Jump to ContentJump to Main Navigation
Show Summary Details
More options …

Jürges, Hendrik

The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy

Editor-in-Chief: Ludwig, Sandra / Schmitz, Hendrik

Ed. by Barigozzi, Francesca / Brunner, Johann / Fleck, Robert / Mastrobuoni, Giovanni / Mendola, Mariapia / Requate, Till / de Vries, Frans / Wenzel, Tobias


IMPACT FACTOR 2018: 0.520
5-year IMPACT FACTOR: 0.556

CiteScore 2018: 0.54

SCImago Journal Rank (SJR) 2018: 0.356
Source Normalized Impact per Paper (SNIP) 2018: 0.394

Online
ISSN
1935-1682
See all formats and pricing
More options …
Volume 14, Issue 1

Issues

Volume 6 (2006)

Volume 4 (2004)

Volume 2 (2002)

Volume 1 (2001)

Market-Induced Rationalization and Welfare-Enhancing Cartels

Jan Tuinstra
  • Amsterdam School of Economics and CeNDEF, University of Amsterdam and Tinbergen Institute, Valckenierstraat 65–67, 1018 XE Amsterdam, The Netherlands
  • Email
  • Other articles by this author:
  • De Gruyter OnlineGoogle Scholar
/ Daan L. in ’t Veld
  • Corresponding author
  • Amsterdam School of Economics and CeNDEF, University of Amsterdam and Tinbergen Institute, Valckenierstraat 65–67, 1018 XE Amsterdam, The Netherlands
  • Email
  • Other articles by this author:
  • De Gruyter OnlineGoogle Scholar
Published Online: 2013-10-24 | DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/bejeap-2013-0005

Abstract

We show that incomplete cartels in quantity-setting oligopolies may increase welfare, without any efficiencies or synergies being internalized by cartel formation. The main intuition is that the cartel has an incentive to contract output and that the firms outside the cartel react to this by expanding output. If the outsiders are more efficient than the cartel firms, average production costs go down. We model collusion in a market structure with imperfect substitute goods. Even for relatively moderate differences in efficiency, total welfare may increase due to this market-induced rationalization, whereas the cartel remains profitable. We discuss why the effect can be relevant for sectors where new, superior products are developed. Because anti-cartel enforcement is costly, it is important for competition authorities to realize that not all cartels lead to a welfare loss.

Keywords: efficient cartels; cournot competition; rationalization of production

JEL Classification: L10; L41; D43

References

  • Bittner, T. 2005. “An Event Study of the Rhenish-Westphalian Coal Syndicate.” European Review of Economic History 9:337–64.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Bos, I., and E. Pot. 2012. “On the Possibility of Welfare-Enhancing Hard Core Cartels.” Journal of Economics 107:199–216.CrossrefWeb of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Cheung, F. K. 1992. “Two Remarks on the Equilibrium Analysis of Horizontal Merger.” Economics Letters 40:119–23.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Daughety, A. F. 1990. “Beneficial Concentration.” American Economic Review 80:1231–7.Google Scholar

  • Deneckere, R., and C. Davidson. 1985. “Incentives to Form Coalitions with Bertrand Competition.” RAND Journal of Economics 16:473–86.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Farrell, J., and M. L. Katz. 2006. “The Economics of Welfare Standards in Antitrust.” Competition Policy International 2:3–28.Google Scholar

  • Farrell, J., and C. Shapiro. 1990. “Horizontal Mergers: An Equilibrium Analysis.” American Economic Review 80:107–26.Google Scholar

  • Häckner, J. 2000. “A Note on Price and Quantity Competition in Differentiated Oligopolies.” Journal of Economic Theory 93:233–9.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Kinghorn, J. R. 1996. “Kartells and Cartel Theory: Evidence from Early Twentieth Century German Coal, Iron and Steel Industries.” Essays in Economic and Business History 14:339–63.Google Scholar

  • Kolstadt, C. D. 1994. “Hotelling Rents in Hotelling Space: Product Differentiation in Exhaustible Resource Markets.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 26:163–80.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Matsui, A. 1989. “Consumer-Benefited Cartels under Strategic Capital Investment Competition.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 7:451–70.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Montero, J.-P., and J. I. Guzman. 2010. “Output-Expanding Collusion in the Presence of a Competitive Fringe.” Journal of Industrial Economics 58:106–26.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Panayatou, T. 1978. “OPEC as a Model for Copper Exporters: Potential Gains and Cartel Behavior.” The Developing Economies 17:203–19.Google Scholar

