Jump to ContentJump to Main Navigation
Show Summary Details
More options …

Review of Law & Economics

Editor-in-Chief: Parisi, Francesco / Engel, Christoph

Ed. by Cooter, Robert D. / Gómez Pomar, Fernando / Kornhauser, Lewis A. / Parchomovsky, Gideon / Franzoni, Luigi Alberto


CiteScore 2018: 0.32

SCImago Journal Rank (SJR) 2018: 0.274
Source Normalized Impact per Paper (SNIP) 2018: 0.493

Online
ISSN
1555-5879
See all formats and pricing
More options …
Ahead of print

Issues

Political Insulation, Technical Expertise and the Technocrat’s Paradox

Diego G. Pardow
  • Corresponding author
  • Facultad de Derecho, Universidad de Chile, Pío Nono 1, Providencia, Santiago, Region Metropolitana 7520421, Chile
  • Email
  • Other articles by this author:
  • De Gruyter OnlineGoogle Scholar
Published Online: 2019-07-13 | DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/rle-2016-0056

Abstract

It is generally assumed that independent agencies reflect the Congress’ willingness to deal with two different sources of risk that complement each other: political uncertainty regarding the policy implemented, and technical uncertainty regarding the outcome that would be achieved with that policy. This paper claims that such complementariness is true only when the Congress is expecting to capture the benefits of a sound technical decision. If this is not the case, for example when there is a large possibility of a political turnover in the near future, institutional design should follow a dynamic of entrenchment. Here politics and expertise substitute each other, thus reducing the optimal choice of agency independence. This paper illustrates these ideas by comparing the two waves of institutional reforms that occurred in Chile in the 1920’s and the 1980’s. The variance in the level of insulation achieved by each process responds to a key political difference: the first one was conducted through a democratic consensus that was meant to last several decades, whereas the second one was conducted during an authoritarian regime aware that its tenure in power was coming to an end.

Keywords: independent agencies; delegation; Administrative Law

References

  • Ackerman, Bruce, and William Hassler. 1981. Clean Coal, Dirty Air: Or How the Clean Air Act Became a Multibillion-Dollar Bail-Out for High-Sulfur Coal Producers. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar

  • Aghion, Philippe, and Jean Tirole. 1997. “Formal and Real Authority in Organizations,” 105 (1)Journal of Political Economy 1–29.Google Scholar

  • Bawn, Kathleen. 1995. “Political Control Versus Expertise: Congressional Choices About Administrative Procedures,” 89 (1)American Political Science Review 62–73.Google Scholar

  • Bendor, Jonathan, and Adam Meirowitz. 2004. “Spatial Models of Delegation,” 98 (2)American Political Science Review 293–310.Google Scholar

  • Corbo, Vittorio, and Leonardo Hernández. 2005. Ochenta años de historia del Banco Central de Chile. Documento de Trabajo No. 345 Banco Central de Chile.Google Scholar

  • Cordero, Eduardo. 2012. “La administración del Estado en Chile y el concepto de autonom&’ıa,” in Ramiro Mendoza, ed. Contralor&’ıa General de la República: 85 años de vida institucional (1927–2012). Contralor&’ıa General de la República, pp. 1927–2012.Google Scholar

  • Dewatripont, Mathias, and Jean Tirole. 1994. The Prudential Regulation of Banks. Massachussets: MIT Press.Google Scholar

  • Drake, Paul. 1989. The Money Doctor in the Andes: The KEMMERER MISSIONS, 1923-1933. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar

  • Edwards, Sebastian. 1998. “The Chilean Pension Reform: A Pioneering Program,” in Martin Feldstein ed. Privatizing social security. University of Chicago Press, pp. 33–62.Google Scholar

  • Epstein, David, and Sharyn O’Halloran. 1999. Delegating Powers: A Transaction Cost Politics Approach to Policy Making Under Separate Powers. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar

