Skip to content
BY 4.0 license Open Access Published by De Gruyter Open Access June 9, 2009

Discounting for Climate Change

David Anthoff , Richard S.J. Tol EMAIL logo and Gary W. Yohe
From the journal Economics

Abstract

It is well-known that the discount rate is crucially important for estimating the social cost of carbon, a standard indicator for the seriousness of climate change and desirable level of climate policy. The Ramsey equation for the discount rate has three components: the pure rate of time preference, a measure of relative risk aversion, and the rate of growth of per capita consumption. Much of the attention on the appropriate discount rate for long-term environmental problems has focussed on the role played by the pure rate of time preference in this formulation. We show that the other two elements are numerically just as important in considerations of anthropogenic climate change. The elasticity of the marginal utility with respect to consumption is particularly important because it assumes three roles: consumption smoothing over time, risk aversion, and inequity aversion. Given the large uncertainties about climate change and widely asymmetric impacts, the assumed rates of risk and inequity aversion can be expected to play significant roles. The consumption growth rate plays multiple roles, as well. It is one of the determinants of the discount rate, and one of the drivers of emissions and hence climate change. We also find that the impacts of climate change grow slower than income, so the effective discount rate is higher than the real discount rate. Moreover, the differential growth rate between rich and poor countries determines the time evolution of the size of the equity weights. As there are a number of crucial but uncertain parameters, it is no surprise that one can obtain almost any estimate of the social cost of carbon. We even show that, for a low pure rate of time preference, the estimate of the social cost of carbon is indeed arbitrary—as one can exclude neither large positive nor large negative impacts in the very long run. However, if we probabilistically constrain the parameters to values that are implied by observed behaviour, we find that the expected social cost of carbon, corrected for uncertainty and inequity, is approximate 60 US dollar per metric tonne of carbon (or roughly $17 per tonne of CO2) under the assumption that catastrophic risk is zero.

Data material available at http://www.fnu.zmaw.de/FUND.5679.0.html

JEL Classification: Q54

References

Anthoff, D., C.J. Hepburn, and R.S.J. Tol (2009a). Equity Weighting and the Marginal Damage Costs of Climate Change. Ecological Economics, 68(3): 836–849.10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.06.017Search in Google Scholar

Anthoff, D., R.S.J. Tol, and G.W. Yohe (2009b). Risk Aversion, Time Preference, and the Social Cost of Carbon. Environmental Research Letters, 4(2–2): 1–7.10.1088/1748-9326/4/2/024002Search in Google Scholar

Arrow, K.J. (2007). Global Climate Change: A Challenge to Policy. Economists’ Voice, 1–5.10.2202/1553-3832.1270Search in Google Scholar

Atkinson, G.D., S. Dietz, J. Helgeson, C.J. Hepburn, and H. Saelen (2009). Siblings, not Triplets: Social Preferences for Risk, Inequality and Time in Discounting Climate Change. http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2009–14.Search in Google Scholar

Azar, C., and T. Sterner (1996). Discounting and Distributional Considerations in the Context of Global Warming. Ecological Economics, 19: 169–184.Search in Google Scholar

Batjes, J.J., and C.G.M. Goldewijk (1994). The IMAGE 2 Hundred Year (1890-1990) Database of the Global Environment (HYDE). Rijksinstituut voor Volksgezondheid en Milieu RIVM, Bilthoven.Search in Google Scholar

Bergson, A. (1938). A Reformulation of Certain Aspects of Welfare Economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 52(2): 310–334.Search in Google Scholar

Cline, W.R. (1992). Global Warming—The Benefits of Emission Abatement. Washington, DC: OECD Publications and Information Center.Search in Google Scholar

Creedy, J., and R. Guest, (2008). Discounting and the Time Preference Rate. Economic Record, 84(264): 109–127.Search in Google Scholar

Dasgupta, P. (2007). Commentary: The Stern Review’s Economics of Climate Change. National Institute Economic Review, 199: 4–7.Search in Google Scholar

Epstein, L.G., and S.E. Zin (1989). Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Consumption and Asset Returns: A Theoretical Framework. Econometrica, 57(4): 937–969.Search in Google Scholar

Evans, D.J. (2005). The Elasticity of Marginal Utility of Consumption: Estimates for 20 OECD Countries. Fiscal Studies, 26(2): 197–224.Search in Google Scholar

Evans, D.J., and H. Sezer (2004). Social Discount Rates for Six Major Countries. Applied Economics Letters 11: 557–560.Search in Google Scholar

Evans, D.J., and H. Sezer (2005). Social Discount Rates for Member Countries of the European Union. Journal of Economic Studies, 32(1): 47–59.Search in Google Scholar

Fankhauser, S. (1994). Protection vs. Retreat—The Economic Costs of Sea Level Rise. Environment and Planning A, 27: 299–319.Search in Google Scholar

