Jump to ContentJump to Main Navigation
Show Summary Details
More options …

Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftspolitik

Ed. by Donges, Juergen B. / Krause, Michael / Roth, Steffen J. / Watrin, Christian

Online
ISSN
2366-0317
See all formats and pricing
More options …
Volume 68, Issue 2

Issues

Asymmetrische Information auf dem Handwerksmarkt – eine qualitative Analyse

Till Proeger
  • Corresponding author
  • Volkswirtschaftliches Institut für Mittelstand und Handwerk an der Universität Göttingen ifh Göttingen, Heinrich-Düker-Weg 6 37073 Göttingen Germany Tel.: (0551) 39 174884 Göttingen, Germany
  • Email
  • Other articles by this author:
  • De Gruyter OnlineGoogle Scholar
/ Li Kathrin Rupieper
  • Volkswirtschaftliches Institut für Mittelstand und Handwerk an der Universität Göttingen ifh Göttingen, Heinrich-Düker-Weg 6 37073 Göttingen Germany Tel.: (0551) 39 174884 Göttingen, Germany
  • Email
  • Other articles by this author:
  • De Gruyter OnlineGoogle Scholar
Published Online: 2019-09-07 | DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/zfwp-2019-2010

Abstract

The code of craft regulation constitutes the legal base for craft and trade occupations in Germany. Resulting from a deregulation in 2004, the requirement to obtain a degree of higher occupational training, which used to be obligatory for founding a business, was dropped for about half of the occupations regulated by this code. While this deregulation has been frequently analyzed from a competition economics’ perspective, evidence regarding the information economics’ aspect of this deregulation is lacking. It is of particular relevance whether the deregulation fostered market failures due to “market-for-lemons” issues or, to the contrary, whether market-endogenous information instruments have emerged – a question located at the pivot of the economic discussion of the craft regulation. This study uses a qualitative research approach and analyzes 268 interviews with firms and customers on craft fairs to examine informational asymmetries on the market for craft services as well as market instruments for their compensation. We find evidence that strong informational asymmetries exist and are compensated by regional reputation building of firms. Further, we show that no formal informational mechanisms have emerged that could determine service quality ex ante. Based upon those results, suggestions for the further study of the informational properties of the craft market are presented.

Schlagwörter: Handwerk; Informationsasymmetrien; Interviews; Market-for-Lemons; Reputation

Keywords: Craft and Trade; Information Asymmetries; Interviews; Market-for-Lemons; Reputation

JEL Classification: D02; D83; J44; L51

Literatur

  • Akerlof, George A. (1970), “The Market for ‘lemons’: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Jg. 84, H. 3, S. 488–500.Google Scholar

  • Aspers, Patrik (2009), “Knowledge and Valuation in Markets”, Theory and Society, Jg. 38, H. 2, S. 111–131.Web of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Assaad, Ragui (1993), “Formal and Informal Institutions in the Labor Market, with Applications to the Construction Sector in Egypt”, World Development, Jg. 21, H. 6, S. 925–939.Google Scholar

  • Bartholomew, Susan und Anne D. Smith (2006), “Improving Survey Response Rates from Chief Executive Officers in Small Firms: The Importance of Social Networks”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Jg. 30, H. 1, S. 83–96.Google Scholar

  • Darby, Michael R. und Edi Karni (1973), “Free competition and the optimal amount of fraud”, The Journal of Law and Economics, Jg. 16, H. 1, S. 67–88.Google Scholar

  • Eisenhardt, Kathleen M. (1989), “Building theories from case study research”, Academy of Management Review, Jg. 14, S. 532–550.Google Scholar

  • Eisenhardt, Kathleen M., und Graebner, M. E. (2007), “Theory building from cases: opportunities and challenges”, Academy of Management Journal, Jg. 50, H.1, S. 25–32.Google Scholar

  • Feser, Daniel und Proeger, Till (2018), “Knowledge-Intensive Business Services as Credence Goods – a Demand-Side Approach”, Journal of the Knowledge Economy, Jg. 9 H. 1, S. 62–80.Web of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Feser, Daniel und Proeger, Till (2017). “Asymmetric information as a barrier to knowledge spillovers in expert markets”, International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, Jg. 13 H. 1, S. 211–232.Google Scholar

  • Fredriksen, Kaja, Petrik Runst und Kilian Bizer (2018), “Masterful Meisters? Voluntary Certification and Quality in the German Crafts Sector”, German Economic Review, Jg. 20, H.1, S. 83–104. DOI: 10.1111/geer.12158.Google Scholar

  • Gründerszene.de (2015), „MyHammer. Ein Berliner Urgestein kehrt zurück, abgerufen unter https://www.gruenderszene.de/allgemein/myhammer-claudia-frese, letzter Aufruf 10.08.2018.