  • Ferrada, Juan Carlos. 1998. “La autonomia como tecnica de reparto de potestades públicas: El caso del Banco Central de Chile,” 25 (1)Revista chilena de derecho 335–344.Google Scholar

  • Fiorina, Morris P. 1986. “Legislator Uncertainty, Legislative Control, and the Delegation of Legislative Power,” 2 (1)Journal of Law, Economics & Organization 33–51.Google Scholar

  • Fiorina, Morris, and Roger Noll. 1978. “Voters, Legislators and Bureaucracy: Institutional Design in the Public Sector,” 68(2)The American Economic Review 256–260.Google Scholar

  • Foxley, Alejandro. 1983. Latin American experiments in neoconservative economics. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar

  • Freeman, Jody, and Jim Rossi. 2012. “Agency Coordination in Shared Regulatory Space,” 125(5)Harvard Law Review 1131–1211.Google Scholar

  • Gailmard, Sean. 2002. “Expertise, Subversion, and Bureaucratic Discretion,” 18 (2)Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 536–555.Google Scholar

  • Garc&’ıa, José Francisco. 2009. “?‘ Inflación de superintendencias? Un diagnóstico cr&’ıtico desde el derecho regulatorio,” Revista Actualidad Jur&’ıdica 10.Google Scholar

  • Garc&’ıa, José Francisco, and Luis Cordero. 2012. “Elementos para la discusión sobre agencias independientes en Chile. El caso de las superintendencias,” in Javier Couso, ed. Anuario de Derecho Público 2012. Santiago: Universidad Diego Portales, pp. 415–435.Google Scholar

  • Garc&’ıa, José Francisco, and Sergio Verdugo. 2010. “De las superintendencias a las agencias regulatorias independientes en Chile: Aspectos constitucionales y de diseño regulatorio,” 22 Actualidad Jur&’ıdica 263–305.Google Scholar

  • Gersen, Jacob. 2010. “Designing Agencies,” in Daniel Farber and Anne Joseph O’Connell, eds. Research Handbook on Public Choice and Public Law. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 333–362.Google Scholar

  • Gilardi, Fabrizio. 2002. “Policy Credibility and Delegation to Independent Regulatory Agencies: A Comparative Empirical Analysis,” 9 (6)Journal of European Public Policy 873–893.Google Scholar

  • Glaser, Elisabeth. 2003. “Chile’s Monetarist Money Doctors, 1850–1988,” in Marc Flandreau, ed. Money Doctors: The Experience of International Financial Advising, 1850–2000. London, UK: Routledge, pp. 166–198.Google Scholar

  • Hart, Oliver, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W Vishny. 1997. “The Proper Scope of Government: Theory and an Application to Prisons,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 1127–1161.Google Scholar

  • Hayek, Friedrich. 1945. “The Use of Knowledge in Society,” 35 (4)The American Economic Review 519–530.Google Scholar

  • Huber, John D, and Charles R Shipan. 2006. “Politics, Delegation and Bureucracy,” in The Oxford handbook of political economy, vol. 7 New York, New York: Oxford University Press, p. 256.Google Scholar

  • Huneeus, Carlos, and Lake Sagaris. 2007. The Pinochet Regime. Boulder, Colorado: Lynne Rienner Publishers.Google Scholar

  • Issacharoff, Samuel, and Laura Miller. 2010. “Democracy and Electoral Processes,” in Daniel Farber and Anne Joseph O’Connell, eds. Research Handbook on Public Choice and Public Law. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 221–258.Google Scholar

  • Kagan, Elena. 2001. “Presidential Administration,” Harvard Law Review 2245–2385.Google Scholar

  • Kiewiet, Roderick, and Mathew McCubbins. 1991. The logic of delegation. Chicago, Illinois: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar

  • Kydland, Finn, and Edward Prescott. 1977. “Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans,” The Journal of Political Economy 473–491.Google Scholar

