Jump to ContentJump to Main Navigation
Show Summary Details
More options …

Auriol, Emmanuelle

The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy

Editor-in-Chief: Jürges, Hendrik / Ludwig, Sandra

Ed. by Brunner, Johann / Fleck, Robert / Mendola, Mariapia / Requate, Till / Schirle, Tammy / de Vries, Frans / Zulehner, Christine

4 Issues per year


IMPACT FACTOR 2017: 0.306
5-year IMPACT FACTOR: 0.492

CiteScore 2017: 0.50

SCImago Journal Rank (SJR) 2017: 0.414
Source Normalized Impact per Paper (SNIP) 2017: 0.531

Online
ISSN
1935-1682
See all formats and pricing
More options …
Volume 15, Issue 4

Issues

Volume 6 (2006)

Volume 4 (2004)

Volume 2 (2002)

Volume 1 (2001)

The Dynamics of Offshoring and Institutions

Fredrik Heyman / Patrik Gustavsson Tingvall
Published Online: 2015-06-02 | DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/bejeap-2014-0073

Abstract

Previous research has found that weak institutions can hamper investment and alter patterns of trade. However, little is known about the impact of institutional quality on offshoring. This lack of knowledge is surprising, given that offshoring has become an important part of many firms’ internationalization strategies. This study uses detailed firm-level data for the 1997–2005 period to examine the relationship between institutional quality in 113 source countries and offshoring by Swedish firms. The results suggest that weak institutions are negatively related to offshoring in general and to the offshoring of R&D- and relationship specificity-intensive inputs in particular. An analysis of learning effects suggests that the impact of weak institutions on the offshoring of relationship specificity-intensive inputs vanishes when firms return to countries from which they have previous market experience. Our results are robust to the use of various measures of institutional quality.

Keywords: offshoring; institutions; firm-level data

JEL: F14; F23; P48

References

  • Abram, C. E. 2008. “How Much Do Perceptions of Corruption Really Tell Us?” Economics 2:3.Google Scholar

  • Adams, J. D. 2005. “Industrial R&D Laboratories: Windows on Black Boxes?” The Journal of Technology Transfer 30:129–37.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Aeberhardt, R., B. Ines, and H. Fadinger. 2011. “Learning, Incomplete Contracts and Export Dynamics: Theory and Evidence from French Firms,” Working Paper 1006, Department of Economics, University of Vienna.Google Scholar

  • Altomonte, C., and G. Békés. 2010. “Trade Complexity and Productivity,” CeFiG Working Papers 12, Center for Firms in the Global Economy.Google Scholar

  • Alvarez, R., and R. Lopez. 2008. “Is Exporting a Source of Productivity Spillovers?” Review of World Economics 144 (4):723–49.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Anderson, J. E. 1979. “A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation.” American Economic Review 69 (1):106–16.Google Scholar

  • Anderson, J. E., and D. Marcoullier. 2002. “Insecurity and the Pattern of Trade: An Empirical Investigation.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 84 (2):342–52.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Anderson, J. E., and E. van Wincoop. 2003. “Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle.” American Economic Review 93 (1):170–92.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Antràs, P. 2003. “Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (4):1375–418.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Antràs, P., and E. Helpman. 2004. “Global Sourcing.” Journal of Political Economy 112 (3):552–80.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Antràs, P., and E. Helpman. 2006. “Contractual Frictions and Global Sourcing.” NBER WP No. 12747.Google Scholar

  • Arellano, M., and O. Bover. 1995. “Another Look at the Instrumental Variable Estimation of Error-Components Models.” Journal of Econometrics 68:29–51.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Araujo, L., G. Mion, and E. Ornelas. 2012. “Institutions and Export Dynamics.” Mimeo, Michigan State University and London School of Economics.Google Scholar

  • Baldwin, R., and D. Taglioni. 2006. “Gravity for Dummies and Dummies for Gravity Equations.” NBER WP No. 12516.Google Scholar

  • Bartel, A., S. Lach, and N. Sicherman. 2005. “Outsourcing and Technological Change.” NBER WP No. 11158.Google Scholar

  • Benedicits, De. L., and C. Vicarelli. 2010. “Dummies for Gravity and Gravity for Policies: Mission Impossible?” Accessed January 2010. Mimeo.www.ReserchGate.net.

