Jump to ContentJump to Main Navigation
Show Summary Details
More options …

Journal of Ancient History

Ed. by Farney, Gary

2 Issues per year

Online
ISSN
2324-8114
See all formats and pricing
More options …

Artisans, Retailers, and Credit Transactions in the Roman World

Cameron Hawkins
  • Corresponding author
  • Department of Religion and Classics, University of Rochester, P.O. Box 270074, Rochester NY 14627, USA University of RochesterRochesterUnited States of America
  • Email
  • Other articles by this author:
  • De Gruyter OnlineGoogle Scholar
Published Online: 2017-06-14 | DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/jah-2016-0016

Abstract

In this article, I argue not just that many artisans and retailers in the Roman world were able to finance their businesses only by relying heavily on access to credit, but also that they depended primarily upon trade credit—that is, upon interpersonal credit provided to them by suppliers and subcontractors to whom they were linked by relationships of trust, and from whom they purchased goods and services on account. This was true primarily because most artisans and retailers catered to clients who often lacked ready money when they made purchases, and thus found it necessary to offer shop credit instead of concluding sales in exchange for immediate cash payments. This strategy in turn exacerbated their own cash flow problems and compelled them to incur liabilities that could easily match or exceed the value of their tangible assets. In these circumstances, many found that trade credit was both more accessible than loans procured on the credit market (for which they often lacked the necessary collateral), and also less risky, since suppliers of trade credit could be more forgiving of missed payments than conventional lenders (who were likely to take actions that could result either in seizure of an entrepreneur’s collateral or in his or her insolvency).

Keywords: Artisans; retailers; credit; trust; reputation

Bibliography

  • Aldrete, G. S., and D. J. Mattingly. “Feeding the city: the organization, operation, and scale of the supply system for Rome.” In Life, Death, and Entertainment in the Roman Empire, edited by D. S. Potter and D. J. Mattingly, 171–204. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, 1999.Google Scholar

  • Aubert, J.-J. Business Managers in Ancient Rome: a social and economic study of institores, 200 B. C. – A. D. 250. Leiden: Brill, 1994.Google Scholar

  • Aubert, J.-J. “‘Dumtaxat de peculio’: what’s in a peculium, or establishing the extent of the principal’s liability.” In New Frontiers: law and society in the Roman world, edited by P. Du Plessis, 192–206. Edinburgh: Edinburgh U. P., 2013.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Biscottini, M. V. “L’archivio di Tryphon, tessitore di Oxyrhynchos.” Aegyptus 46 (1966): 60–90, 186–292.Google Scholar

  • Broekaert, W. “Partners in business: Roman merchants and the potential advantages of being a collegiatus.” AncSoc 41 (2011): 221–256.Google Scholar

  • Broekaert, W. and A. Zuiderhoek. “Society, the market, or actually both? Networks and the allocation of credit and capital goods in the Roman economy.” CCG 26 (2015): 141–190.Google Scholar

  • Brunt, P. A. “Free labour and public works at Rome.” JRS 70 (1980): 81–100.Google Scholar

  • Buckland, W. W. The Roman Law of Slavery: the condition of the slave in private law from Augustus to Justinian. Cambridge: Cambridge U. P., 1908.Google Scholar

  • Burford, A. Craftsmen in Greek and Roman Society. Ithaca: Cornell U. P., 1972.Google Scholar

  • Coquery, N. “The aristocratic hôtel and its artisans in eighteenth-century Paris: the market ruled by court society.” In The Artisan and the European Town, 1500–1900, edited by G. Crossick, 92–115. Aldershot: Scholar’s, 1997.Google Scholar

  • De Vries, J. The Industrious Revolution: consumer behavior and the household economy, 1650 to the present. Cambridge: Cambridge U. P., 2008.Google Scholar

  • Earle, P. The Making of the English Middle Class: business, society, and family life in London, 1660–1730. London: Methuen, 1989.Google Scholar

  • Finley, M. I. The Ancient Economy. Updated Edition. Berkeley: University of California, 1999.Google Scholar

  • Földi, A. “Eine alternative Annäherungweise: Gedanken zum Problem des Handelsrechts in der römischen Welt.” RIDA 48 (2001): 65–90. Google Scholar

  • Frier, B. Landlords and Tenants in Imperial Rome. Princeton: Princeton U. P., 1980.Google Scholar

  • Gibbons, R. “Four formal(izable) theories of the firm?” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 58 (2005): 200–245.Google Scholar

  • Grantham, G. “Contra Ricardo: on the macroeconomics of pre-industrial economies.” European Review of Economic History 3 (1999): 199–232.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Harris, W. V. “The nature of Roman money.” In The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans, edited by W. V. Harris, 174–207. Oxford: Oxford U. P., 2008.Google Scholar

  • Hawkins, C. “Labour and employment.” In The Cambridge Companion to Ancient Rome, edited by P. Erdkamp, 336–351. Cambridge: Cambridge U. P., 2013.Google Scholar

