Jump to ContentJump to Main Navigation
Show Summary Details
More options …

The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics

Editor-in-Chief: Cavalcanti, Tiago / Kambourov, Gueorgui

Ed. by Abraham, Arpad / Carceles-Poveda , Eva / Debortoli, Davide / Lambertini, Luisa / Nimark, Kristoffer / Wang, Pengfei

2 Issues per year


IMPACT FACTOR 2016: 0.043
5-year IMPACT FACTOR: 0.376

CiteScore 2016: 0.36

SCImago Journal Rank (SJR) 2016: 0.312
Source Normalized Impact per Paper (SNIP) 2016: 0.272

Online
ISSN
1935-1690
See all formats and pricing
More options …

Required reserves as a credit policy tool

Yasin Mimir
  • Corresponding author
  • Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, Istanbul School of Central Banking, Fener Kalamış Cad., Atlıhan Sk. No: 30/A, Kadıköy, Istanbul, Turkey
  • Email
  • Other articles by this author:
  • De Gruyter OnlineGoogle Scholar
/ Enes Sunel
  • Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, Research and Monetary Policy Department, Istiklal Cad. No: 10 Ulus, Ankara, Turkey
  • Other articles by this author:
  • De Gruyter OnlineGoogle Scholar
/ Temel Taşkın
  • Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, Research and Monetary Policy Department, Istiklal Cad. No: 10 Ulus, Ankara, Turkey
  • Other articles by this author:
  • De Gruyter OnlineGoogle Scholar
Published Online: 2013-06-20 | DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/bejm-2012-0093

Abstract

This paper quantitatively investigates the role of reserve requirements as a credit policy tool. We build a monetary dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model with a banking sector in which an agency problem between households and banks leads to endogenous capital constraints for the latter. In this setup, a countercyclical required reserves ratio (RRR) rule that responds to expected credit growth is found to countervail the negative effects of the financial accelerator mechanism triggered by productivity and bank capital shocks. Furthermore, it reduces the procyclicality of the financial system compared to a fixed RRR policy regime. The credit policy is most effective when the economy is hit by a financial shock. A time-varying RRR policy reduces the intertemporal distortions created by the fluctuations in credit spreads at the expense of generating higher inflation volatility, indicating an interesting trade-off between price stability and financial stability.

Keywords: banking sector; time-varying reserve requirements; macroeconomic; financial shocks; JEL Classification: E44; E51; G21; G28

References

  • Angelini, P., S. Neri, and F. Panetta. 2012. “Monetary and Macroprudential Policies.” European Central Bank Working Paper No. 1449.Google Scholar

  • Angeloni, I., and E. Faia. 2009. “A Tale of Two Policies: Prudential Regulation and Monetary Policy with Fragile Banks.” Kiel Institute for the World Economy Working Paper No. 1569.Google Scholar

  • Başçı, E. 2012. “The IMF.” Paper presented at the World Bank Annual Meetings, October. Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey.Google Scholar

  • Beau, D., L. Clerc, and B. Mojon. 2012. Macro-Prudential Policy and the Conduct of Monetary Policy. Mimeo, Banque de France.Google Scholar

  • Beneš, J., and K. Lees. 2010. “Multi-Period Fixed Rate Loans, Housing and Monetary Policy in Small Open Economies.” Reserve Bank of New Zealand Discussion Paper Series No. 2010-03.Google Scholar

  • Benigno, G., H. Chen, C. Otrok, A. Rebucci, and E. R. Young. 2010. “Revisiting Overborrowing and Its Policy Implications.” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 7872.Google Scholar

  • Benigno, G., H. Chen, C. Otrok, A. Rebucci, and E. R. Young. 2011. “Financial Crisis and Macro-Prudential Policies.” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 8175.Google Scholar

  • Bernanke, B. S., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist. 1999. “The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework.” In Handbook of Macroeconomics, edited by J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford, vol. 1C. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar

  • Borio, C., and M. Drehmann. 2009. “Assessing the Risk of Banking Crises Revisited.” BIS Quarterly Review, March, 29–46.Google Scholar

  • BRSA. 2011. “Financial Markets Report.” Banking Regulation and Supervision Agency, vol. 24.Google Scholar

