Jump to ContentJump to Main Navigation
Show Summary Details
More options …

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics

Editor-in-Chief: Schipper, Burkhard

Ed. by Fong, Yuk-fai / Peeters, Ronald / Puzzello , Daniela / Rivas, Javier / Wenzelburger, Jan

2 Issues per year


IMPACT FACTOR 2016: 0.229
5-year IMPACT FACTOR: 0.271

CiteScore 2016: 0.30

SCImago Journal Rank (SJR) 2016: 0.398
Source Normalized Impact per Paper (SNIP) 2016: 0.232

Mathematical Citation Quotient (MCQ) 2016: 0.08

Online
ISSN
1935-1704
See all formats and pricing
More options …

Monopolistic Signal Provision

Luis Rayo
  • Corresponding author
  • The London School of Economics and Political Science, Department of Management, London, United Kingdom
  • Email
  • Other articles by this author:
  • De Gruyter OnlineGoogle Scholar
Published Online: 2013-05-08 | DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/bejte-2012-0003

Abstract

I study a monopolist who sells a signal to a consumer with a hidden type. The consumer uses this signal to obtain social status, defined as the expectation of the consumer’s type conditional on the signal. The monopolist must decide how accurately different types are revealed. When pooling subsets of types, she reduces social surplus, but extracts greater information rents. I derive the optimal mechanism by examining the covariance between the consumer’s type and his virtual marginal value of social status.

Keywords: nonlinear pricing; signaling; information disclosure

References

  • Bagwell, Laurie Simon, and B. Douglas Bernheim. 1996. “Veblen Effects in a Theory of Conspicuous Consumption.” American Economic Review 86(3):349–73.Google Scholar

  • Banks, Jeffrey S., and Joel Sobel. 1987. “Equilibrium Selection in Signaling Games.” Econometrica 55(3):647–61.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Becker, Gary S., and Kevin M. Murphy. 2000. Social Economics: Market Behavior in a Social Environment. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar

  • Becker, Gary S., Kevin M., Murphy, and Edward L. Glaeser. 2000. “Social Markets and the Escalation of Quality: The World of Veblen Revisited.” in Becker, Gary S., and Murphy, Kevin M. (2000).Google Scholar

  • Bergemann, Dirk, and Martin Pesendorfer. 2007. “Information Structures in Optimal Auctions.” Journal of Economic Theory 137(1):580–609.CrossrefWeb of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Bernheim, B. Douglas. 1994. “A Theory of Conformity.” Journal of Political Economy 102(5):841–77.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Board, Simon. 2009. “Monopolistic Group Design with Peer Effects.” Theoretical Economics 4(1):89–125.Google Scholar

  • Cho, In-Koo, and David M. Kreps. 1987. “Signaling Games and Stable Equilibria.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 102(2):179–221.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Cho, In-Koo, and Joel Sobel. 1990. “Strategic Stability and Uniqueness in Signaling Games.” Journal of Economic Theory 50(2):381–413.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Damiano, Ettore, and Hao Li. 2007. “Price Discrimination and Efficient Matching.” Economic Theory 30(2):243–63.Google Scholar

  • Damiano, Ettore, and Hao Li. 2008. “Competing Matchmaking.” Journal of the European Economic Association 6(4):789–818.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Daughety, Andrew F., and Jennifer F. Reinganum. 2010. “Public Goods, Social Pressure, and the Choice Between Privacy and Publicity.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 2(2):191–221.Web of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Diaz-Diaz, Miguel, and Luis Rayo. 2012. “Conspicuous Consumption with Imperfect Competition.” mimeo, Central Bank of Mexico and LSE.Google Scholar

  • Fudenberg, Drew, and Jean Tirole. 2000. Game Theory. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar

  • Glazer, Amihai, and Kai A. Konrad. 1996. “A Signaling Explanation for Charity.” American Economic Review 86(4):1019–28.Google Scholar

  • Gomes, Renato, and Alessandro Pavan. 2011. “Price Discrimination in Many-to-Many Matching Markets.” mimeo, Toulouse School of Economics and Northwestern University.Google Scholar

  • Guesnerie, Roger, and Jean-Jacques Laffont. 1984. “A Complete Solution to a Class of Principal-Agent Problems with an Application to the Control of a Self-Managed Firm.” Journal of Public Economics 25(3):329–69.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Harbaugh, William T. 1998. “What do Donations Buy? A Model of Philanthropy Based on Prestige and Warm Glow.” Journal of Public Economics 67(2):269–84.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Hoppe, Heidrun C., Benny Moldovanu, and Emre Ozdenoren. 2011. “Coarse Matching with Incomplete Information.” Economic Theory 47(1):75–104.Web of ScienceCrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Lizzeri, Alessandro. 1999. “Information Revelation and Certification Intermediaries.” Rand Journal of Economics 30(2):214–31.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Maskin, Eric, and John Riley. 1984. “Monopoly with Incomplete Information.” Rand Journal of Economics 15(2):171–96.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Milgrom, Paul, and Ilya Segal. 2002. “Envelope Theorems for Arbitrary Choice Sets.” Econometrica 70(2):583–601.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Moldovanu, Benny, Aner Sela, and Xianwen Shi. 2007. “Contests for Status.” Journal of Political Economy 115(2):338–63.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Mussa, Michael, and Sherwin Rosen. 1978. “Monopoly and Product Quality.” Journal of Economic Theory 18(2):301–17.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Myerson, Roger B. 1981. “Optimal Auction Design.” Mathematics of Operations Research 6(1):58–73.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Pesendorfer, Wolfgang. 1995. “Design Innovation and Fashion Cycles.” American Economic Review 85(4):771–92.Google Scholar