  • Friedman, Milton (1962, 2002), “Capitalism and Freedom. 40th Anniversary Edition”, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar

  • Glaser, Barney G. (1965), “The Constant Comparative Method of Qualitative Analysis”, Social Problems, Jg. 12, H. 4, S. 436–445.Google Scholar

  • Glaser, Barney und Anselm L. Strauss (2017), “Discovery of Grounded Theory: Strategies for Qualitative Research”, New York, London: Routledge.Google Scholar

  • Haupt, Andreas und Nils Witte (2016), “Occupational Licensing and the Wage Structure in Germany”, KIT Working Paper Series in Sociology (2016), H. 4.Google Scholar

  • Kerschbamer, Rudolf und Matthias Sutter (2017), “The Economics of Credence Goods – a Survey of Recent Lab and Field Experiments”, CESifo Economic Studies, Jg. 63, H. 1, S. 1–23.Web of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Kleiner, Morris M. (2000), “Occupational Licensing”, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Jg. 14, H. 4, S. 189–202.Google Scholar

  • Kleiner, Morris M. (2006), Licensing Occupations: Ensuring Quality or Restricting Competition?” W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. Kalamazoo, Michigan.Google Scholar

  • Kleiner, Morris M. (2015), “Guild-Ridden Labor Markets: The Curious Case of Occupational Licensing”, W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. Kalamazoo, Michigan.Google Scholar

  • Koch, Andreas und Sebastian Nielen (2017), “Ökonomische Wirkungen der Handwerksnovelle 2004: Ergebnisse einer Kontrollgruppenanalyse”, Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik, Jg. 18, H. 1, S. 72–85.Google Scholar

  • Leland, Hayne E. (1979), “Quacks, Lemons, and Licensing: A Theory of Minimum Quality Standards”, Journal of Political Economy, Jg. 87, H. 6, S. 1328–1346.Google Scholar

  • Mayring, Philipp (2004), “Qualitative content analysis”, in U. Flick, E. von Kardoff und I. Steinke (Hrsg.), A Companion to Qualitative Research, Sage: London, S. 266–269.Google Scholar

  • Newby, Rick, John Watson und David Woodliff (2003), “SME Survey Methodology: Response Rates, Data Quality, and Cost Effectiveness”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Jg. 28, H. 2, S. 163–172.Google Scholar

  • Proeger, Till (2018), “Knowledge spillovers and absorptive capacity – institutional evidence from the ‘German Mittelstand‘”, forthcoming in: Journal of the Knowledge Economy, doi: 10.1007/s13132-018-0539-8.Google Scholar

  • Röber, Wiebke (2009), Eine informationsökonomische Analyse des Handwerks. Dissertation im Fachbereich Wirtschafts-, Verhaltens- und Rechtswissenschaften der Leuphana Universität Lüneburg.Google Scholar

  • Rostam-Afschar, Davud (2014), “Entry Regulation and Entrepreneurship: A Natural Experiment in German Craftsmanship” Empirical Economics, Jg. 47, H. 3, S. 1067–1101.Web of ScienceGoogle Scholar

  • Rostam-Afschar, Davud (2015), “Regulatory effects of the amendment to the HwO in 2004 in German craftsmanship”, Forschungsbericht, Directorate General Internal Market and Services, Europäische Kommission.Google Scholar

  • Runst, Petrik, Jörg Thomä, Katarzyna Haverkamp und Klaus Müller (2018a) “A replication of ‘Entry regulation and entrepreneurship: a natural experiment in German craftsmanship’”, forthcoming in Empirical Economics, DOI: 10.1007/s00181-018-1457-0.Google Scholar

  • Runst, Petrik, Kaja Fredriksen, Till Proeger, Katarzyna Haverkamp und Jörg Thomä (2018b), “Handwerksordnung: ökonomische Effekte der Deregulierung von 2004“, Wirtschaftsdienst, Jg. 98, H. 5, S. 365–371.Google Scholar

  • Shapiro, Carl (1986), “Investment, Moral Hazard, and Occupational Licensing”, The Review of Economic Studies, Jg. 53, H. 5, S. 843–62.Google Scholar

  • Svorny, Shirley (2000), “Licensing, market entry regulation”, in: Boudewijn Bouckaert und Gerrit De Geest (Hrsg.): Encyclopedia of Law and Economics Volume III: The Regulation of Contracts, Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, S. 296–328.Google Scholar

  • Terhorst, Pieter & Hilal Erkuş-Öztürk (2016), “Reducing quality uncertainty in the Amsterdam field of restaurants”, in: Niels Beerepoot, Bart Lambregts, Jana Kleibert (Hrsg.): Globalisation and Services-driven Economic Growth: Perspectives from the Global North and South, Routledge: London, S. 105–118.Google Scholar

About the article

Published Online: 2019-09-07

Published in Print: 2019-08-01


Citation Information: Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftspolitik, Volume 68, Issue 2, Pages 149–182, ISSN (Online) 2366-0317, ISSN (Print) 0721-3808, DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/zfwp-2019-2010.

Export Citation

© 2019 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston.Get Permission

Citing Articles

Here you can find all Crossref-listed publications in which this article is cited. If you would like to receive automatic email messages as soon as this article is cited in other publications, simply activate the “Citation Alert” on the top of this page.

Comments (0)

Please log in or register to comment.
Log in