  • Perry, M., and R. Porter. 1985. “Oligopoly and the Incentive for Horizontal Merger.” American Economic Review 75:219–27.Google Scholar

  • Posada, P., and O. R. Straume. 2004. “Merger, Partial Collusion and Relocation.” Journal of Economics 83:243–65.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Ross, T. W. 1992. “Cartel Stability and Product Differentiation.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 10:1–13.CrossrefWeb of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Salant, S. W., S. Switzer, and R. J. Reynolds. 1983. “Losses from Horizontal Merger: The Effects of an Exogenous Change in Industry Structure on the Cournot–Nash Equilibrium.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98:185–99.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Singh, N., and X. Vives. 1984. “Price and Quantity Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly.” RAND Journal of Economics 15:546–54.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Sjostrom, W. 1989. “Collusion in Ocean Shipping: A Test of Monopoly and Empty Core Models.” Journal of Political Economy 97:1160–79.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Stennek, J. 2003. “Horizontal Mergers Without Synergies May Increase Consumer Welfare.” Topics in Economic Analysis & Policy 3, Article 2.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Taylor, J. E. 2010. “The Welfare Impact of Collusion under Various Industry Characteristics: APanel Examination of Efficient Cartel Theory.” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 10, Article 97.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

About the article

Published Online: 2013-10-24


While we borrow this term from Stennek (2003), we use it in a more common setting. The model of Stennek (2003) is special in the sense that the competitive equilibrium is inefficient, because the cost functions are assumed to be private knowledge.

Although the effect we describe is very intuitive, we have just found one paper that captures it implicitly. The numerical example of Cheung (1992, 120), which deals with synergies from mergers, includes a welfare-enhancing (but unprofitable) cartel (for the special case of zero synergies).

Following Singh and Vives (1984), the linear inverse demand functions can be derived from a utility function that is quadratic in consumption of commodities 1 and 2 and linear in consumption of a numeraire composite commodity. We will depart from Singh and Vives (1984), who consider a (differentiated) duopoly, by allowing for multiple producers of each commodity.

In another version of the model, we adopted a constant elasticity of substitution (CES) framework, so that the two goods range from perfect substitutes to perfect complements. We found here as well that welfare-enhancing cartels are possible (and profitable). Because the CES framework does not allow for analytical solutions but requires numerical calculations, we present the results with linear inverse demand functions.

Our analysis is centered around the assumption that industry 2 is cost-efficient (i.e. , but it also applies to situations where products from industry 2 are qualitatively superior. In fact, this could be easily incorporated in the model by a reinterpretation of . After generalizing the inverse demand functions to for and , assuming means that industry 2 produces higher quality goods than industry 1, as measured in a vertical sense; see Häckner (2000). Solving the more general model leads us to redefine , a combined measure of the differences in efficiency and quality. The expressions in Lemma 1, Proposition 2, Lemma 3, and Proposition 4 remain unchanged (note that in expression 2 the term ( has to be replaced with ). All our results can, therefore, be interpreted in terms of differences in quality as well as efficiency. We thank an anonymous referee for this suggestion.

Note that the profitability of the cartel (relative to the competitive case) does not depend on marginal costs c or d. This is a consequence of assuming linear cost and inverse demand functions. However, the efficiency difference does determine market shares of individual firms. Therefore, the minimal number of firms to join for profitability might represent an arbitrarily small market share. In particular, the market share of industry 1 firms, , equals for which becomes arbitrary small for close enough to .

It is straightforward to show that, assuming firms use grim trigger strategies, the critical discount factor for a sustainable cartel in the infinitely repeated game is given by This critical discount factor is increasing in m and , non-monotonic in n and strictly below 1 as long as condition [3] holds.

As profitability of a cartel does not depend on marginal costs (see Footnote 5), condition [3] is equally valid for the alternative cartel with m and n reversed. Also, the critical discount factor (see Footnote 6) is identical with m and n reversed. Analysis of the examples in Figure 2 makes clear that the alternative cartel is for most cases either unprofitable or requires a higher discount factor than the cartel of inefficient firms. The only exception is for and , in which case a cartel of efficient firms is sustainable for a wider range of discount factors when or (but not when ).


Citation Information: The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, Volume 14, Issue 1, Pages 189–202, ISSN (Online) 1935-1682, ISSN (Print) 2194-6108, DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/bejeap-2013-0005.

Export Citation

©2014 by Walter de Gruyter Berlin / Boston.Get Permission

Comments (0)

Please log in or register to comment.
Log in