  • Lazear, Edward. 2000. “The Power of Incentives,” 90 (2)The American Economic Review 410–414.Google Scholar

  • Lewis, David. 2004. Presidents and the Politics of Agency Design: Political Insulation in the United States Government Bureaucracy, 1946–1997. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar

  • Macey, Jonathan R. 1992. “Organizational Design and Political Control of Administrative Agencies,” 8 (1)Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 93–110.Google Scholar

  • Majone, Giandomenico. 2001. “Nonmajoritarian Institutions and the Limits of Democratic Governance: A Political Transaction-Cost Approach,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE)/Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 57–78.Google Scholar

  • McCubbins, Mathew. 1985. “The Legislative Design of Regulatory Structure,” American Journal of Political Science 721–748.Google Scholar

  • Meier, Kenneth, and George Krause. 2003. “The Scientific Study of Bureaucracy: An Overview,” Politics, Policy, and Organizations 1–19.Google Scholar

  • Miller, Geoffrey. 1986. “Independent Agencies,” 1986 The Supreme Court Review 41–97.Google Scholar

  • Moe, Terry. 1985. “The Politicized Presidency,” in John Chubb and Paul Peterson, eds. The new direction in American politics. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, pp. 235–271.Google Scholar

  • Moe, Terry. 1997. “Positive Theory of Public Bureaucracy,” in Perspectives on public choice: A handbook. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 455–480.Google Scholar

  • Morandé, Felipe, and Juan Daniel D&’ıaz, eds. 2010. Chile en el club de los pa&’ıses desarrollados. Santiago de Chile: Ediciones Universidad Católica de Chile.Google Scholar

  • North, Douglass. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar

  • OECD, Organization for Economic Cooperation & Development. 2014. The Governance of Regulators. Paris: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar

  • Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 1986. “Reforming Public Bureaucracy through Economic Incentives?” 2 (1)Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 131–61.Google Scholar

  • Silva, Eduardo. 1996. The State and Capital in Chile: Business Elites, Technocrats, and Market Economics. Oxford: Westview Press.Google Scholar

  • Silva, Patricio. 1991. “Technocrats and Politics in Chile: from the Chicago Boys to the CIEPLAN Monks,” 23 (2)Journal of Latin American Studies 385–410.Google Scholar

  • Spiller, Pablo. 1995. “Regulatory Commitment and Utilities Privatization, Implications for Future Comparative Research,” in Jeffrey Banks and Eric Hanusek, eds. Modern Political Economy: Old Topics, New Directions. New York, New York: Cambridge University Press Cambridge chapter 2, pp. 63–79.Google Scholar

  • Stephenson, Matthew. 2007. “Bureaucratic Decision Costs and Endogenous Agency Expertise,” 23 (2)Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 469–498.Google Scholar

  • Stephenson, Matthew. 2008. “Optimal Political Control of the Bureaucracy,” Michigan Law Review 53–110.Google Scholar

  • Talley, Eric. 2012. “Law, Economics, and the Burden (s) of Proof,” in Jennifer Arlen, ed. Research Handbook on the Economics of Torts. New York: Edward Elgar Publications.Google Scholar

  • Tirole, Jean. 1994. “The Internal Organization of Government,” Oxford Economic Papers 1–29.Google Scholar

  • Weber, Max. 1956. Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology. Berkeley, California: University of California Press.Google Scholar

  • Williamson, Oliver. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar

  • Wilson, James. 1989. Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies do and Why They Do It. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar

  • Wood, Dan, and John Bothe. 2004. “Political Transaction Costs and the Politics of Administrative Design,” 66 (1)Journal of Politics 176–202.Google Scholar

About the article

Published Online: 2019-07-13


Citation Information: Review of Law & Economics, ISSN (Online) 1555-5879, ISSN (Print) 2194-6000, DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/rle-2016-0056.

Export Citation

© 2019 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston.Get Permission

Comments (0)

Please log in or register to comment.
Log in