  • Brunnermeier, M. K., and L. H. Pedersen. 2009. “Market Liquidity and Funding Liquidity.” Review of Financial Studies 22 (6): 2201–2238.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Brunnermeier, M. K., and Y. Sannikov. 2011. A Macroeconomic Model with a Financial Sector. Mimeo, Princeton University.Google Scholar

  • CBRT. 2011. “Inflation Report.” Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, vol. IV.Google Scholar

  • CBRT. 2012a. “Financial Stability Report.” Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, vol. 14.Google Scholar

  • CBRT. 2012b. “Inflation Report.” Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, vol. IV.Google Scholar

  • Christensen, I., C. Meh, and K. Moran. 2011. “Bank Leverage Regulation and Macroeconomic Dynamics.” Bank of Canada Working Paper No. 2011-32.Google Scholar

  • Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and C. L. Evans. 2005. “Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy.” Journal of Political Economy 113 (1): 1–45.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Cooley, T., and G. Hansen. 1989. “The Inflation Tax in a Real Business Cycle Model.” American Economic Review 79 (4): 733–748.Google Scholar

  • Cúrdia, V., and M. Woodford. 2010. “Credit Spreads and Monetary Policy.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42 (Suppl 6): 3–35.Web of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Diamond, D. W., and R. G. Rajan. 2001. “Liquidity Risk, Liquidity Creation, and Financial Fragility: A Theory of Banking.” Journal of Political Economy 109 (2): 287–327.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Faia, E., and T. Monacelli. 2007. “Optimal Interest Rate Rules, Asset Prices, and Credit Frictions.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 31 (10): 3228–3254.Google Scholar

  • Gerali, A., S. Neri, L. Sessa, and F. M. Signoretti. 2010. “Credit and Banking in a DSGE Model of the Euro Area.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42 (Suppl 6): 107–141.Web of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Gertler, M., and P. Karadi. 2011. “A Model of Unconventional Monetary Policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics 58 (1): 17–34.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Gilchrist, S., and M. Saito. 2008. “Expectations, Asset Prices and Monetary Policy: The Role of Learning.” In Asset Prices and Monetary Policy, edited by J. Y. Campbell. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar

  • Gilchrist, S., and E. Zakrajšek. 2012. “Credit Supply Shocks and Economic Activity in a Financial Accelerator Model.” In Rethinking the Financial Crisis, edited by A. S. Blinder, A. W. Lo and R. M. Solow, Forthcoming, vol. 29 (2–3), 295–330. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar

  • Glocker, C., and P. Towbin. 2012. “Reserve Requirements for Price and Financial Stability: When Are They Effective?” International Journal of Central Banking 8 (1): 65–113.Google Scholar

  • Gray, S. 2011. “Central Bank Balances and Reserve Requirements.” IMF Working Paper No. 11/36.Google Scholar

  • Hancock, D., A. J. Laing, and J. A. Wilcox. 1995. “Bank Capital Shocks: Dynamic Effects on Securities, Loans, and Capital.” Journal of Banking and Finance 19 (3–4): 661–677.Google Scholar

  • Iacoviello, M. 2005. “House Prices, Borrowing Constraints, and Monetary Policy in the Business Cycle.” American Economic review 95 (3): 739–764.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Iacoviello, M. 2010. Financial Business Cycles. Mimeo, Federal Reserve Board.Google Scholar

  • Jeanne, O., and A. Korinek. 2010. Managing Credit Booms and Busts: A Pigouvian Taxation Approach. Mimeo, Johns Hopkins University and University of Maryland.Google Scholar

  • Kannan, P., P. Rabanal, and A. Scott. 2012. “Monetary and Macroprudential Policy Rules in a Model of House Price Booms.” B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 12 (1): Art 16.Google Scholar

  • Kashyap, A. K., and J. C. Stein. 2012. “The Optimal Conduct of Monetary Policy with Interest on Reserves.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4 (1): 266–282.Web of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Kiyotaki, N., and J. Moore. 2008. Liquidity, Business Cycles, and Monetary Policy. Mimeo, Princeton University.Google Scholar