  • Benedicits, De. L., and L. Salvatici. 2007. The Trade Impact of European Union Preferential Policies: An Analysis Through Gravity Models, edited by Benedicits, De. L., and Salvatici, L. London, New York: Springer.Google Scholar

  • Bergstrand, J. H. 1985. “The Gravity Equation in International Trade: Some Microeconomic Foundations and Empirical Evidence.” Review of Economics and Statistics 67 (3):474–81.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Bergstrand, J. H. 1989. “The Generalized Gravity Equation, Monopolistic Competition, and the Factor-Proportions Theory in International Trade.” Review of Economics and Statistics 71 (1):143–53.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Bernard, A., and J. B. Jensen. 2004. “Why Some Firms Export.” Review of Economics and Statistics 86 (2):561–9.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Blundell, R., and S. Bond. 1998. “Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models.” Journal of Econometrics 87:115–43.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Caetano, J. M., and A. Caleiro. 2005. “Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment, What kind of relationship is there?” Working Paper No. 18, Department of Economics, University of Évora.Google Scholar

  • Casaburi, L., and V. Gattai. 2009. “Why FDI? An Empirical Assessment Based on Contractual Incompleteness and Dissipation of Intangible Assets.” Working Paper No. 164, Department of Economics, University of Milano-Bicocca.Google Scholar

  • Dai, M., and M. Yu. 2013. “Firm R&D, Absorptive Capacity and Learning by Exporting: Firm-Level Evidence from China.” The World Economy 3 (9):1131–1145.CrossrefWeb of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Deardorff, A. V. 1998. “Determinants of Bilateral Trade: Does Gravity Work in a Neoclassical World?” In The Regionalization of the World Economy, edited by J. A. Frankel, 7–22. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar

  • Depken, C. A., and R. J. Sonora. 2005. “Asymmetric Effects of Economic Freedom on International Trade Flows.” International Journal of Business and Economics 4 (2):141–55.Google Scholar

  • Egger, P. H., and H. Winner. 2006. “How Corruption Influences Foreign Direct Investment: A Panel Data Study.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 54 (2):459–86.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Fafchamps, M., S. E. Hamine, and M. Zeufack. 2002. “Learning to Export: Evidence from Moroccan Manufacturing.” World Bank Policy Research Paper No. 2827.Google Scholar

  • Feenstra, R. C., and G. H. Hanson. 1996. “Globalization, Outsourcing, and Wage Inequality.” American Economic Review 86 (2):240–5.Web of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Feenstra, R. 2004. “Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence,” Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar

  • Feenstra, R. C., and G. H. Hanson. 2005. “Ownership and Control in Outsourcing to China: Estimating the Property Rights Theory of the Firm.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 120 (2):729–62.Google Scholar

  • Ferguson, S., and S. Formai. 2013. “Institution-Driven Comparative Advantage, Complex Goods and Organizational Choice.” Journal of Institutional Economics 90:193–200.Web of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Grossman, G. M., J. Sanford, and O. D. Hart. 1986. “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration.” Journal of Political Economy 94 (4):691–719.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Grossman, G. M., and E. Helpman. 2002. “Integration versus Outsourcing in Industry Equilibrium.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (1):85–120.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Grossman, G. M., and E. Helpman. 2003. “Outsourcing versus FDI in Industry Equilibrium.” Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (2–3):317–27.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Grossman, G. M., and E. Helpman. 2005. “Outsourcing in a Global Economy.” Review of Economic Studies 72:135–59.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Grossman, G. M., and E. Rossi-Hansberg. 2012. “Tasks Trade between Similar Countries.” Econometrica 80 (2):593–629.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Hart, O. D. 1995. Firms, Contracts and Financial Structure. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar

  • Hart, O. D., and J. Moore. 1990. “Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm” Journal of Political Economy 98 (6):1119–58.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Habib, M., and L. Zurawicki. 2002. “Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment” Journal of International Business Studies 33 (2):291–307.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Hakkala, K., P. -J. Norbäck, and H. Svaleryd. 2008. “Asymmetric Effects of Corruption on FDI: Evidence from Swedish Multinational Firms” The Review of Economics and Statistics 90 (4):627–42.CrossrefWeb of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Hakkala, K., F. Heyman, and F. Sjöholm. 2014. “Multinational Firms, Acquisitions and Job Tasks.” European Economic Review 66:248–65.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Hijzen, A. 2005. “A Bird’s Eye View of International Outsourcing: Data, Measurement and Labour Demand Effects.” Economie Internationale 4 (104):45–63.Google Scholar

  • Hummels, D., D. Rapoport, and K. Yi. 1998. “Vertical Specialization and the Changing Nature of World Trade.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 4 (2):79–99.Google Scholar