Fankhauser, S., R.S.J. Tol, and D.W. Pearce (1997). The Aggregation of Climate Change Damages: A Welfare Theoretic Approach. Environmental and Resource Economics, 10(3): 249–266.Search in Google Scholar

Guo, J., C.J. Hepburn, R.S.J. Tol, and D. Anthoff (2006). Discounting and the Social Cost of Climate Change: A Closer Look at Uncertainty. Environmental Science & Policy, 9: 205–216.Search in Google Scholar

Hammitt, J.K., R.J. Lempert, and M.E. Schlesinger (1992). A Sequential-Decision Strategy for Abating Climate Change. Nature, 357: 315–318.Search in Google Scholar

Hasselmann, K., S. Hasselmann, R. Giering, V. Ocana, and H. von Storch (1997). Sensitivity Study of Optimal CO2 Emission Paths Using a Simplified Structural Integrated Assessment Model (SIAM). Climatic Change, 37: 345–386.Search in Google Scholar

Hoel, M., and T. Sterner (2007). Discounting and Relative Prices in Assessing Future Environmental Damages. Climatic Change, 84: 265–280.Search in Google Scholar

Hope, C.W. (2008). Discount Rates, Equity Weights and the Social Cost of Carbon. Energy Economics, 30(3): 1011–1019.Search in Google Scholar

Horowitz, J.K. (2002). Preferences in the Future. Environmental and Resource Economics, 21: 241–259.Search in Google Scholar

Jensen, P.H., and E. Webster (2007). Is Stern Correct? Does Climate Change Require Policy Intervention? Australian Economic Review, 40(4): 421–431.10.1111/j.1467-8462.2007.00481.xSearch in Google Scholar

Kattenberg, A., F. Giorgi, H. Grassl, G.A. Meehl, J.F.B. Mitchell, R.J. Stouffer, T. Tokioka, A.J. Weaver, and T.M.L. Wigley (1996). Climate Models—Projections of Future Climate. Climate Change 1995: The Science of Climate Change—Contribution of Working Group I to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, first edition, J.T. Houghton et al. (eds.), Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 285–357.Search in Google Scholar

Koegel, T. (2009). On the Relation with Dual-Rate Discounting and Substitutability. http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2009-10.Search in Google Scholar

Leggett, J., W.J. Pepper, and R.J. Swart (1992). Emissions Scenarios for the IPCC: An Update. Climate Change 1992—The Supplementary Report to the IPCC Scientific Assessment, First Edition, J.T. Houghton, B.A. Callander, and S.K. Varney (eds.), Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 71–95.Search in Google Scholar

Link, P.M., and R.S.J. Tol (2004). Possible Economic Impacts of a Shutdown of the Thermohaline Circulation: An Application of FUND. Portuguese Economic Journal, 3(2): 99–114.Search in Google Scholar

Maier-Reimer, E., and K. Hasselmann (1987). Transport and Storage of Carbon Dioxide in the Ocean: An Inorganic Ocean Circulation Carbon Cycle Model. Climate Dynamics, 2: 63–90.Search in Google Scholar

Mendelsohn, R.O. (2008). Is the Stern Review an Economic Analysis?. Rev Environ Econ Policy, 2(1): 45–60.Search in Google Scholar

Mendelsohn, R.O., W.N. Morrison, M.E. Schlesinger, and N.G. Andronova (2000). Country-Specific Market Impacts of Climate Change. Climatic Change, 45(3–4): 553–569.Search in Google Scholar

Narita, D., D. Anthoff, and R.S.J. Tol (2008). Damage Costs of Climate Change through Intensification of Tropical Cyclone Activities: An Application of FUND, Working Paper 259, Economic and Social Research Institute, Dublin.10.3354/cr00799Search in Google Scholar

Narita, D., D. Anthoff, and R.S.J. Tol (2009). Economic Costs of Extratropical Storms under Climate Change: An Application of FUND. Working Paper 274, Economic and Social Research Institute, Dublin.Search in Google Scholar

Nordhaus, W.D. (2007). Critical Assumptions in the Stern Review on Climate Change. Science, 317: 201–202.Search in Google Scholar

Ramaswamy, V., O. Boucher, J. Haigh, D. Hauglustaine, J. Haywood, G. Myhre, T. Nakajima, G.Y. Shi, and S. Solomon (2001). Radiative Forcing of Climate Change. Climate Change 2001: The Scientific Basis—Contribution of Working Group I to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, J.T. Houghton and Y. Ding (eds.), Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 349–416.Search in Google Scholar

Ramsey, F. (1928). A Mathematical Theory of Saving. Economic Journal, 38: 543–549.Search in Google Scholar

Reed, W.J. (1984). The Effects of the Risk of Fire on the Optimal Rotation of a Forest. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 11(2): 180–190.Search in Google Scholar

Saelen, H., G.D. Atkinson, S. Dietz, J. Helgeson, and C.J. Hepburn (2008). Risk, Inequality and Time in the Welfare Economics of Climate Change: Is the Workhorse Model Underspecified?. Discussion Paper 400, Department of Economics, Oxford University, Oxford.Search in Google Scholar