  • Ramey, Garey. 1996. “D1 Signaling Equilibria with Multiple Signals and a Continuum of Types.” Journal of Economic Theory 69(2):508–31.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Rayo, Luis, and Ilya Segal. 2010. “Optimal Information Disclosure.” Journal of Political Economy 118(5):949–987.CrossrefWeb of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Veblen, Thorstein B. 1899. The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study of Institutions. London: Unwin Books.Google Scholar

  • Vikander, Nick E. 2010. “Targeted Advertising and Social Status.” Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper 11–016/1.Google Scholar

  • Zubrickas, Robertas. 2012. “Optimal Grading.” mimeo, University of Zurich.Google Scholar

About the article

Published Online: 2013-05-08

Published in Print: 2013-01-01


This paper is a revised version of chapter 3 of my Ph.D. dissertation.

fn 3 provides an example of such a model.

In principle, there may exist multiple valid versions of the above conditional expectation, all of which coincide over a full measure subset of Θ. I focus on the standard version in which whenever the monopolist sells signal s to type θ′ only.

The following setting, borrowed from Rayo and Segal (2010), delivers the above reduced-form preferences. After observing the consumer’s signal s, the social contact must either “accept” or “reject” the consumer. Acceptance is worth υ(θ) to the consumer and θr to the social contact, where r is an outside option drawn from a uniform distribution over Θ. If Θ is normalized to [0, 1], the probability of acceptance is .

Note that the second term in h vanishes as θθH and F (θ) → 1.

Note that υ′(0) does not exist when α < 1. Theorem 1 remains valid, however, because υ′(θ) is well defined for all other types.

One can only hope for uniqueness almost-everywhere because profits are not affected by whether the boundary points of the intervals in are included or not in the pools.

For a formal definition of D1 equilibria for a continuum of types, see Ramey (1996).

D1 is a stronger requirement than the “Intuitive Criterion” (Cho and Kreps 1987). Unfortunately, the Intuitive Criterion does not guarantee a unique equilibrium when the sender has more than two types (see, for example, Fudenberg and Tirole 2000).

If Lizzeri’s monopolist could charge a report-contingent price, but could not verify the seller’s type directly or use stochastic disclosure rules, his setting would be the same as the present one (with his sellerin the place of my consumer) except for a crucial difference: his seller’s preferences are not single-crossing (namely, . In this case, one can see from problem (I) (Section 2.1) that the monopolist would obtain the same expected profits, , under any truthful filter.

Damiano and Li (2008) study the case of competition across matchmakers. Hoppe, Moldovanu, and Ozdenoren (2011) study the value of course matching schemes.

In other words, our papers intersect only when the two populations in Damiano and Li (2007) have identical distributions, utility is linear, and virtual values are monotone, in which case both models are identical and deliver perfect sorting. Another difference between the two papers is methodological. Damiano and Li use properties of supermodular functions to obtain a suffcient condition for perfect sorting, and local variations in the matching schedule to obtain a necessary condition. In contrast, I focus on the overall covariance structure between virtual marginal values and consumer types to find optimal pooling regions.

Diaz-Diaz and Rayo (2012) study the intermediate case of imperfect competition. They find excessive quality consumption and “Veblen effects:” goods with identical intrinsic quality sold at different prices. Daughety and Reinganum (2010) study private provision of public goods when consumers have a status motive and Vikander (2010) studies advertising when a status motive is also present. Glazer and Konrad (1996) argue that signaling wealth is a primary motivation behind charitable contributions.

The two papers also differ in their methodology. I use optimal nonlinear pricing methods, whereas Moldovanu et al. use methods of optimal contest design.

The Stanford Fund, 1998–99, gsbwww.uchicago.edu/campaign, 01/2003. See Harbaugh (1998) for further discussion of charitable donations.

Notice also that we might have P (D) = P (D′) for two different intervals D, D .


Citation Information: The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, ISSN (Online) 1935-1704, ISSN (Print) 2194-6124, DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/bejte-2012-0003.

Export Citation

©2013 by Walter de Gruyter Berlin / Boston. Copyright Clearance Center

Citing Articles

Here you can find all Crossref-listed publications in which this article is cited. If you would like to receive automatic email messages as soon as this article is cited in other publications, simply activate the “Citation Alert” on the top of this page.

[1]
Ronen Gradwohl and Rann Smorodinsky
Games and Economic Behavior, 2017, Volume 104, Page 293
[2]
Renato Gomes and Alessandro Pavan
Theoretical Economics, 2016, Volume 11, Number 3, Page 1005
[3]
Thomas Trégouët
International Journal of Industrial Organization, 2015, Volume 42, Page 34
[4]
Gilat Levy and Ronny Razin
American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2015, Volume 7, Number 2, Page 308
[5]
Rogério Mazali and José A. Rodrigues-Neto
Games and Economic Behavior, 2013, Volume 82, Page 103
[6]
T.R. Johnson
Journal of Economic Theory, 2013, Volume 148, Number 4, Page 1700

Comments (0)

Please log in or register to comment.
Log in