Jump to ContentJump to Main Navigation
Show Summary Details
More options …

The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics

Editor-in-Chief: Cavalcanti, Tiago / Kambourov, Gueorgui

Ed. by Abraham, Arpad / Carceles-Poveda , Eva / Debortoli, Davide / Lambertini, Luisa / Nimark, Kristoffer / Wang, Pengfei

2 Issues per year


IMPACT FACTOR 2016: 0.043
5-year IMPACT FACTOR: 0.376

CiteScore 2016: 0.36

SCImago Journal Rank (SJR) 2016: 0.312
Source Normalized Impact per Paper (SNIP) 2016: 0.272

Online
ISSN
1935-1690
See all formats and pricing
More options …

Productivity and resource misallocation in Latin America1)

Matias Busso
  • Corresponding author
  • Research Department, Inter-American Development Bank, 1300 New York Avenue NW, Washington, DC 20577, USA
  • Email
  • Other articles by this author:
  • De Gruyter OnlineGoogle Scholar
/ Lucia Madrigal / Carmen Pagés
  • Labor Markets Unit, Inter-American Development Bank, 1300 New York Avenue NW, Washington, DC, USA
  • Other articles by this author:
  • De Gruyter OnlineGoogle Scholar
Published Online: 2013-06-19 | DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/bejm-2012-0087

Abstract

Total factor productivity (TFP) in Latin America has declined relative to the US since the mid-1970s. This paper applies a comparable methodology to firm-level data of ten Latin American countries to quantify the heterogeneity of firm productivity and the extent to which resource misallocation can explain lower aggregate TFP. In general, productivity heterogeneity and resource misallocation are found to be much larger than in the US. Achieving an efficient allocation of resources could boost manufacturing TFP between 41% and 122% depending on the countries and years considered. We also find that difficulty in access to capital and restrictive labor regulations explain distortions faced by firms.

Keywords: distortions; firm heterogeneity; firm productivity; Latin America; misallocation costs; total factor productivity; JEL Classification: D24; O47; L25

References

  • Banerjee, A., and E. Duflo. 2005. “Growth Theory through the Lens of Development Economics.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, edited by P. Aghion and P. Durlauf. Vol. 1a. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier.Google Scholar

  • Bergoeing, R., P. Kehoe, T. Kehoe, and R. Soto. 2002. “Policy-Driven Productivity in Chile and Mexico in the 1980’s and 1990’s.” American Economic Review 92 (2): 16–21.Google Scholar

  • Blyde, J., and E. Fernández-Arias. 2004. Why does Latin America Grow More Slowly? IDB Publications 22698, Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.Google Scholar

  • Buera, F., J. Kaboski, and Y. Shin. 2011. “Finance and Development: A Tale of Two Sectors.” American Economic Review 101 (5): 1964–2002.CrossrefWeb of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Busso M., L. Madrigal, and C. Pagés. 2010. “Productivity from the Bottom Up: Firms and Resource Misallocation in Latin America” In The Age of Productivity: Transforming Economies from the Bottom Up (Development in the Americas), edited by Carmen Pagés. New York, United States:Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar

  • Busso, M., M. Fazio, and S. Levy. 2012. (In)Formal and (Un)Productive: The Productivity Costs of Excessive Informality in Mexico. Research Department Publications 4789, Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank, Research Department.Google Scholar

  • Cole, H., L. Ohanian, A. Riascos, and J. Schmitz. 2005. “Latin America in the rearview mirror.” Journal of Monetary Economics 52 (1): 69–107.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Daude, C., and E. Fernández-Arias. 2010. “On the Role of Aggregate Productivity and Factor Accumulation in Economic Development in Latin America and the Caribbean.” IDB Working Paper IDB-WP-131. Washington, DC, USA: Inter-American Development Bank.Google Scholar

  • de la Torre, A., A. Ize, and S. Schmukler. 2012. Financial Development in Latin America and the Caribbean: The Road Ahead, Washington, DC:World Bank.Google Scholar

  • De Vries, Gaaitzen. 2009. Productivity in a Distorted Market: The Case of Brazil’s Retail Sector. Memorandum GD-112. Groningen, The Netherlands: University of Groningen, Groningen Growth and Development Centre.Google Scholar

  • D’Erasmo, P., and H. Moscoso Boedo. 2012. “Financial Structure, Informality and Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics 59 (3): 286–302.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Duarte, M., and D. Restuccia. 2010. “The Role of the Structural Transformation in Aggregate Productivity.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (1): 129–173.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Ferreira, P., S. Pessôa, and F. Veloso. 2013. “On The Evolution Of Total Factor Productivity In Latin America.” Economic Inquiry 51 (1): 16–30.CrossrefWeb of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Gomez Sabaine, J., and J. Jimenez. 2012. “Tax Structure and Tax Evasion in Latin America.” Macroeconomia del Desarrollo 118. CEPALGoogle Scholar

