.” The Journal of Finance 69: 101–137. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12095.10.1111/jofi.12095Search in Google Scholar
Buss, A., and G. Vilkov. 2012. “Measuring Equity Risk with Option-Implied Correlations.” Review of Financial Studies 25: 3113–3140. http://rfs.oxfordjournals.org/content/25/10/3113.abstract.10.1093/rfs/hhs087Search in Google Scholar
Chang, C.-C., S.-L. Chung, and M.-T. Yu. 2006. “Loan Guarantee Portfolios and Joint Loan Guarantees with Stochastic Interest Rates.” The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 46: 16–35. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1062976903000917.10.1016/j.qref.2003.07.004Search in Google Scholar
Christoffersen, P., S. Heston, and K. Jacobs. 2006. “Option Valuation with Conditional Skewness.” Journal of Econometrics 131: 253–284. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304407605000126.10.1016/j.jeconom.2005.01.010Search in Google Scholar
Christoffersen, P., B. Feunou, K. Jacobs, and N. Meddahi. 2014. “The Economic Value of Realized Volatility: Using High-Frequency Returns for Option Valuation.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 49: 663–697. http://journals.cambridge.org/article_S0022109014000428.10.1017/S0022109014000428Search in Google Scholar
Davies, R. B. 1973. “Numerical Inversion of a Characteristic Function.” Biometrika 60: 231–262.10.1093/biomet/60.2.415Search in Google Scholar
Duffie, D., J. Pan, and K. Singleton. 2000. “Transform Analysis and Asset Pricing for Affine Jump-Diffusions.” Econometrica 68: 1343–1376. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00164.10.1111/1468-0262.00164Search in Google Scholar
Duffie, D., D. Filipović, and W. Schachermayer. 2003. “Affine Processes and Applications in Finance.” Annals of Applied Probability 13: 984–1053.10.1214/aoap/1060202833Search in Google Scholar
Duffy, D. J. 2009. “Numerical Analysis of Jump Diffusion Models: A Partial Differential Equation Approach.” Wilmott Magazine.Search in Google Scholar
Dufresne, D., J. Garrido, and M. Morales. 2009. “Fourier Inversion Formulas in Option Pricing and Insurance.” Methodology and Computing in Applied Probability 11: 359–383. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11009-007-9049-z.10.1007/s11009-007-9049-zSearch in Google Scholar
Engle, R. 2000. “Dynamic Conditional Correlation – A Simple Class of Multivariate Garch Models.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 20: 339–350.10.1198/073500102288618487Search in Google Scholar
Feunou, B., and J.-S. Fontaine. 2010. “Discrete Choice Term Structure Models: Theory and Applications.” Working Paper, Duke University and Bank of Canada.10.2139/ssrn.1772971Search in Google Scholar
Feunou, B., and N. Meddahi. 2009. “Generalized Affine Model, Provides a General Framework that Characterizes Infinite Order Affine Model.” Working Paper, Duke University.10.2139/ssrn.1367033Search in Google Scholar
Forsberg, L., and T. Bollerslev. 2002. “Bridging the Gap Between the Distribution of Realized (ecu) Volatility and Arch Modelling (of the euro): The Garch-nig Model.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 17: 535–548. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/jae.685.10.1002/jae.685Search in Google Scholar
Gay, G. D., and S. Manaster. 1984. “The Quality Option Implicit in Futures Contracts.” Journal of Financial Economics 13: 353–370. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/0304405X84900047.10.1016/0304-405X(84)90004-7Search in Google Scholar
Gerber, H. U., and E. S. W. Shiu. 1994. “Option Pricing by Esscher Transforms.” Transactions of the Society of Actuaries 46: 99–191.Search in Google Scholar
Glasserman, P. 2003. Monte Carlo Methods in Financial Engineering. 1st ed. New York, NY, USA: Springer.10.1007/978-0-387-21617-1Search in Google Scholar
Gourieroux, C. 2006. “Continuous Time Wishart Process for Stochastic Risk.” Econometric Reviews 25: 177–217. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/07474930600713234.10.1080/07474930600713234Search in Google Scholar
Gourieroux, C. and R. Sufana. 2010. “Derivative Pricing with Wishart Multivariate Stochastic Volatility.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 28: 438–451. http://dx.doi.org/10.1198/jbes.2009.08105.10.1198/jbes.2009.08105Search in Google Scholar
Hazewinkel, M. 2002. Encyclopaedia of Mathematics. 1st ed. Berlin Heidelberg New York, NY, USA: Springer-Verlag.Search in Google Scholar
Heston, S. 1993. “A closed-Form Solution for Options with Stochastic Volatility with Applications To Bond and Currency Options.” Review of Financial Studies, 6: 327–343. http://rfs.oxfordjournals.org/content/6/2/327.abstract.10.1093/rfs/6.2.327Search in Google Scholar
Johnson, H. 1987. “Options on The Maximum or The Minimum of Several Assets.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 22: 277–283. http://journals.cambridge.org/article_S002210900001262X.10.2307/2330963Search in Google Scholar
Kempf, A., O. Korn, and S. Saßning. 2014. “Portfolio Optimization Using Forward-Looking Information.” Review of Finance. DOI: 10.1093/rof/rfu006. http://rof.oxfordjournals.org/content/early/2014/03/07/rof.rfu006.abstract.Search in Google Scholar
Margrabe, W. 1978. “The Value of An Option to Exchange One Asset for Another.” The Journal of Finance 33: 177–186. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1978.tb03397.x.10.1111/j.1540-6261.1978.tb03397.xSearch in Google Scholar
Martzoukous, S. H. 2001. “The Option on n Assets with Exchange Rate and Exercise Price Risk.” Journal of Multinational Financial Management 11: 1–15.10.1016/S1042-444X(00)00039-6Search in Google Scholar
Navatte, P., and C. Villa. 2000. “The Information Content of Implied Volatility, Skewness and Kurtosis: Empirical Evidence From Long-term cac 40 Options.” European Financial Management, 6: 41–56. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-036X.00110.10.1111/1468-036X.00110Search in Google Scholar
Qu, D. 2010. “Pricing Basket Options with Skew.” Wilmott Magazine.Search in Google Scholar
Rota, G.-C. 1964. “On the Foundations of Combinatory Theory of Mö,bius Functions.” Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie und Verw 2: 340–368.10.1007/BF00531932Search in Google Scholar
Shephard, N., and K. Sheppard. 2010. “Realising the Future: Forecasting with High frequency-Based Volatility (heavy) Models.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 25: 197–231. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/jae.1158.10.1002/jae.1158Search in Google Scholar
Stoll, R. M. 1969. “The Relationship Between Put and Call Option Prices.” Journal of Finance 24: 801–824.10.1111/j.1540-6261.1969.tb01694.xSearch in Google Scholar
Stulz, R. M. 1982. “Options on The Minimum or The Maximum of Two Risky Assets: Analysis and Applications.” Journal of Financial Economics 10: 161–185. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/0304405X82900113.10.1016/0304-405X(82)90011-3Search in Google Scholar
van Binsbergen, J., M. Brandt, and R. Koijen. 2012. “On the Timing and Pricing of Dividends.” American Economic Review 102: 1596–1618. http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer.102.4.1596.10.1257/aer.102.4.1596Search in Google Scholar
Supplemental Material
The online version of this article (DOI: 10.1515/snde-2014-0034) offers supplementary material, available to authorized users.
©2015 by De Gruyter