  • Hummels, D., J. Ishii, and K. Yi. 2001. “The Nature and Growth of Vertical Specialisation in World Trade.” Journal of International Economics 54 (1):75–96.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Kaufman, D., A. Kraay, and P. Zoido. 1999. “Aggregating Governance Indicators.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2195.Google Scholar

  • Kim, J. -O. 1979. Introduction to Factor Analysis: What It Is and How to Do It. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications, Inc.Google Scholar

  • Kukenova, M., and M. Strieborny. 2009. “Investment in Relationship-Specific Assets: Does Finance Matter?” MPRA Paper 15229, University Library of Munich, Germany.Google Scholar

  • Mayer, T., and S. Zignago. 2006. “Notes on CEPII’s Distance Measures.” Accessed May 3, 2006. www.cepii.fr.

  • Márquez-Ramos, L., I. Mart’tinez-Zarzoso, and C. Suárez-Burgute. 2012. “Trade Policy Versus Trade Facilitation: An Application Using “Good Old” OLS.” Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, Vol. 6, 2012-11. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2056942 or http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2012-11.

  • Massini, S., N. Pern-Ajchariyawong, and A. Y. Lewin. 2010. “Role of Corporate-Wide Offshoring Strategy on Offshoring Drivers, Risks and Performance.” Industry and Innovation 17 (4):337–71.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Mayer, T., and S. Zignago. 2006. “Notes on CEPII’s Distance Measures.” MPRA Paper 26469.Google Scholar

  • Melitz, M. 2003. “The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity.” Econometrica 71 (6):1695–725.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Méon, P. -G., and K. Sekkat. 2006. “Institutional Quality and Trade: Which Institutions? Which Trade?” DULBEA Working Papers 06–06. RS, ULB, Universite Libre de Bruxelles.Google Scholar

  • Miaojie, Y., and D. Mi. 2011. “Pre-Export R&D, Exporting and Productivity Gains: Evidence from Chinese Firms.” CTRG WP No. 2011/011.Google Scholar

  • Michel, B., and F. Rycx. 2014. “Productivity Gains and Spillover from Offshoring.” Review of International Economics 22 (1):73–85.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Mocan, N. 2008. “What Determines Corruption? International Evidence from Microdata.” Economic Inquiry 46 (4):493–510.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Niccolini, M. 2007. “Institutions and Offshoring Decision.” CESifo WP No. 2074.Google Scholar

  • North, D. C. 1991. “Institutions.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (1):97–112.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Nunn, N. 2007. “Relationship-Specificity, Incomplete Contracts and the Pattern of Trade.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 122 (2):569–600.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Ranjan, P., and J. Y. Lee. 2007. “Contract Enforcement and International Trade.” Economics and Politics 19 (2):191–218.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Rauch, J.E. 1999. “Networks versus markets in international trade.” Journal of International Economics 48 (1):7–35.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Rauch, J. E., and J. Watson. 2003. “Starting Small in an Unfamiliar Environment.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 21 (7):1021–42.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Segerstrom, P. S., and S. Stepanok. 2013. “Learning How to Export”, Kiel Institute for the World Economy, WP No. 1801.Google Scholar

  • Söderlund, B., and P. Tingvall Gustavsson. 2014. “Dynamic Effects of Institutions on Firm-Level Exports.” Review of World Economics 150 (2):277–308.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Teorell, C., H. Samanni, and B. Rothstein. 2009. “The Quality of Government Dataset,” version 17 June 2009.Google Scholar

  • Tinbergen, J. 1962. Shaping the World Economy: Suggestions for an International Economic Policy. New York: The Twentieth Century Fund.Google Scholar

  • Tingvall, G. P. 2012. “Dynamic Effects of Corruption on Offshoring.” Ratio Working Paper No. 182.Google Scholar

  • Turrini, A., and T. V. Ypersele. 2010. “Traders, Courts, and the Border Effect Puzzle.” Regional Science and Urban Economics 40:81–91.CrossrefWeb of ScienceGoogle Scholar

About the article

Published Online: 2015-06-02

Published in Print: 2015-10-01


Funding: Fredrik Heyman gratefully acknowledges the financial support from the Swedish Research Council and the Swedish Research Council for Health and Working Life and Welfare (Forte). Both authors also gratefully acknowledge the financial support from the Torsten Söderbergs Research Foundation.


Citation Information: The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, Volume 15, Issue 4, Pages 1975–2016, ISSN (Online) 1935-1682, ISSN (Print) 2194-6108, DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/bejeap-2014-0073.

Export Citation

©2015 by De Gruyter.Get Permission

Comments (0)

Please log in or register to comment.
Log in