  • Guner, N., G. Ventura, and Y. Xu. 2008. “Macroeconomic Implications of Size-Dependent Policies.” Review of Economic Dynamics 11 (4): 721–744.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Heckman, J., and Carmen Pagés. 2003. “Law and Employment: Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean”. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper #10129. December. Cambridge, MA, USA.Google Scholar

  • Hopenhayn, H., and R. Rogerson. 1993. “Job Turnover and Policy Evaluation: A General Equilibrium Analysis.” Journal of Political Economy 101 (5): 915–938.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Howitt, P. 2000. “Endogenous Growth and Cross-Country Income Differences.” American Economic Review 90 (4): 829–846.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Hsieh, C., and P. Klenow. 2009. “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (4): 1403–1448.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Klenow, P., and A. Rodriguez-Clare. 2005. “Externalities and Growth.” Handbook of Economic Growth. In Handbook of Economic Growth, edited by P. Aghion and S. Durlauf, 1st ed., Vol. 1, Chapter 11, 817–861. The Netherlands: Elsevier.Google Scholar

  • Levy, S. 2008. Good Intentions, Bad Outcomes: Social Policy, Informality, and Economic Growth in Mexico. Washington, DC, USA: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar

  • Midrigan, V., and D. Xu. 2010. “Finance and Misallocation: Evidence from Plant-level Data.” NBER Working Papers 15647, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar

  • Moll, B. 2012. “Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation?” mimeo.Google Scholar

  • Parente, S., and E. Prescott. 1994. “Barriers to Technology Adoption and Development.” Journal of Political Economy 102 (2): 298–321.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Parente, S.L., and E.C. Prescott. 2002. Barriers to Riches. Cambridge, USA: MIT Press.Google Scholar

  • Peek, J., and E. Rosengren. 2005. “Unnatural Selection: Perverse Incentives and the Misallocation of Credit in Japan.” American Economic Review 95 (4): 1144–1166.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Prescott, E., and S. Parente. 1999. “Monopoly Rights: A Barrier to Riches.” American Economic Review 89 (5): 1216–1233.Google Scholar

  • Restuccia, D. 2008. “The Latin American Development Problem.” Working Paper 318. Toronto, Canada: University of Toronto, Economics Department.Google Scholar

  • Restuccia, D., and R. Rogerson. 2008. “Policy Distortions and Aggregate Productivity with Heterogeneous Establishments.” Review of Economic Dynamics 11 (4): 707–720.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

About the article

Corresponding author: Matias Busso, Research Department, Inter-American Development Bank, 1300 New York Avenue NW, Washington, DC 20577, USA, e-mail:


Published Online: 2013-06-19

Published in Print: 2013-01-01


See Blyde and Fernandez-Arias (2004); Cole et al. (2005); Restuccia (2008); Daude and Fernández-Arias (2010); Ferreira, Pessôa, and Veloso (2013).

See Parente and Prescott (1994, 1999, 2002); Howitt (2000); Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare (2005).

See Bergoeing et al. (2005), Cole et al. (2005), Banerjee and Duflo (2005), Restuccia and Rogerson (2008) and Hsieh and Klenow (2009) propose an alternative explanation.

As the elasticity of substitution between plant value-added s increases, intermediate inputs become closer to perfect substitutes. At the limit, only the highest-productivity good is produced.

As reported by the Manufacturing Industry Database hosted by the NBER.

In the Section 4, we assess the robustness of the main results to alternative hypothesis about these two parameters.

The average TFPQ is taken via a geometric average:

The average TFPR is:

We also used information from the WBES for Argentina, Chile, Bolivia, Ecuador, Mexico, Peru and Uruguay. See Table A3.

Most of the official data reside in the national institutes of statistics. Therefore we relied on a network of research teams that helped us running the codes. The computations in each country were made by the following reseachers: Argentina programs were run by A. Neumeyer and G. Sandleris; in Bolivia by C.G. Machicado and J.C. Birbuet; in Brazil, by C. Ferraz; in Chile and with the WBES, by M. Busso, L. Madrigal, and C. Pagés; in Colombia, by A. Camacho and E. Conover; Ecuador, by C. Arellano; El Salvador, by J.P. Atal, M. Busso and C. Cisneros; Mexico, by P. Martínez; Uruguay, by C. Casacuberta and N. Gandelman; and in Venezuela, by L. Kolovitch. In all cases the computations were done using a common program and, as much as possible, the same variable and sample definitions was used, too. All codes are available from the authors upon request.