  • Lim, C., F. Columba, A. Costa, P. Kongsamut, A. Otani, M. Saiyid, T. Wezel, and X. Wu. 2011. “Macroprudential Policy: What Instruments and How to Use Them? Lessons from Country Experiences.” IMF Working Paper No. 11/238.Google Scholar

  • Meh, C., and K. Moran. 2010. “The Role of Bank Capital in the Propagation of Shocks.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34 (3): 555–576.Google Scholar

  • Mendoza, E. G., and V. Quadrini. 2010. “Financial Globalization, Financial Crises and Contagion.” Journal of Monetary Economics 57 (1): 24–39.CrossrefWeb of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Mimir, Y. 2013. “Financial Intermediaries, Credit Shocks, and Business Cycles”. CBRT Working Paper No. 13/13.Google Scholar

  • Montoro, C. 2011. Assessing the Role of Reserve Requirements under Financial Frictions. Mimeo, Bank for International Settlements.Google Scholar

  • Montoro, C., and R. Moreno. 2011. “The Use of Reserve Requirements as a Policy Instrument in Latin America.” BIS Quarterly Review, March, 53–65.Google Scholar

  • Reinhart, C. M., and K. S. Rogoff. 2008. “Is the 2007 US Sub-Prime Financial Crisis So Different? An International Historical Comparison.” American Economic Review 98 (2): 339–344.Web of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Smets, F., and R. Wouters. 2007. “Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach.” American Economic Review 97 (3): 586–606.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

About the article

Corresponding author: Yasin Mimir, Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, Istanbul School of Central Banking, Fener Kalamış Cad., Atlıhan Sk. No: 30/A, Kadıköy, Istanbul, Turkey, e-mail:


Published Online: 2013-06-20

Published in Print: 2013-01-01


See Gray (2011), Lim et al. (2011), Montoro (2011), Montoro and Moreno (2011), Glocker and Towbin (2012) for a discussion of country experiences.

Endogenously determined short-term nominal interest rates will also be more volatile compared to a Taylor rule setup.

We also conduct an analysis of a model economy with a zero required reserves policy. However, since the dynamics of this case strongly resemble those of the fixed RRR economy, we do not include it in the paper in order to save space.

Christensen, Meh, and Moran (2011) and Angelini, Neri, and Panetta (2012) follow a similar route when analyzing countercyclical capital requirements for macroprudential purposes.

For examples, see Benigno et al. (2010), Jeanne and Korinek (2010), Mendoza and Quadrini (2010), Benigno et al. (2011), Brunnermeier and Sannikov (2011) and Christensen, Meh, and Moran (2011), among others.

Gilchrist and Zakrajšek (2012) illustrate that monetary policy response to credit spreads, as a means to maintain financial stability, countervails the adverse impact of financial disruptions on macroeconomic variables.

This study analyzes the role of public intermediation of funds in times of financial repression.

Beau, Clerc, and Mojon (2012) provide a section in which the institutional frameworks adopted by the US, the UK, and the European Union are discussed in terms of the implementation of macroprudential policies. Arguably, the governance of macroprudential policies in Turkey is similar to that in the European Union in that the European Systemic Risk Board is independent from the European Central Bank (as the BRSA is independent from the CBRT in Turkey), but does not possess ultimate control over all macroprudential policy measures (the CBRT being in full charge of, for example, currency/maturity composition and the level of reserve requirements).

Increasing reserve requirements prior to this regime change was essential because by doing so, the CBRT rendered itself the net lender in the overnight market. This way, when it decides to carry out a traditional auction (instead of a quantity auction) in the overnight funding market, it could raise the average cost of central bank funding, way above the benchmark policy rate, which can be adjusted only once a month.

The Turkish banking system has been considerably conservative in complying with the regulations enacted by the BRSA since the aftermath of the domestic financial turmoil of 2001. Indeed, the actual risk weighted capital adequacy ratio of the Turkish banking system is currently around 16%, which is much higher than the regulatory minimum.

The introduction of a wide overnight interest corridor by the CBRT has illustrated that the effectiveness of reserve requirement hikes on increasing the cost of extending credit for banks is dampened, if the rate at which the central bank provides as much liquidity as the banking system demands is close to the policy rate. See BRSA (2011) for the details of the collective policy measures taken by the BRSA and the CBRT during the excessive capital inflows era and the developments thereafter.