  • Hawkins, C. Roman Artisans and the Urban Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge U. P., 2016.Google Scholar

  • Hollander, D. B. Money in the Late Roman Republic. Leiden: Brill, 2007.Google Scholar

  • Holleran, C. Shopping in Ancient Rome: the retail trade in the late Republic and the Principate. Oxford: Oxford U. P., 2012.Google Scholar

  • Hopkins, K. “Rome, taxes, rents and trade.” Kodai 6/7 (1995/1996): 41–75.Google Scholar

  • Howgego, C. “The supply and use of money in the Roman world: 200 B.C. to A.D. 300.” JRS 82 (1992): 1–31.Google Scholar

  • Jones, D. The Bankers of Puteoli: finance, trade and industry in the Roman world. Stroud: Tempus, 2006.Google Scholar

  • Kadens, E. “Pre-modern credit networks and the limits of reputation.” Iowa Law Review 100 (2015): 2429–2455.Google Scholar

  • Katsari, C. The Roman Monetary System: the eastern provinces from the first to the third century AD. Cambridge: Cambridge U. P., 2011.Google Scholar

  • Kehoe, D. P. Investment, Profit, and Tenancy: the jurists and the Roman agrarian economy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, 1997.Google Scholar

  • Kehoe, D. P. Law and the Rural Economy in the Roman Empire. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, 2007.Google Scholar

  • Kent, D. A. “Small businessmen and their credit transactions in early nineteenth-century Britain.” Business History 36 (1994): 47–64.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Lazo, P. “La ‘merx peculiaris’ como patrimonio especial.” Revista de Estudios Histórico-Jurídicos [Sección Derecho Romano] 35 (2013): 179–91.Google Scholar

  • Marshall, R. K. The Local Merchants of Prato: small entrepreneurs in the late medieval economy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U. P., 1999.Google Scholar

  • Martin, S. D. The Roman Jurists and the Organization of Private Building in the Late Republic and Early Empire. Brussels: Latomus, 1989.Google Scholar

  • Millar, F. “The world of the Golden Ass.” JRS 71 (1981): 63–75.Google Scholar

  • Monteix, N. “Du couteau au boucher: remarques préliminaires sur la préparation et le commerce de la viande à Pompéi.” Food and History 5 (2007): 169–95. Google Scholar

  • Muldrew, C. The Economy of Obligation: the culture of credit and social relations in early modern England. Houndmills: MacMillan, 1998.Google Scholar

  • Place, Francis. The Autobiography of Francis Place (1771–1854). Edited by Mary Thale. Cambridge: Cambridge U. P., 1972.Google Scholar

  • Rathbone, D. Economic Rationalism and Rural Society in Third-Century A. D. Egypt: the Heroninos Archive and the Appianus Estate. Cambridge: Cambridge U. P., 1991.Google Scholar

  • Ray, D. Development Economics. Princeton: Princeton U. P., 1998. Google Scholar

  • Safrai, Z. The Economy of Roman Palestine. London: Routledge, 1994.Google Scholar

  • Scheidel, W. “Real slave prices and the relative cost of slave labor in the Greco-Roman world.” AncSoc 35 (2005): 1–17. Google Scholar

  • Scheidel, W. “Coin quality, coin quantity, and coin value in early China and the Roman world.” AJN 22 (2010): 93–118.Google Scholar

  • Sonenscher, M. Work and Wages: natural law, politics, and the eighteenth-century French trades. Cambridge: Cambridge U. P., 1989.Google Scholar

  • Stedman Jones, G. Outcast London: a study in the relationship between classes in Victorian society. New York: Pantheon, 1984. Google Scholar

  • Verboven, K. “Currency, bullion and accounts: monetary modes in the Roman world.” Belgisch Tijdschrift voor Numismatiek en Zegelkunde / Revue Belge de Numismatique et de Sigillographie 155 (2009): 91–124.Google Scholar

  • Verboven, K. “Currency and credit in the Bay of Naples in the first century AD.” In Economy of Pompeii, edited by A. Wilson and M. Flohr, 361–384. Oxford: Oxford U. P., 2017.Google Scholar

  • Veyne, P. “La ‘Plèbe Moyenne’ sous le haut-empire Romain.” Annales HSS 55 (2000): 1169–1199.CrossrefGoogle Scholar

  • Young, C. “Financing the micro-scale enterprise: rural craft producers in Scotland, 1840–1914.” Business History Review 69 (1995): 398–421.Google Scholar

About the article

Published Online: 2017-06-14

Published in Print: 2017-06-07


Citation Information: Journal of Ancient History, ISSN (Online) 2324-8114, ISSN (Print) 2324-8106, DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/jah-2016-0016.

Export Citation

© 2017 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston. Copyright Clearance Center

Comments (0)

Please log in or register to comment.
Log in