Interestingly, there is more productive heterogeneity in these two economies than in China as reported in Hsieh and Klenow (2009), regardless of the measure of dispersion employed. This may be, at least partly driven by the fact that Chinese data covers plants with revenues above US$600,000 and therefore excludes the smallest, possibly least productive firms.

It should also be noted that some of the dispersion is not due to real differences in productivities but to differences in quality within the sector which translate to prices.

In the Appendix Table A1 we provide other dispersion methods for the distributions of the three variables.

Duarte and Restuccia (2010) point to the lower degree of competition in the service sectors in relation to manufacturing as one potential reason why across countries there is more convergence to the world frontier in manufacturing than in the service sector.

See, Banerjee and Duflo (2005); Buera, Kaboski and Shin (2011); Moll (2012); Midrigan and Xu (2010); D’Erasmo and Boedo (2012).

The argument is that productivity determines size, with more productive firms growing to be larger, rather than the other way around: i.e., larger firms become more productive as a result of their size. Yet a positive relationship between total factor productivity and size can also be driven by economies of scale. This is because most methods of computing TFP assume constant returns to scale; therefore, increasing returns to scale would wrongly show up as higher TPF for bigger firms.

In particular, the survey asks “Is Oisc ‘No Obstacle’, ‘a Minor Obstacle’, ‘a Major Obstacle’, or ‘a Very Severe Obstacle’ to the current operations of this establishment?” where the obstacles Oisc are, for example, access to finance, labor regulations, functioning of the courts, etc.

The scales are based on the following variables: (I) Restricted Access to Capital: (1) Degree of obstacles for current operation: Access to finance; (2) Access to finance listed as a top 3 obstacle; (3) Has a line of credit or loan from a financial institution; (4) Has its financial statements certified by an external auditor. (II) Restrictive Labor Regulations: (1) Degree of obstacle for current operations: labor regulations; (2) Degree of obstacle for current operations: inadequately educated labor force; (3) Degree of obstacle for current operations: practices of informal competitors; (4) Labor regulations listed as a top 3 obstacle; (5) Practices of informal competitors listed as a top 3 obstacle; (6) Percentage of workforce unionized; (7) Labor regulations affect decisions of hiring or firing permanent workers; (8) % of workers declared for payroll taxes. (III) Bad Functioning of Courts: (1) Degree of obstacle to current operations: functioning of the courts; (2) Functioning of courts listed as a top 3 obstacle; (3) Agreement with: The court system is Fair, impartial and uncorrupted; (4) Agreement with: The court system is Quick; (5) Agreement with: The court system is Affordable; (6) Agreement with: The court system is Able to enforce its decisions. (IV) Detrimental Regulations and Institution Instability: (1) Degree of obstacle for the current operation: licensing and permits; (2) Degree of obstacle for current operations: customs and trade regulations; (3) Any regulation listed as a top 3 obstacle; (4) Degree of obstacle for current operation: political instability; (5) Degree of obstacle for current operation: corruption; (6) Degree of obstacle for the current operation: macroeconomic instability; (7) Any instability listed as a top 3 obstacle. (V) Unfair Taxation: (1) Degree of obstacle of taxes for the current operations of the establishment; (2) Degree of obstacle for the current operation: tax administration; (3) Taxation listed as a top 3 obstacle; (4) % of sales declared for corporate or sales taxes; (5) Establishment was visited and or inspected by tax officials; (6) Located in capital city (i.e., easier to monitor).

The code is available at Matias Busso’s webpage.

The views expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the opinions of the Inter-American Development Bank.


Citation Information: The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, ISSN (Online) 1935-1690, ISSN (Print) 2194-6116, DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/bejm-2012-0087.

Export Citation

©2013 by Walter de Gruyter Berlin Boston. Copyright Clearance Center

Citing Articles

Here you can find all Crossref-listed publications in which this article is cited. If you would like to receive automatic email messages as soon as this article is cited in other publications, simply activate the “Citation Alert” on the top of this page.

[1]
Diego Restuccia and Richard Rogerson
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2017, Volume 31, Number 3, Page 151
[2]
Mykola Ryzhenkov
Journal of Comparative Economics, 2016, Volume 44, Number 1, Page 41
[3]
Manuel García-Santana and Roberto Ramos
SERIEs, 2015, Volume 6, Number 3, Page 279
[4]
Siwapong Dheera-Aumpon
Asian-Pacific Economic Literature, 2014, Volume 28, Number 2, Page 63

Comments (0)

Please log in or register to comment.
Log in