This assumption is useful in making the agency problem that we introduce in Section 3.2 more realistic.

The zero real return earned from required reserves actually implies that the central bank is remunerating reserves with a nominal rate equal to the rate of inflation. This is indeed consistent with the experience of commercial banks in Turkey, since their local currency denominated reserves have been remunerated with a nominal return in line with the rate of inflation in the period 2002:1–2010:3. For the remuneration rates, see www.tcmb.gov.tr/yeni/bgm/dim/TLzorunlukarsilikfaizorani.html.

This assumption ensures that bankers never accumulate enough net worth to finance all their equity purchases of nonfinancial firms via internal funds so that they always have to borrow from households in the form of deposits.

Derivations of equations (11), (12) and (13) are available in the technical Appendix.

We model monetary policy in a simplistic manner in order to isolate the impact of required reserves policy described below. We also abstain from modeling disturbances to money growth because they produce implausible inflation dynamics in a cash-in-advance model of a flexible price environment.

Perfect insurance within family members of households ensures that the increase in real balances and reserves demand is lumped into Tt, which does not alter the optimality conditions of the utility maximization problem.

Loss function analysis in Section 5.4 uses second-order approximation of equilibrium conditions.

The legal target of the risk-weighted capital adequacy ratio set by the BRSA in Turkey is 8%, however, in practice, commercial banks in Turkey maintain 16% for this ratio.

This is the period in which the CBRT changed the RRR for macroprudential purposes.

We do not input the series of reserve requirement ratios into this empirical equation because the observed credit spreads and deposit rates would endogenously reflect the impact of reserves.

On bank capital shocks, see Hancock, Laing, and Wilcox (1995), Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), Cúrdia and Woodford (2010), Iacoviello (2010), Meh and Moran (2010), Mendoza and Quadrini (2010), and Mimir (2013).

Financial shocks cannot be studied in this experiment because when financial frictions are absent, banks become a veil and bank capital is not defined.

Notice that the fluctuations in these two cases are around different steady states because the long-run value of RRR is different across economies.

RRR is assumed to be positive but fixed in order not to obscure the variance decomposition analysis.

The dynamics of the economy with no reserves are available upon request.

Standard deviations of model variables are computed over sufficiently long simulations of the approximated decision rules. When simulations are sufficiently long, the moments of the simulated data converge to their theoretical counterparts.

It is straightforward to predict that the volatility of nominal interest rates (which are not set by a monetary policy authority, but rather are determined endogenously) increases in this case as well.

Indeed, stabilizing credit spreads in this way is analogous to stabilizing distortionary consumption taxes in the usual Ramsey framework.

Accordingly, equation (30) is modified to be

and
respectively.

Indeed, responding to credit partly resembles responding to asset prices because credit is defined as the market value of capital claims issued by production firms that are traded at the asset price of capital.

Consistent with the variance decomposition results reported in Table 2, the volatility of inflation under time-invariant reserves policy economies is reduced sharply when there are no financial shocks.

Reinhart and Rogoff (2008) and Borio and Drehmann (2009) argue that excessive credit expansions help predict financial crises.

Recall that the steady state of all of these economies is identical.

The first best of this model economy is achieved when both monetary and financial frictions are removed.

Notice that the recalibrated values for ϕ vary in the range of [2.7, 4.13], whereas the benchmark value for this parameter is 3.28.

Investment is more volatile when φ is lower precisely because less of the adjustment to the adverse TFP shock comes through asset price changes.


Citation Information: The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, Volume 13, Issue 1, Pages 823–880, ISSN (Online) 1935-1690, ISSN (Print) 2194-6116, DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/bejm-2012-0093.

Export Citation

©2013 by Walter de Gruyter Berlin Boston. Copyright Clearance Center

Citing Articles

Here you can find all Crossref-listed publications in which this article is cited. If you would like to receive automatic email messages as soon as this article is cited in other publications, simply activate the “Citation Alert” on the top of this page.

[1]
Yaprak Tavman
Oxford Economic Papers, 2015, Volume 67, Number 2, Page 334

Comments (0)

Please log in or register to comment.
Log in