Samuelson, P.A. (1975). Foundations of Economic Analysis. (Enlarged edition) Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Spackman, M. (2004). Time Discounting and of the Cost of Capital in Government. Fiscal Studies, 25(4): 467–518.Search in Google Scholar

Stern, N.H. (1977). Welfare Weights and the Elasticity of the Marginal Valuation of Income. Studies in Modern Economic Analysis: Proceedings of the Annual Conference of the Association of University Teachers of Economics, M.J. Artis and A.R. Norbay (eds.), Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 209–257.Search in Google Scholar

Stern, N.H. (2008). The Economics of Climate Change. American Economic Review, 98(2): 1–37.Search in Google Scholar

Stern, N.H., S. Peters, V. Bakhski, A. Bowen, C. Cameron, S. Catovsky, D. Crane, S. Cruickshank, S. Dietz, N. Edmondson, S.-L. Garbett, L. Hamid, G. Hoffman, D. Ingram, B. Jones, N. Patmore, H. Radcliffe, R. Sathiyarajah, M. Stock, C. Taylor, T. Vernon, H. Wanjie, and D. Zenghelis (2006). Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Stern, N.H., and C. Taylor (2007). Climate Change: Risks, Ethics and the Stern Review. Science, 317(5835): 203–204.Search in Google Scholar

Sterner, T., and U.M. Persson (2008). An. Even Sterner Review: Introducing Relative Prices into the Discounting Debate. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 2(1): 61–76.Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J. (1995). The Damage Costs of Climate Change toward More Comprehensive Calculations. Environmental and Resource Economics, 5(4): 353–374.Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J. (1997). On the Optimal Control of Carbon Dioxide Emissions: An Application of FUND. Environmental Modeling and Assessment, 2: 151–163.Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J. (1999). The Marginal Costs of Greenhouse Gas Emissions. Energy Journal, 20(1): 61–81.Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J. (2001). Equitable Cost-Benefit Analysis of Climate Change. Ecological Economics, 36(1): 71–85.Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J. (2002a). Estimates of the Damage Costs of Climate Change—Part 1: Benchmark Estimates. Environmental and Resource Economics, 21(1): 47–73.Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J. (2002b). Estimates of the Damage Costs of Climate Change—Part II: Dynamic Estimates. Environmental and Resource Economics, 21(2): 135–160.10.1023/A:1014539414591Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J. (2002c). Welfare Specifications and Optimal Control of Climate Change: An Application of FUND. Energy Economics, 24: 367–376.10.1016/S0140-9883(02)00010-5Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J. (2003). On Dual-Rate Discounting. Economic Modelling, 21: 95–98.Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J. (2005a). Emission Abatement versus Development as Strategies to Reduce Vulnerability to Climate Change: An Application of FUND. Environment and Development Economics, 10(5): 615–629.10.1017/S1355770X05002354Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J. (2005b). The Marginal Costs of Carbon Dioxide Emissions: An Assessment of the Uncertainties. Energy Policy, 33: 2064–2074.10.1016/j.enpol.2004.04.002Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J. (2006). Multi-Gas Emission Reduction for Climate Change Policy: An Application of FUND. Energy Journal (Multi-Greenhouse Gas Mitigation and Climate Policy Special Issue), 235–250.10.5547/ISSN0195-6574-EJ-VolSI2006-NoSI3-11Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J. (2008). Measuring International Inequality Aversion. Working Paper 254, Economic and Social Research Institute, Dublin.Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J., T.E. Downing, and N. Eyre (1999). The Marginal Costs of Radiatively-Active Gases. Institute for Environmental Studies, Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam.Search in Google Scholar

Tol, R.S.J., K.L. Ebi, and G.W. Yohe (2007). Infectious Disease, Development, and Climate Change: A Scenario Analysis. Environment and Development Economics, 12: 687–706.Search in Google Scholar

Weitzman, M.L. (2001). Gamma Discounting. American Economic Review, 91(1): 260–271.Search in Google Scholar

Weitzman, M.L. (2007). A Review of the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Journal of Economic Literature, 45(3): 703–724.Search in Google Scholar

Weyant, J.P. (2008). A Critique of the Stern Review’s Mitigation Cost Analyses and Integrated Assessment. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 2(1): 77–93.Search in Google Scholar

Winkler, R. (2009). Now or Never: Environmental Protection under Hyperbolic Discounting. http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2009-12.Search in Google Scholar

Yang, Z. (2003). Dual-Rate Discounting in Dynamic Economic-Environmental Modeling. Economic Modelling, 20: 941–957.Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2009-06-09
Published in Print: 2009-12-01

© 2009 David Anthoff et al., published by Sciendo

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

Downloaded on 27.11.2022 from frontend.live.degruyter.dgbricks.com/document/doi/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2009-24/html
Scroll Up Arrow